Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T20:10:02.477Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Pandora's jar: scarcity and the standard of living in classical Greek economic theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 July 2009

Get access

Extract

Few ideas are as central both to social scientific analysis and normative political philosophy as the concept of scarcity. For the social analyst, scarcity is at the core of many models, including most prominently what Gary Becker has called the economic approach to human behavior, for example rational choice and game theoretic approaches. Its importance in this sphere stems from the fact that it is one of the key ingredients generating calculation and strategic interaction, cooperative or conflictual. Where, conversely, a superabundance is postulated there is, as Carl Menger observed, no economizing behavior, no competition, nor any need for a property regime. And so too is the idea of scarcity one of the background conditions for the theory of justice in general—‘justice derives its origins’ from human selfishness combined with ‘the scanty provision nature has made for his wants’ —and for the problems of distributive justice in particular. Again, where there is superabundance these matters would not so much as arise. Yet scarcity is at the same time one of those concepts which, like the notion of the standard of living, seems readily accessible, transparent, indeed available almost pre-theoretically. So universal, so ready-to-hand does the notion of scarcity appear that we may be tempted to allow it to enter our theoretical lexicon unexamined.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Archives Européenes de Sociology 1994

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

(1) Menger, (Carl), Principles of Economics, translated by Dingwall, James and Hoselitz, Bert F. (New York: New York University Press, 1976), 9496, 98–9, 100–101, 289–90Google Scholar. On scarcity and the economizing explanation of human behavior see also Becker, Gary S., The Economic Approach to Human Behavior (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976), 314.Google Scholar

(2) Hume, (David), A Treatise of Human Nature, Selby-Bigge, L.A., ed. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1973), p. 495Google Scholar and see Rawls, John, A Theory of Justice (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1971), 126127.Google Scholar

(3) Schumpeter, (Joseph), History of Economic Analysis, ed. by Boody Schumpeter, Elizabeth (New York: Oxford University Press, 1954), p. 57Google Scholar and on Aristotle's supposed ideological bent see p. 59–60 and Veyne, Paul, Le pain et le cirque (Paris: Éditions du Seuil, 1976), p. 175CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On Aristotle as the ‘prehistory’ of economic thought see Blaug, Mark, Economic Theory in Retrospect, 4th ed. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), p. 29.Google Scholar

(4) See for example Arendt, (Hannah), The Human Condition (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1969), 2730.Google Scholar

(5) See for example Pearson, (Harry W.), The Economy has no Surplus: Critique of a Theory of Development, in Trade and Market in the Early Empires, edited by Polanyi, Karl, Arensberg, Conrad M. and Pearson, Harry W. (New York: The Free Press, 1957)Google Scholar; Polanyi, Karl, The Economy as Instituted Process; Aristotle Discovers the Economy, both in Trade and Market in the Early Empires and K. Polanyi, The Livelihood of Man (New York: Academic Press, 1977)Google Scholar. I discuss the moral economic approach at length in my On the Idea of the Moral Economy, American Political Science Review (September 1994) and A Note on the Idea of the Moral Economy, American Political Science Review 87 (1993), 949954.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

(6) Menger (Carl), Principles of Economics, 94–6, 98–9, 100–101, 289–90. North, Douglass C., Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: W.W. Norton, 1981), 105106, 181Google Scholar; North, Douglass C., Markets and Other Allocation Systems in History: The Challenge of Karl Polanyi, Journal of European Economic History 6 (1977), 703716, 708–11Google Scholar; Gunderson, Gerald A., Economic Behavior in the Ancient World, Explorations in the New Economic History: Essays in Honor of Douglass C. North, edited by Ransom, Roger L., Sutch, Richard and Walton, Gary W. (New York: Academic Press, 1982), p. 237nGoogle Scholar; Lowry, S. Todd, Recent Literature on Ancient Greek Economic Thought, The Journal of Economic Literature 17 (1979), 6586Google Scholar; for related analysis see Posner, Richard A., The Economics of Justice (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1983), chs. 5–8.Google Scholar

(7) The passages are from respectively Hesiod, Works and Days, 585ff in Hesiod: Theogony. Works and Days. Shield, translated by Athanassakis, A.N. (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1983)Google Scholar, and Athenaeus, , The Deipnosophists, vi.270b in The Deipnosophists, 7 vols., translated by Gulick, C. B. (Cambridge MA: Loeb Classical Library, 1929).Google Scholar

(8) Athenaeus, The Deipnosophists vi.268b, d and see also 267e–f.

(9) See Weil, (Raymond), Deux notes sur Aristote et l'esclavage, in Revue philosophique de la France et de l'étranger, 172 (1982), 339344, 340Google Scholar; Baldry, H.C., The Idler's Paradise in Antic Comedy in Greece and Rome, 22 (1953), 4960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

(10) Aristotle, , Nicomachean Ethics, translated by Rackham, H. (Cambridge MA: Loeb Classical Library, 1982), 1133a261133a27Google Scholar and (pseudo) Aristotle, , Économique, translated by Wartelle, André (Paris: Les Belles-Lettres, 1968), I.1.2.Google Scholar

(11) Xenophon, , Oeconomicus, translated by Lord, Carnes, in Leo Strauss, Xenophon's Socratic Discourse (Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press, 1970), ii.1, 10.Google Scholar

(12) Aristotle, , Politics, translated by Lord, Carnes (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1984), 1253b241253a25, 1256b29–30, 1256b33–4, 1265a33ff, 1323b7–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, 1179a1ff.

(13) Aristotle, Politics, 1254a5ff.

(14) Aristotle, Politics, 1253b24–5, 1256b29–30, 1256b33–4, 1265a33ff, 1323b7–10; Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, 1179a1ff.

(15) The classical expression in antiquity of this part of the Midas fable is to be found in Ovid, , Metamorphoses, xi.100156 translated by Miller, Frank J., Ovid in Six Volumes, vol. 4 (London: W. Heinemann. Loeb Classical Library, 1976).Google Scholar

(16) Herodotus, , The History, translated by Grene, David (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1987), I.32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

(17) Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, 1133a19ff. ‘Framework of the community’ translates Edouard Will's suggestion for en…tais koinōniais in Will, , De l'aspect éthique des origines grecques de la monnaie, Revue historique 212 (1954), 209231, 215.Google Scholar

(18) Aristotle, , Rhetoric in The Complete Works of Aristotle, ed. Barnes, Jonathan, 2 vols. (vol. 2) (Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press, 1984), 1360a18ff.Google Scholar

(19) See (pseudo) Aristotle, Économique, II.I.1. and on the city as a vast oikos see Paul Veyne, Le pain et le cirque, p. 192; Gernet, Louis, L'approvisionnement d'Athènes en blé au 5e et au 4e siècle (New York: Arno Press, 1979), p. 348Google Scholar; Humphreys, S. C., Economy and Society in Classical Athens in Anthropology and the Greeks (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1978), 143144, 155Google Scholar; Karl Polanyi, The Livelihood of Man, p. 41, Ober, Josiah, Mass and Elite in Democratic Athens (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989), p. 212Google Scholar also discusses the family/kinship aspects of the polis.

(20) Gauthier (Philippe), La cité in Gauthier, , ed. Athènes au temps de Périclès (Paris: Hachette, 1964), p. 47Google Scholar. As Max Weber explains: ‘In classical Athens the claims upon [the citizen's] time by the ekklēsia, jury court service…were of proportions which no other differentiated culture in history has ever experienced before or after’, Economy and Society, edited by Roth, Guenther and Wittich, Claus, translated by Fischoff, Ephraim et al. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978), (2 vols), vol. 2, p. 1361Google Scholar. On the subsistence dimension of the polis economy see Garnsey, Peter, Famine and Food Supply in the Greco-Roman World: Responses to Risk and Crisis (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Aristotle, Politics, 1293a5–7 and Aristotle, , The Constitution of Athens, translated by Moore, J. M., in Aristotle and Xenophon on Democracy and Oligarchy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975), xxiv.3 and xxvii.3, xli.3 and lxii.2.Google Scholar

(21) Xenophon, , Ways and Means, in Scripta Minora, translated by Marchant, E.C. (London: W. Heinemann. Loeb Classical Library, 1946), iv.33Google Scholar. Gauthier, Philippe, Un commentaire historique des Poroi de Xénophon (Paris: Librairie Minard, 1976), x, 20–1, 23, 85, 168, 240, 244Google Scholar. On misthos as civic salary see also Will, , Notes sur Misthos, in Le monde grec: Hommages à Claire Préaux, edited by Bingen, Jean, Cambier, Guy and Nachtergael, Georges (Brussels: Éditions de l'Université de Bruxelles, 1975)Google Scholar. See also Ober, Mass and Elite in Democratic Athens, p. 202 for a discussion of Demosthenes' proposal for a still more extensive welfare system.

(22) Lysias, , Orations, translated by Lamb, W.R.M. (London: William Heinemann. Loeb Classical Library, 1930), xxxi.6, 7.Google Scholar

(23) Aristotle, Politics, 1255b33ff.

(24) Aristotle, , Magna Moralia, translated by Armstrong, G. Cyril (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1935), 1198b12ff. and Aristotle, Politics, 1255b35–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

(25) Archaic and classical Greek marriages are analyzed in Sealey, Raphael, Women and Law in Classical Greece (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1990)Google Scholar; on the treatment of women as objects of the marriage contract see p. 25, 33. Also valuable is Cantarella, Eva, Pandora's Daughters. The Role & Status of Women in Greek & Roman Antiquity, translated by Fant, Maureen B. (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1987).Google Scholar

(26) Xenophon, , Oeconomicus, xii.1113, xiii.9, xiv.6, 9.Google Scholar

(27) Xenophon, , Ways and Means, i.1.Google Scholar

(28) Xenophon, , Ways and Means, ii. 2, 5, 6, 7; iii.3–4.Google Scholar

(29) See Xenophon, , Ways and Means, iii.14, iv.17.Google Scholar

(30) Qualified suggestions as to the novelty of Xenophon's economic theory are to be found in Mossé, Claude, Xénophon économiste, in Le monde grec: Hommages à Claire Préaux, ed. by Bingen, Jean et al. (Brussels: Éditions de l'Université de Bruxelles, 1975)Google Scholar and in Le 4e Siècle, in Le monde grec et l'Orient, vol. 2, edited by Will, Edouard (Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1975), p. 108.Google Scholar

(31) Xenophon, , Ways and Means, iv.34, vi.1.Google Scholar

(32) Xenophon, , Ways and Means, iv.17.Google Scholar

(33) Aristotle, Politics, 1291a10, 1319a31ff., 1321a5–6, 1329a36ff., 1330a26–7.

(34) Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, 1133a23ff. and Finley, Moses I., Aristotle and Economic Analysis, in Studies in Ancient Society, edited by Finley, M. I. (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1974), 34, 38–39Google Scholar; Will, Origines grecques de la monnaie, 218–20.

(35) Xenophon, , Oeconomicus, vii ff; ix.15; xii.4; xiii.4; xiv.4; xxi.2.Google Scholar

(36) Xenophon, , Oeconomicus, vii.7, 23–29.Google Scholar

(37) Aristotle, Nicomackean Ethics, 1094a–1095a; 1095a16–17, 1095b19–21, 1096a6–8.

(38) I discuss the relationship between ancient Greek economic theory and the critique of democracy in Household and Market. On the Origins of Moral Economic Philosophy, Review of Politics (April 1994).

(39) Xenophon, , Oeconomicus, ii.49, 10.Google Scholar

(40) Xenophon, , Oeconomicus, ii.13.Google Scholar

(41) Aristotle, Politics, 1253b25, 31; 1256b31–33; 1265a33ff; Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, 1096a6ff.

(42) Aristotle, Politics, 1265a33; Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, 1096aff and Xenophon, , Oeconamicus, i.1723.Google Scholar

(43) Sen, (Amartya), On Ethics and Economics (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987), p. 2ff.Google Scholar

(44) An extended treatment of some of these themes can be found in my Households. On the Moral Architecture of the Economy (Cornell University Press, 1993).Google Scholar