Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T17:15:58.290Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Turning Wages into Capital Differentiation on the Market for Unsecured Loans in the United States, 1900-1945

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 November 2021

Simon Bittmann*
Affiliation:
CNRS – Université de Strasbourg [[email protected]].
Get access

Abstract

In this article, we show how interpretive battles about compliance can lead to regulatory differentiation and, in turn, market segmentation. To do so, we study the evolution of unsecured lending in the United States, between 1900 and 1945. In the early 20th century, a large segment of the workforce relied on their wages to access credit: this required the “legal coding” of labor income into capital, where lenders would offer advances in exchange for a lien over future revenues. Regulating these transactions raised conflicts between Progressive reformers, lenders and, after 1929, federal regulators, which spanned over five decades. The historical comparison of three states—Illinois, New York and Georgia—, shows that local discussions revolved around three outcomes—legal status, pricing method and collateralization—, the issue of which led to distinct regulatory paths and market configurations at the state level. Finally, the New Deal policies created an additional strand of federal coding, furthering market divides between unregulated payday lenders, non-bank credit companies, and commercial banks. On financial markets, discussions about compliance often revolve around calculative technologies, and we suggest this as a possible crossing point between STS analyses of capitalization devices and Pistor’s theory of capital modulation.

Résumé

Résumé

Dans cet article, nous montrons comment les batailles interprétatives relatives à la conformité (compliance) peuvent conduire à une différentiation réglementaire et, par suite, à une segmentation du marché. Pour ce faire, nous étudions l’évolution des prêts personnels aux États-Unis, entre 1900 et 1945. Au début du xxe siècle, une fraction croissante de travailleurs s’appuient sur leur salaire pour accéder au crédit: cela nécessite le « codage légal » des revenus du travail en capital, un processus permis par l’intermédiation de prêteurs qui offrent des avances en échange d’un droit de saisie. La réglementation de ces transactions soulève de nombreux conflits, à cheval sur cinq décennies, entre différents réformateurs progressistes, les prêteurs et, après 1929, les régulateurs fédéraux. L’analyse historique comparative de trois États – l’Illinois, New York et la Géorgie – montre que les discussions locales ont porté sur trois dimensions – le statut juridique et le prix de ces crédits, ainsi que le collatéral fourni – dont l’issue a conduit ceux-ci sur des trajectoires juridique et marchande divergentes. Enfin, les politiques du New Deal créent une strate supplémentaire de codage au niveau fédéral, accentuant les divisions du marché entre prêteurs sur salaire non réglementés, agences de crédit non-bancaires et banques commerciales. Sur les marchés financiers, les débats autour de la conformité concernent souvent les technologies de calcul, et nous suggérons cela comme un point de rencontre entre les analyses de sociologie des sciences, portant sur le processus de capitalisation, et celles proposées par Katharina Pistor, autour de la notion de codage juridique.

Zusammenfassung

Zusammenfassung

In diesem Artikel zeigen wir, wie Interpretationskämpfe um die Einhaltung von Vorschriften zu einer regulatorischen Differenzierung und damit zu einer Marktsegmentierung führen können. Dazu untersuchen wir die Entwicklung der unbesicherten Kreditvergabe in den Vereinigten Staaten in den Jahren zwischen 1900 und 1945. Im frühen 20. Jahrhundert war ein Großteil der Arbeiterschaft auf Löhne angewiesen, um Zugang zu Krediten zu erhalten: Dies erforderte die „legale Kodierung“ von Arbeitseinkommen in Kapital, bei der Kreditgeber Vorschüsse im Austausch für ein Pfandrecht auf zukünftige Einnahmen anboten. Die Regulierung dieser Transaktionen führte zu Konflikten zwischen fortschrittlichen Reformern, Kreditgebern und, nach 1929, den Bundesaufsichtsbehörden, die mehr als fünf Jahrzehnte andauerten. Ein historischer Vergleich dreier Bundesstaaten – Illinois, New York und Georgia - zeigt, dass sich die lokalen Diskussionen um drei Ergebnisse drehten - rechtlicher Status, Preisbildungsmethode und Sicherheiten –, die zu unterschiedlichen Regulierungswegen und Marktkonfigurationen auf bundesstaatlicher Ebene führten. Schließlich schuf die Politik des New Deal eine zusätzliche Ebene staatlicher Kodierung, die die Marktaufteilung zwischen unregulierten Zahltagskreditgebern, Nicht-Bank-Kreditunternehmen und Geschäftsbanken vertiefte. Auf den Finanzmärkten drehen sich die Diskussionen über Compliance oft um Computertechnologien, und wir schlagen vor, dass dies eine mögliche Schnittstelle zwischen den Analysen der Wissenschafts- und Technologiestudien zu Kapitalisierungsschemata und Katharina Pistor‘s Theorie der Kapitalmodulation darstellt.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© European Journal of Sociology 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Amsterdam, Daniel, 2016. Roaring Metropolis: Businessmen’s Campaign for a Civic Welfare State (Philadelphia, University of Pennsylvania Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Elizabeth, 2008. “Experts, Ideas, and Policy Change: the Russell Sage Foundation and Small Loan Reform, 1909-1941,” Theory and Society, 37 (3): 271310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Elizabeth, Carruthers, Bruce G. and Guinnane, Timothy W., 2015. “An Unlikely Alliance: How Experts and Industry Transformed Consumer Credit Policy in the Early Twentieth Century United States,” Social Science History, 39, 4: 581612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angeletti, Thomas, 2017. “Finance on Trial: Rules and Justifications in the Libor Case,” European Journal of Sociology, 58 (1): 113141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aspers, Patrick, Bengtsson, Peter and Dobeson, Alexander, 2020. “Market Fashioning,” Theory and Society, 49: 417438.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Batlan, Felice, 2015. Women and Justice for the Poor: A History of Legal Aid, 1863-1945 (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckert, Jens, 2013. “Imagined Futures: Fictional Expectations in the Economy,” Theory and Society, 42 (3): 219240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birch, Kean, 2017. “Rethinking Value in the Bio-Economy: Finance, Assetization, and the Management of Value,” Science, Technology, & Human Values, 42 (3): 460490.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Birch, Kean and Muniesa, Fabian, eds, 2020. Assetization: Turning Things into Assets in Technoscientific Capitalism (Cambridge, Cambridge MIT Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bittmann, Simon, 2019. “De l’‘usure’ en Amérique. La transformation des politiques du crédit du progressisme au New Deal, 1903-1938,” Genèses, 117 (4): 4973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bittmann, Simon, 2020a. “Le temps du crédit. Endettement et stratification sociale en Illinois dans les années 1910,” Annales. Histoire, sciences sociales, 75 (2): 285319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bittmann, Simon, 2020b. “Comment une entreprise répond à ses critiques ? Une analyse longitudinale du cas Household Finance aux États-Unis, 1910-1941,” Revue française de sociologie, 61 (4): 673700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Julia, 2013. “Reconceiving Financial Markets—From the Economic to the Social,” Journal of Corporate Law Studies, 13, 2: 401442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calder, Lendol, 1999. Financing the American Dream (Princeton, Princeton University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carruthers Bruce, G. and Stinchcombe, Arthur L., 1999. “The Social Structure of Liquidity: Flexibility, Markets, and States,” Theory and Society, 28, 3: 353382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carruthers Bruce, G., Guinnane, Timothy W. and Lee, Youngsook, 2012. “Bringing ‘honest capital’ to poor borrowers: the passage of the US Uniform Small Loan Law, 1907-1930”. Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 42, 3: 393418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chapman, John C., 1940. Commercial Banks and Consumer Instalment Credit (Cambridge, NBER Books).Google Scholar
Coppock, Joseph D., 1940. Government Agencies of Consumer Instalment Credit (Cambridge, NBER Books).Google Scholar
Dauer, Ernst A., 1944. Comparative Operating Experience of Consumer Instalment Financing Agencies and Commercial Banks, 1929-41 (Cambridge, NBER Books).Google Scholar
Deringer, William, 2017. “Pricing the Future in the Seventeenth Century: Calculating Technologies in Competition,” Technology and Culture, 58, 2: 506528.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dobbin, F., 2009. Inventing Equal Opportunity (Princeton, Princeton University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doganova, Liliana, 2014. “Décompter le futur,” Sociétés contemporaines, 93, 1: 6787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donovan, Brian 2010. White Slave Crusades: Race, Gender, and Anti-Vice Activism, 1887-1917 (Champaign, University of Illinois Press).Google Scholar
Easterly, Michael, 2010. Your Job is Your Credit: Creating a Market for Loans to Salaried Employees in New York City, 1885-1920, PhD, History, UCLA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edelman, Lauren B., Krieger, Linda H., Eliason, Scott R., Albiston, Catherine R. and Mellema, Virginia, 2011. “When Organizations Rule: Judicial Deference to Institutionalized Employment Structures,” American Journal of Sociology, 117, 3: 888954.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edelman, Lauren B. and Stryker, Robyn, 2005. “A Sociological Approach to Law and the Economy,” in Smelser, Neil J. and Swedberg, Richard, eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton University Press: 527551).Google Scholar
Fleming, Anne, 2018a. “The Long History of ‘Truth in Lending’,” Journal of Policy History, 30, 2: 236271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleming, Anne, 2018b. City of Debtors (Harvard, Harvard University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fourcade, Marion, 2011. “Cents and Sensibility: Economic Valuation and the Nature of ‘Nature’,” American Journal of Sociology, 116, 6: 17211777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fourcade, Marion and Healy, Kieran, 2007. “Moral Views of Market Society,” Annual Review of Sociology, 33: 285311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Funk, Russel J. and Hirschman, Daniel, 2014. “Derivatives and Deregulation: Financial Innovation and the Demise of Glass–Steagall,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 59, 4: 669704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glenn John, M., Brandt, Lilian and Andrews, F. Emerson, 1947. Russell Sage Foundation 1907-1946 (vol. 1 & 2) (New York, Russell Sage Foundation).Google Scholar
Gray, Garry C. and Silbey, Susan S., 2014. “Governing Inside the Organization: Interpreting Regulation and Compliance,” American Journal of Sociology, 120, 1: 96145.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gulati, Ranjay, 1995. “Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in Alliances,” Academy of Management Journal, 38, 1: 85112.Google Scholar
Huertas, Thomas F. and Silverman, Joan L., 1986. “Charles E. Mitchell: Scapegoat of the Crash?,” Business History Review, 60, 1: 81103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyman, Louis 2012. Debtor Nation: The History of America in Red Ink (Princeton, Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Keire, Mara L., 2010. For Business and Pleasure: Red-Light Districts and the Regulation of Vice in the United States, 1890-1933 (Baltimore, John Hopkins University Press).Google Scholar
Kessler, Amalia D., 2005. “Our inquisitorial tradition: Equity procedure, due process, and the search for an alternative to the adversarial,” Cornell Law Review, 90, 1: 11811276.Google Scholar
Lauer, Josh, 2017. Creditworthy: A History of Consumer Surveillance and Financial Identity in America (New York, Columbia University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laurie, B., 1997. Artisans into Workers: Labor in Nineteenth-Century America (Champaign, University of Illinois Press).Google Scholar
Mahoney, James and Thelen, Kathleen, eds, 2009. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marquis, Christopher and Lounsbury, Michael, 2007. “Vive la Résistance: Competing Logics and the Consolidation of U.S. Community Banking,” Academy of Management Journal, 50, 4: 799820.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marquis, Christopher, Huang, Zhi and Almandoz, Juan, 2011. “Explaining the Loss of Community: Competing Logics and Institutional Change in the U.S. Banking Industry,” in Marquis, Christopher, Lounsbury, Michael and Greenwood, Royston, eds, Communities and Organizations (Bingley, Emerald Group Publishing: 177213).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, Karl, [1867] 2015. Capital. A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 1, transl. by Moore, Samuel and Aveling, Edward (Moscow, Progress Publisher).Google Scholar
McCaffrey, David P., Smith, Amy E. and Martinez-Moyano, Ignacio J., 2007. “‘Then Let’s Have a Dialogue’: Interdependence and Negotiation In a Cohesive Regulatory System,” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 17, 2: 307334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muniesa, Fabian, Doganova, Liliana, Ortiz, Horacia, Pina-Stranger, Alvaro, Paterson, Florence, Bourgoin, Alaric, Ehrenstein, Vera, Juven, Pierre-André, Pontille, David, Sarac-Lesavre, Basak and Yon, Guillaume, eds, 2017. Capitalization: A Cultural Guide (Paris, Presse des Mines).Google Scholar
Njoya, Wanjiru, 2007. Property in Work: The Employment Relationship in the Anglo-American Firm (Aldershot, Ashgate).Google Scholar
O’Connor, Alice, 2007. Social Science for What? Philanthropy and the Social Question in a World Turned Rightside Up (New York, Russell Sage Foundation).Google Scholar
Pedriana, Nicola, 2006. “From Protective to Equal Treatment: Legal Framing Processes and Transformation of the Women’s Movement in the 1960s,” American Journal of Sociology, 111, 6: 17181761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pedriana, Nicola and Stryker, Robyn, 2004. “The Strength of a Weak Agency: Enforcement of Title VII of the 1964 Civil Rights Act and the Expansion of State Capacity, 1965-1971,” American Journal of Sociology, 110, 3: 709760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pistor, Katarina, 2019. The Code of Capital: How the Law Creates Wealth and Inequality (Princeton, Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Plummer, Wilbur C., 1940. Sales Finance Companies and Their Credit Practices (Cambridge, NBER Books).Google Scholar
Poon, Martha, 2009. “From New Deal Institutions to Capital Markets: Commercial Consumer Risk Scores and the Making of Subprime Mortgage Finance,” Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 5: 654674.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rao, Hayagreeva, 2008. Market Rebels: How Activists Make or Break Radical Innovations (Princeton, Princeton University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Louise N. and Stearns, Maud E., 1930. Ten Thousand Small Loans: Facts about Borrowers in 109 Cities in 17 States (New York, Russell Sage Foundation Press).Google Scholar
Rockoff, Hugh, 2003. Prodigals and Projecture: An Economic History of Usury Laws in the United States from Colonial Times to 1900 (National Bureau of Economic Research, N° 9742).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepard, Kris, 2009. Rationing Justice: Poverty Lawyers and Poor People in the Deep South (Baton Rouge, Louisiana State University Press).Google Scholar
Soederberg, Susan, 2014. Debtfare States and the Poverty Industry: Money, Discipline and the Surplus Population (London, Routledge).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thiemann, Matthias and Lepoutre, Jan, 2017. “Stitched on the Edge: Rule evasion, Embedded Regulators, and the Evolution of Markets,” American Journal of Sociology, 122, 6: 17751821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trumbull, Gunnar, 2014. Consumer Lending in France and America: Credit and Welfare (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uzzi, Brian, 1999. “Embeddedness in the Making of Financial Capital: How Social Relations and Networks Benefit Firms Seeking Financing,” American Sociological Review, 64, 4: 481505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Max, (1922) 1978. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology (Berkeley, University of California Press).Google Scholar
Willrich, Michael, 2003. City of Courts: Socializing Justice in Progressive Era Chicago (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar