Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T18:51:52.315Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

International Financial Institutions and Financial Accountability

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 September 2012

Abstract

While useful proposals to reform International Financial Institutions (IFIs) have been widely discussed, the lack of meaningful financial accountability has received little attention. Considering the substantial damage done by IFIs, this is surprising both from an ethical and an economist's point of view. In a market economy anyone must face the economic consequences of their actions and decisions. If consultants give advice negligently or without obeying minimal professional standards, they have to pay compensation for the damage they have caused. National liability and tort laws serve the purpose of compensating those suffering unlawful damages and of deterring such behavior. By contrast, tortious damage caused by IFIs must be paid by IFIs' borrowers, including many of the world's poorest people. IFIs may even gain financially from their own negligence by extending new loans necessary to repair damages done by their prior loans. One failed adjustment program calls for the next. This mechanism makes IFI-flops generate IFI-jobs and additional income. This perverted incentive system rewarding errors, negligence, and even violations of the very constitutions of IFIs is absolutely at odds with the principles on which Western market economies rest. It must be brought to an end. This essay presents the idea of financial accountability, showing how easily reforms making IFIs financially accountable could be implemented. Moreover, embracing financial accountability would bring IFI operations closer to the intentions of their founders, who wanted IFIs subject to the basic legal and economic concepts of financial accountability not exempt from it. The market mechanism and its beneficial incentive system must finally be brought to IFIs.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Carnegie Council for Ethics in International Affairs 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Buira, Ariel , “Reforming the Governance of the Bretton Woods Institutions,” in OPEC Fund for International Development, ed., Financing for Development, Pamphlet Series no. 33 (Vienna: OPEC Fund, 2002), p. 213 – 57Google Scholar. Over the years the democratic representation component of the Bretton Woods institutions—the basic votes given to each member equally—has been perceptibly diminished by capital increases. The basic votes, which were, e.g., 12.4% of the IMF's total voting power at Bretton Woods, are now 2.1%. In response, changes of voting rights and the representation of members by executive directors were demanded as both strongly disadvantage developing countries. The search for a new managing director after Kohler's resignation brought the IMF's selection procedures under unprecedented critique.

2 Ngaire Woods, in “The Challenges of Good Governance for the IMF and the World Bank Themselves,” World Development 28, no. 5 (2000), pp. 823–41, has proposed special majorities or double majorities differentiating between the stakes countries hold in IFIs. More recently, in “Holding Intergovernmental Institutions to Account,” Ethics & International Affairs 17, no. 1 (2003), pp. 69–80, she has advocated greater constitutional, internal, and political accountability of IFIs.Google Scholar

3 On the performance of multilateral development banks, see Raffer, Kunibert and Singer, HW, The Foreign Aid Business, Economic Assistance and Development Co-operation (Brookfield, Vi: Edward Elgar, 1996), pp. 175 ff;Google Scholaron the IDE, see Task Force on Management, Portfolio, Managing for Effective Development: Report of the Task Force on Portfolio Management for the Inter-American Development Bank (Washington, D.C.: IDE, 1993Google Scholar).

4 Raffer, Kunibert , “ Applying Chapter 9 Insolvency to International Debts: An Economically Efficient Solution with a Human Face ,” World Development 18, no. 2 (1990 ), pp. 301ff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Raffer, K., “International Financial Institutions and Accountability: The Need for Drastic Change,” in Murshed, S. M. and Raffer, K., eds., Trade, Transfers and Development, Problems and Prospects for the Twenty-First Century (Brookfield, Vi: Edward Elgar, 1993), pp. 151ffGoogle Scholar; available at http://homepage.unvie.ac.at/Kunibert.Raffer; and Raffer, K., “Good Governance, Accountability, and Official Development Co-operation: Analyzing OECD-Demands at the Example of the IBRD,” in Ginther, K., Denters, E., and de Waart, P.J.I.M., eds., Sustainable Development and Good Governance (Dordrecht: Martinus Nijhoff/Kluwer, 1995), pp. 343ffGoogle Scholar. No other author has taken up this problem. Woods (2003) uses the term “financial accountability” but refers to the political accountability visa vis members that finance IFIs. In my terminology that would be political accountability.

5 Documenting failures of the Bretton Woods institutions has developed into a cottage industry. Among the more widely known books are Caufield, Catherine, Masters of Illusion: The World Bank and the Poverty of Nations (London: Pan, 1998Google Scholar); George, Susan and Sabelli, Fabrizio, Faith and Credit: The World Bank's Secular Empire (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1995Google Scholar); and Rich, Bruce, Mortgaging the Earth: The World Bank, Environmental Impoverishment and the Crisis of Development (Boston: Earthscan/Beacon, 1994)Google Scholar. Arguably even more damaging are internal documents of which the Wapenhans Report is still the best known but by no means only example. See Bank, World, “Effective Implementation: Key to Development Impact,” Report of the Portfolio Management Task Force (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1992Google Scholar).

6 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development , “ DAC Orientations on Participatory Development and Good Governance ” ( Paris: OECD, 1993Google Scholar), para. 3, p. 2; available at http://www.acdi-cida.gc.ca/INET/IMAGES.NSF/vLUImages/HRDG/$ffle/Dace.pdf.

7 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Development Co-operation, Efforts and Policies of the Members of the Development Assistance Committee: 1997 Report (Paris: OECD, 1998 ), p. 22Google Scholar.

8 Raffer, “International Financial Institutions and Accountability,” p. 158Google Scholar.

9 “En Alemania, un fallo judicial apunta a un banco por los bonos, Un tribunal dispuso que un cliente sea indemnizado por haber side mal asesorado,” Clarin.com, October 29, 2003; available at http://old.clarin.com/diario/2003/10/29/p-00601.htm.

10 Gapper, John and Gourlay, Richard , “ Damages Win Leads Lloyds to Rethink Advice ,” Financial Times, September 5, 1995, p. 9Google Scholar.

11 Stiglitz, Joseph , “ What I Learned at the World Economic Crisis: The Insider ,” New Republic, April 17, 2000, pp. 5659Google Scholar.

12 See, e.g., OECD, Development Co-operation, Efforts and Policies of the Members of the Development Assistance Committee, pp. 18ff. or pp. 67ffGoogle Scholar.

13 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development , “ Toward Sustained Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Program of Action ” ( Washington,, D.C.: IBRD, 1984 ), p. 24Google Scholar.

14 Winters, Jeffrey A. , “ Criminal Debt,” Written statement, “Combating Corruption in the Multilateral Development Banks,” Hearing before the Committee on Foreign Relations, U.S. Senate, 108th Congress, 2nd session, May 13, 2004; available at http://foreign.senate.gov/testimony/2004/WintersTestimony040503.pdfGoogle Scholar. At a conference at Northwestern University in 1999, IBRD staff objected vigorously, claiming that losses to corruption were lower, 20–25% at most.

15 Mosley, Paul, Harrigan, Jane, and Toye, John, Aid and Power: The World Bank and Policy Based Lending, vol. 1 (London: Routledge, 1991 ), p. 24Google Scholar.

16 Wade, Robert , “ From Miracle to Meltdown: Vulnerabilities, Moral Hazard, Panic and Debt Deflation in the Asian Crisis ” (paper presented at East Asia Crisis Workshop, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, Sussex, June i, 1998); available at http://www.ids.ac.uk/ids/global/Conf7pdfs/wade.pdfGoogle Scholar.

18 IBRD, 1998 Annual Review of Development Effectiveness, OED (Washington,, D.C.: IBRD, 1999 ), p. 2Google Scholar; available at http://Inweb18.worldbank.org/oed/oeddoclib.nsf/11d38e62C269811285256808006a0022/56f24588862d25d8852567f200568e93/$FILE/arde98.pdf.

22 See the IMF's Articles of Agreement at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/aa/.

23 Raffer, Kunibert and Singer, H. W., The Economic North-South Divide: Six Decades of Unequal Development (Northampton, Mass.: Edward Elgar, 2001 ), p. 157CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 Fischer, Stanley , “ Capital Account Liberalization and the Role of the IMF ” ( paper presented at the IMF seminar “Asia and the IMF,” Hong Kong, September 19, 1997); available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/apd/asia/fischer.htm .Google Scholar

26 Caufield, , Masters of Illusion , p. 319Google Scholar.

27 IBRD, World Debt Tables 1992–93, vol. 1 (Washington,, D.C.: IBRD, 1992Google Scholar), pp. 10ff (emphasis in original).

28 Krueger, Anne , “ International Financial Architecture for 2002: A New Approach to Sovereign Debt Restructuring ” ( address given at the National Economists’ Club Annual Members’ Dinner, American Enterprise Institute, Washington, D.C., November 26,2001); available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/112601.htm .Google Scholar

29 See Raffer, , “International Financial Institutions and Accountability”; and Raffer, “Good Governance, Accountability, and Official Development Co-operation.”Google Scholar

30 See Agreement Establishing the Inter-American Development Bank; available at http://www.iadb.org/leg/Documents/Pdf7Convenio-Eng.pdf.

31 See Agreement Establishing the Asian Development Bank; available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/Reports/Charter/charter.pdf.

32 An e-mail to the AfDB (April 7, 2004, 14:20:06) describing the problem and asking for the legal text was received according to the Bank's computer but has remained unanswered.

34 As recommended by Raffer and Singer, The Foreign Aid Business-, pp. 209ffGoogle Scholar.

35 International Monetary Fund, “Executive Board Reviews IMF's Income Position,” Public Information Notice no. 03/64 (May 22, 2003); available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pn/2003/pn0364.htm.

36 Ibid, (emphasis in original)Google Scholar.

37 Boughton, James M. , “ Digging a Hole, Filling It In: Payments Arrears to the Fund ,” in Boughton, James M., Silent Revolution: The International Monetary Fund 1979–1989 (Washington,, D.C.: IMF, 2001 ), p. 814Google Scholar; available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/history/2001/ch16.pdf.

38 International Monetary Fund, “Executive Board Reviews IMF's Income Position,” p. 3.Google Scholar

40 International Monetary Fund, “Financial Risk in the Fund and the Level of Precautionary Balances,” February 3, 2004, p. 26; available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/tre/risk/2004/020304.pdf.

41 I first proposed the idea of a court of arbitration to ensure financial accountability for projects in 1993. See Raffer, “International Financial Institutions and Accountability.”Google Scholar

42 I have proposed nearly the same procedure in my model of sovereign Chapter 9 insolvency. See Raffer, “Applying Chapter 9 Insolvency to International Debts.”Google Scholar

43 The IMF would have to waive its immunity, but is empowered to do soGoogle Scholar.

44 For details, see Raffer, Kunibert, “Introducing Financial Accountability at the IBRD: An Overdue and Necessary Reform” (paper presented at the conference “Reinventing the World Bank,” Northwestern University, Evanston, 111., May 14–16,1999); available at http://homepage.univie.ac.at/Kunibert.Raffer.Google Scholar

45 I recommend ad hoc panels as part of my model of sovereign debt arbitration because in that case there is hope that any standing institution will become severely underemployed once the backlog of cases of debt-distressed sovereigns are solvedGoogle Scholar.

46 Helping poor people from the South with advice and financial resources in the preparation of complaints would be a useful task for NGOsGoogle Scholar.

47 International Monetary Fund and IDA , “ Debt Sus-tainability in Low-Income Countries—Proposal for an Operational Framework and Policy Implications ,” February 3, 2004, p. 13Google Scholar; available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sustain/2004/020304.pdf.

49 Designing a fair and humane solution to the sovereign debt crisis in the late 1980s, I proposed this easy way to hold IFIs financially accountable. To the best of my knowledge it was the first time financial accountability of IFIs was brought up. This equal treatment provision has remained a fundamental feature of my sovereign insolvency model. See Raffer, “Applying Chapter 9 Insolvency to International Debts,” pp. 30/ff.; and Raffer, Kunibert, “The IMF's SDRM: Another Form of Simply Disastrous Rescheduling Management?” in Jochnick, Chris and Preston, Fraser, eds., Sovereign Debt at the Crossroads (Oxford: Oxford University Press, forthcoming).Google Scholar

50 International Monetary Fund , “ Overdue Payments: IMF strategy focuses on prevention, cooperation, remedial measures, and deterrence ,” IMF Survey Supplement, September 2001, p. 21Google Scholar; available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/2001/090101.pdf.

51 Caufield, , Masters of Illusion , p. 319Google Scholar.

52 Ibid., p. 323Google Scholar.

53 Boughton, “Digging a Hole, Filling It In,” p. 820Google Scholar.

55 Ibid., p. 821Google Scholar.

56 Raffer, “The IMF's SDRM: Another Form of Simply Disastrous Rescheduling Management?”Google Scholar

57 International Monetary Fund , “ Financial Statements, Quarter Ended January 31, 2004 ,” p. 8; available at http://www.imf.org/externaVpubs/ft/quart/2004ry/013104.pdfGoogle Scholar.

58 Compared with 1999 this is a steep increase: on April 30 the three largest users “only” accounted for 49 percent, the “big five” for 69 percent . See International Monetary Fund, “Financial Statements, Quarter Ended April 30,1999,” p. 10; available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/quart/1999fy/043099.pdfGoogle Scholar.

59 International Monetary Fund , “ Financial Risk in the Fund and the Level of Precautionary Balances ,” February 3, 2004, pp. 24ffGoogle Scholar.

60 Rafter, “The IMF's SDRM.”Google Scholar