Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-12T22:17:43.176Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Sustainability and the measurement of wealth

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 May 2012

Kenneth J. Arrow
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Stanford University, USA. Email: [email protected]
Partha Dasgupta
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Cambridge, UK. Email: [email protected]
Lawrence H. Goulder
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305, USA. Email: [email protected]
Kevin J. Mumford
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Purdue University, USA. Email: [email protected]
Kirsten Oleson
Affiliation:
Department of Natural Resources and Environmental Management, University of Hawaii, USA. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

We develop and apply a consistent and comprehensive theoretical framework for assessing whether economic growth is compatible with sustaining wellbeing over time. Our approach differs from earlier approaches by concentrating on wealth rather than income. Sustainability is demonstrated by showing that a properly defined comprehensive measure of wealth is maintained through time. Our wealth measure is unusually comprehensive, capturing not only reproducible and human capital but also natural capital, health improvements and technological change. We apply the framework to five countries: the United States, China, Brazil, India and Venezuela. We show that the often-neglected contributors to wealth – technological change, natural capital and health capital – fundamentally affect the conclusions one draws about whether given nations are achieving sustainability. Indeed, even countries that display sustainability differ considerably in the kinds of capital that contribute to it.

Type
Focus
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arrow, K.J., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L., Daily, G., Ehrlich, P.R., Heal, G.M., Levin, S., Mäler, K.-G., Schneider, S., Starrett, D.A., and Walker, B. (2004), ‘Are we consuming too much?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(1): 147172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K.J., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L.H., Mumford, K., and Oleson, K. (2007), ‘China, the U.S., and sustainability: perspectives based on comprehensive wealth’, Mimeo, Department of Economics, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Asheim, G. (1997), ‘Adjusting green NNP to measure sustainability’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 99: 355370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G.S., Philipson, T.J., and Soares, R.S. (2005), ‘The quantity and quality of life and the evolution of world inequality’, American Economic Review 95(1): 227291.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
BP (2005), Statistical Review of World Energy, June 2005, [Available at] http://www.bp.com/.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, P. (2001), Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, P. and Mäler, K.-G. (2000), ‘Net national product, wealth, and social well-being’, Environment and Development Economics 5(1): 6993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Food and Agriculture Organization (2006), ‘Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005’, United Nations FAO Forestry Paper No. 147. Rome: FAO.Google Scholar
Hamilton, K. and Clemens, M. (1999), ‘Genuine savings rates in developing countries’, World Bank Economic Review 13(2): 333356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartwick, J.M. (1977), ‘Intergenerational equity and the investing of rents from exhaustible resources’, American Economic Review 66(5): 972974.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. (1940), ‘The valuation of social income’, Economica 7: 105124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houghton, R.A. (2005), ‘Aboveground forest biomass and the global carbon balance’, Global Change Biology 11: 945958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C.I. and Klenow, P.J. (2010), ‘Beyond GDP? Welfare across countries and time’, Working Paper, September, Stanford University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klenow, P.J. and Rodríguez-Clare, A. (1997), ‘The neoclassical revival in growth economics: has it gone too far?’, in Bernanke, B. and Rotemberg, J. (eds), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Klenow, P.J. and Rodríguez-Clare, A. (2005), ‘Externalities and growth’, in Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. (eds), Handbook of Economic Growth, Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Lane, P.R. and Milesi-Ferretti, G.M. (2007), ‘The external wealth of nations Mark II: revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities, 1970–2004’, Journal of International Economics 73(2): 223250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindahl, E.R. (1934), ‘The concept of income’, in Bagge, G. (ed.), Economic Essays in Honor of Gustaf Cassel, London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Murphy, K.M. and Topel, R.H. (2006), ‘The value of health and longevity’, Journal of Political Economy 114(5): 871904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D. (2002), ‘The health of nations: the contribution of improved health to living standards’, NBER Working Paper No. 8818, NBER, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D. and Boyer, J. (2000), Warming the World: Economic Models of Global Warming, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nordhaus, W. and Tobin, J. (1972), ‘Is economic growth obsolete?’, in Economic Growth, 5th Anniversary Colloquium of the NBER, New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Pearce, D.W. and Atkinson, G. (1993), ‘Capital theory and the measurement of sustainable development: an indicator of weak sustainability’, Ecological Economics 8: 103108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pezzey, J. (1992), ‘Sustainable development concepts: an economic analysis’, World Bank Environment Paper No. 2, World Bank: Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Repetto, R., Magrath, W., Wells, M., Beer, C., and Rossini, F. (1989), Wasting Assets: Natural Resources in the National Income Accounts, Washington, DC: World Resources Institute.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. (1961), ‘The evaluation of “social income”: capital formation and wealth’, in Lutz, F.A. and Hague, D.C. (eds), The Theory of Capital, London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Sefton, J. and Weale, M.R. (1996), ‘The net national product and exhaustible resources’, Journal of Public Economics 61: 2147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, R.M. (1974), ‘Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources’, Review of Economic Studies 41 (Symposium Issue): 2945.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tol, R.S.J. (2009), ‘The economic effects of climate change’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(2): 2951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
US Geological Survey (2006), Mineral Commodity Summaries 2006, Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W.K. and Aldy, J.E. (2003), ‘The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world’, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 27(1): 576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bank, World (1997), Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally Sustainable Development, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Bank, World (2006), Where is the Wealth of Nations?, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Bank, World (2011), The Changing Wealth of Nations: Measuring Sustainable Development in the New Millennium, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Commission on Environment and Development (1987), Our Common Future, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar