Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T08:29:08.735Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Social capital dynamics and collective action: the role of subjective satisfaction in a common pool resource experiment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2015

Leonardo Becchetti
Affiliation:
Università di Roma Tor Vergata, Facoltà di Economia, Dipartimento di Economia e Istituzioni, Via Columbia 2, 00133 Roma, Italy. Tel. +39-06-72595706. Fax +39-06-2020500. E-mail: [email protected]
Stefano Castriota
Affiliation:
University of Bolzano, Italy. E-mail: [email protected]
Pierluigi Conzo
Affiliation:
University of Turin & CSEF, Italy. E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

In low-income countries, grassroots collective action for the management of a common environmental resource is a well-known substitute for government provision of public goods. In our research we test experimentally what its effect is on social capital. To this purpose we structure a ‘sandwich’ experiment in which participants play a common pool resource game (CPRG) between two trust games in a Nairobi slum where social capital is scarce but informal rules regulating the commons are abundant. Our findings show that the change in trustworthiness between the two trust game rounds generated by the CPRG experience is crucially affected by the subjective satisfaction about the CPRG, rather than by standard objective measures related to CPRG players' behaviour. These results highlight that subjective satisfaction in a collective action has relevant predictive power on social capital creation, providing information which can be crucial to designing successful self-organized environmental resource regimes.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alesina, A., Baqir, R., and Easterly, W. (1999), ‘Public goods and ethnic divisions’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(4): 12431284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K.J. (1974), The Limits of Organization, 1st edn New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Becchetti, L. and Conzo, P. (2011), ‘Enhancing capabilities through credit access: creditworthiness as a signal of trustworthiness under asymmetric information’, Journal of Public Economics 95(3–4): 265278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becchetti, L., Conzo, P., and Romeo, A. (2013), ‘Violence, social capital and economic development: evidence of a microeconomic vicious circle’, Oxford Economic Papers; doi:10.1093/oep/gpt008.Google Scholar
Becchetti, L., Conzo, P., and Degli Antoni, G. (2015), ‘Public disclosure of players’ conduct and common resources harvesting: experimental evidence from a Nairobi slum', Social Choice and Welfare 45: 7196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beguy, D., Bocquier, P., and Msiyaphazi Zulu, E. (2010), ‘Circular migration patterns and determinants in Nairobi slum settlements’, Demographic Research 23, Art. 20: 549586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., and McCabe, K. (1995), ‘Trust, reciprocity, and social history‘, Games and Economic Behavior 10(1): 122142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blattman, C. and Annan, J. (2010), ‘The consequences of child soldiering’, Review of Economics and Statistics 92(4): 882898.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, I. and Greig, F. (2009), ‘Exploring gendered behavior in the field with experiments: why public goods are provided by women in a Nairobi slum’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 70: 19.Google Scholar
Brandts, J. and Charness, G. (2000), ‘Hot vs. cold: sequential responses and preference stability in experimental games’, Experimental Economics 2: 227238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. and Fehr, E. (2003), ‘Measuring social norms and preferences using experimental games: a guide for social scientists’, David K. Levine's Working Paper Archive, St Louis, MO.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casari, M. and Cason, T.N. (2009), ‘The strategy method lowers measured trustworthy behavior’, Economics Letters 103(3): 157159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T.N. and Mui, V. (1998), ‘Social influence in the sequential dictator game’, Journal of Mathematical Psychology 42(2–3): 248265.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cassar, A. and Wydick, B. (2010), ‘Does social capital matter? Evidence from a five-country group lending experiment’, Oxford Economic Papers 62(4): 715739.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, A.E., Frijters, P., and Shields, M.A. (2006), ‘Income and happiness: evidence, explanations and economic implications’, Working Paper No. 2006–24, Jourdan Sciences Economiques, Paris.Google Scholar
Faye, O., Baschieri, A., Falkingham, J., and Muindi, K. (2011), ‘Hunger and food insecurity in Nairobi's slums: an assessment using IRT models’, Journal of Urban Health 88(2): 235255.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fehr, E. (2009), ‘On the economics and biology of trust’, Journal of the European Economic Association 7(2–3): 235266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Gächter, S. (2002), ‘Altruistic punishment in humans’, Nature 415: 137140.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2005), ‘Income and well-being: an empirical analysis of the comparison income effect,Journal of Public Economics 89: 9971019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., and Fehr, E. (2001), ‘Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment’, Economics Letters 71(3): 397404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B.S. and Stutzer, A. (2002), ‘What can economists learn from happiness research’, Journal of Economic Literature 40(2): 402435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B.S. and Stutzer, A. (2010), ‘Recent advances in the economics of individual subjective well-being’, IZA Discussion Paper No. 4850, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B.S., Benz, M., and Stutzer, A. (2003), ‘Introducing procedural utility: not only what, but also how matters’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 60: 377401.Google Scholar
Fullenkamp, R. and Chami, C. (2002), ‘Trust and efficiency’, Journal of Banking and Finance 26(9): 17851809.Google Scholar
Gradstein, M. and Justman, M. (2002), ‘Education, social cohesion, and economic growth’, American Economic Review 92(4): 11921204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greig, F. and Bohnet, I. (2008), ‘Is there reciprocity in a reciprocal-exchange economy? Evidence of gendered norms from a slum in Nairobi, Kenya’, Economic Inquiry 46(1): 7783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., and Zingales, L. (2004), ‘The role of social capital in financial development’, American Economic Review 94(3): 526557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., and Zingales, L. (2008), ‘Long term persistence’, Chicago GSB Research Paper No. 08-11, Chicago, IL.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J. and Smith, N. (2004), ‘Comparative experimental evidence from Machiguenga, Mapuche, Huinca and American populations shows substantial variation among social groups in bargaining and public goods behavior’, in Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Gintis, H., Fehr, E. and Camerer, C. (eds), Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Smallscale Societies, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 125167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirano, K., Imbens, G.W., and Ridder, G. (2003), ‘Efficient estimation of average treatment effects using the estimated propensity score’, Econometrica 71(4): 11611189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keefer, P. and Knack, S. (1997), ‘Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 12511288.Google Scholar
La Porta, R., Lopez De Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R.W. (1997), ‘Legal determinants of external finance’, Journal of Finance LII(3): 11311150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montalvo, J.G. and Reynal-Querol, M. (2005a), ‘Ethnic diversity and economic development’, Journal of Development Economics 76: 293323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montalvo, J.G. and Reynal-Querol, M. (2005b), ‘Ethnic polarization, potential conflict, and civil wars’, American Economic Review 95(3): 796816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2000), ‘Collective action and the evolution of social norms’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3): 137158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R.D. (1993), Making Democracy Work. Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
L, Stanca. (2010), ‘How to be kind? Outcomes versus intentions as determinants of fairness’, Economics Letters 106(1): 1921.Google Scholar
Transparency International Kenya (2001), ‘Harambee. Pooling together or pulling apart?’, [Available at] http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/bueros/kenia/01394.pdf.Google Scholar
Wilson, L.S. (1992), ‘The Harambee movement and efficient public good provision in Kenya’, Journal of Public Economics 48(1): 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, P.J. and Knack, S. (2001), ‘Trust and growth’, Economic Journal 111(470): 295321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Becchetti supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Becchetti supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.5 MB