Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-29T07:13:24.489Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Resource-augmenting R&D with heterogeneous labor supply

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 December 2008

JEAN-PIERRE AMIGUES
Affiliation:
Toulouse School of Economics and INRA (IDEI and LERNA)
MICHEL MOREAUX
Affiliation:
Toulouse School of Economics (IUF, IDEI and LERNA)
FRANCESCO RICCI*
Affiliation:
Université de Cergy-Pontoise (THEMA) and Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA).
*
Address: LERNA-TSE, Manufacture des Tabacs, 21 allée de Brienne, 31000 Toulouse, France. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

The effective labor possibilities frontier (ELPF) is defined as the set of statically efficient allocations of labor inputs in the competing tasks of production and R&D. It is concave if labor is heterogeneous. In an R&D-based growth model with an essential non-renewable natural resource, the shape of the ELPF affects the optimal speed of the transition. If resource endowment is poor, transition is slower and involves a smaller R&D effort, and slower growth in per capita consumption, in the case of a heterogeneous labor force as compared to a homogeneous one. Policies that modify the distribution of skills in the population imply shifts of the ELPF. We provide a taxonomy of possible shifts of the ELPF, and link them to education policy or demographic trends.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abel, A. (1982), ‘Dynamic effects of permanent and temporary tax policies in a q model of investment’, Journal of Monetary Economics 9: 353374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992), ‘A model of growth through creative destruction’, Econometrica 60: 323351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1998), Endogenous Growth Theory, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Amigues, J.-P., Grimaud, A., and Moreaux, M. (2004a), ‘Ressources non-renouvelables, impatience et effort optimal de recherche-développement’, Revue d'Economie Politique 114: 393416 (in French).Google Scholar
Amigues, J.-P., Long, N.V., and Moreaux, M. (2004b), ‘Overcoming the natural resource constraints through dedicated R&D: contrasting the non-renewable and the renewable resource economies’, International Journal of Global Environmental Issues 4: 1137.Google Scholar
Amigues, J.-P. and Moreaux, M. (2004), ‘Contrasting how to overcome the resource constraints in the non renewable and renewable economies: does the shape of the utility function matter?’, International Journal of Development Economics 1: 301319.Google Scholar
Bertola, G. (1994), ‘Flexibility, investment, and growth’, Journal of Monetary Economics 34: 215238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, P. and Heal, G. (1979), Economic Theory of Exhaustible Resources, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, P., Heal, G., and Majumdar, M. (1977), ‘Resource depletion and research and development’, in Intriligator, M. (ed.), Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, Vol. 3 B., Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Davison, R. (1978), ‘Optimal depletion of an exhaustible resource with research and development towards an alternative technology’, Review of Economic Studies 45: 355367.Google Scholar
Eicher, T. and Turnovsky, S. (2001), ‘Transitional dynamics in a two-sector non-scale growth model’, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25: 85113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisner, R. and Strotz, R. (1963), ‘Determinants of business investment’, in Commission on Money and Credit: Impacts of Monetary Policy, Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, pp. 60138.Google Scholar
Galor, O. and Tsiddon, D. (1997), ‘Technological progress, mobility, and economic growth’, American Economic Review 87: 363382.Google Scholar
Grimaud, A. and Rouge, L. (2003), ‘Non-renewable resources and growth with vertical innovations: optimum, equilibrium and economic policies’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 45: 433453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groth, C. (2007), ‘Growth-essential non-renewable resources and limits to growth’, mimeo, University of Copenhagen.Google Scholar
Huffman, G. and Wynne, M. (1999), ‘The role of intratemporal adjustment costs in a multisector economy’, Journal of Monetary Economics 43: 317350.Google Scholar
Jones, C. (1995a), ‘R&D-based models of economic growth’, Journal of Political Economy 103: 759784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. (1995b), ‘Time series tests of endogenous growth models’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 495527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kamien, M. and Schwartz, N. (1978), ‘Optimal exhaustible resource depletion with endogenous technical change’, Review of Economic Studies 45: 179196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, P. (1991), ‘History versus expectations’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 651667.Google Scholar
Kydland, F. and Prescott, E. (1982), ‘Time-to-build and aggregate fluctuations’, Econometrica 50: 13451370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, C.-W. (2000), ‘Endogenous vs. semi-endogenous growth in a two-R&D-sector model’, Economic Journal 110: C109122.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. (1967), ‘Adjustment costs and the theory of supply’, Journal of Political Economy 75: 321334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R. and Prescott, E. (1971), ‘Investment under uncertainty’, Econometrica 39: 659681.Google Scholar
Moreaux, M. and Ricci, F. (2005), ‘The simple analytics of developing resources from resources’, Resource and Energy Economics 27: 4163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mussa, M. (1978), ‘Dynamic adjustment in the Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson model’, The Journal of Political Economy 86: 775791.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. and Phelps, E. (1966), ‘Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth’, American Economic Review 56: 6975.Google Scholar
Rebelo, S. (1991), ‘Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth’, Journal of Political Economy 99: 500521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P. (1990), ‘Endogenous technological change’, Journal of Political Economy 98: S71102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P. (2000), ‘Should the government subsidize supply or demand in the market for scientists and engineers?’, NBER working paper n. 7723.Google Scholar
Rothschild, M. (1971), ‘On the cost of adjustment’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 85: 605622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scholz, C. and Ziemes, G. (1999), ‘Exhaustible resources, monopolistic competition, and endogenous growth’, Environmental and Resource Economics 13: 169185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schou, P. (2000), ‘Polluting non-renewable resources and growth’, Environmental and Resource Economics 16: 211227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smulders, S. and de Nooij, M. (2003), ‘The impact of energy conservation on technology and economic growth’, Resource and Energy Economics 25: 5979.Google Scholar
Tahvonen, O. and Salo, S. (2001), ‘Economic growth and transitions between renewable and nonrenewable energy resources’, European Economic Review 45: 13791398.Google Scholar
Tsur, Y. and Zemel, A. (2005), ‘Scarcity, growth and R&D’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 49: 484499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turnovsky, S. (1996), ‘Fiscal policy, adjustment costs, and endogenous growth’, Oxford Economic Papers 48: 361381.Google Scholar
Van Zon, A. and Yetkiner, H. (2003), ‘An endogenous growth model with embodied energy-saving technical change’, Resource and Energy Economics 25: 81103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, A. (1998), ‘Growth without scale effects’, Journal of Political Economy 106: 4163.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Amigues supplementary material

Appendix.pdf

Download Amigues supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 224.8 KB