Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T09:44:53.806Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Intergenerational transfers, lifetime welfare, and resource preservation*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 February 2008

SIMONE VALENTE*
Affiliation:
Center of Economic Research, ETH Zurich Email: [email protected]

Abstract

This paper analyzes overlapping-generations models where natural capital is owned by selfish agents. Transfers in favor of young agents reduce the rate of depletion and increase output growth. It is shown that intergenerational transfers may be preferred to laissez-faire by an indefinite sequence of generations: if the resource share in production is sufficiently high, the welfare gain induced by preservation compensates for the loss due to taxation. This conclusion is reinforced when other assets are available, e.g. man-made capital, claims on monopoly rents, and R&D investment. Transfers raise the welfare of all generations, except that of the first resource owner: if resource endowments are taxed at time zero, all successive generations support resource-saving policies for purely selfish reasons.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Azariadis, C. and Galasso, V. (2002), ‘Fiscal constitutions’, Journal of Economic Theory 103: 255281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R.J. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004), Economic Growth, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Boldrin, M. and Rustichini, A. (2000), ‘Political equilibria with social security’, Review of Economic Dynamics 3: 4178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bovenberg, A.L. and Heijdra, B.J. (1998), ‘Environmental tax policy and intergenerational distribution’, Journal of Public Economics 67: 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bromley, D.W. (1990), ‘The ideology of efficiency: searching for a theory of policy analysis’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 19: 86107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, E. (1975), ‘Why the social insurance budget is too large in a democracy’, Economic Inquiry 13: 373388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooley, T.F. and Soares, J. (1998), ‘A positive theory of Social Security based on reputation’, Journal of Political Economy 107: 135160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gale, D. (1973), ‘Pure exchange equilibrium in dynamic economic models’, Journal of Economic Theory 6: 1236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerlagh, R. and Keyzer, M.A. (2001), ‘Sustainability and the intergenerational distribution of natural resource entitlements’, Journal of Public Economics 79: 315341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerlagh, R. and Keyzer, M.A. (2003), ‘Efficiency of conservationist measures: an optimist viewpoint’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 46: 310333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, P. (1975), ‘Charity: altruism or cooperative egoism?’, in Phelps, E.S. (ed.), Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. (1931), ‘The economics of exhaustible resources’, Journal of Political Economy} 39: 137175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howarth, R.B. (1991), ‘Intergenerational competitive equilibria under technological uncertainty and an exhaustible resource constraint’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 21: 225243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howarth, R.B. and Norgaard, R.B. (1990), ‘Intergenerational resource rights, efficiency, and social optimality’, Land Economics 66: 111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kotlikoff, L.J., Persson, T., and Svensson, L. (1988), ‘Social contracts as assets: a possible solution to the time-consistency problem’, American Economic Review 78: 662677.Google Scholar
Krautkraemer, J.A. and Batina, R.G. (1999), ‘On sustainability and intergenerational transfers with a renewable resource’, Land Economics 75: 167184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marini, G. and Scaramozzino, P. (1995), ‘Overlapping generations and environmental control’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 29: 6477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mourmouras, A. (1993), ‘Conservationist government policies and intergenerational equity in an overlapping generations model with renewable resources’, Journal of Public Economics 51: 249268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pezzey, J.C.V. (1992), Sustainable Development Concepts: An Economic Analysis, Washington DC: The World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pezzey, J.C.V. (1997), ‘Sustainability constraints versus “optimality” versus intertemporal concern, and axioms versus data’, Land Economics 73: 448466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rangel, A. (2003), ‘Forward and backward intergenerational goods: why is social security good for the environment?’, American Economic Review 93: 813834.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sjoblom, K. (1985), ‘Voting for social security’, Public Choice 45: 225240.Google Scholar
Toman, M.A. (1987), ‘Existence and optimality of dynamic competitive equilibria with a non-renewable resource’, Resource and Energy Economics 9: 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valente, S. (2005), ‘Sustainable development, renewable resources and technological progress’, Environmental and Resource Economics 30: 115125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valente, S. (2006), ‘Intergenerational transfers, lifetime welfare and resource preservation: mathematical appendix’. Center of Economic Research, ETH Zurich. Available from www.cer.ethz.ch/resec/people/svalente.CrossRefGoogle Scholar