Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T13:25:15.123Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Does idiosyncratic risk matter for climate policy?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 November 2022

Richard Jaimes*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Pontificia Universidad Javeriana, Carrera 7 # 40 - 36, Bogotá, Colombia
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper studies the implications of distortions in intertemporal margins for the conduct of climate policy. We do so by introducing a framework that combines a standard two-period overlapping generations (OLG) model with a tractable model of household heterogeneity, in which over-accumulation of capital arises from uninsurable idiosyncratic labor income risk. We illustrate that market-based climate policies must be adjusted when the government cannot provide full insurance to households by taxing only capital and is constrained to transfer resources across generations for risk-sharing. In a numerical exercise, we find that idiosyncratic risk leads to an optimal capital income tax rate of 35 per cent and a carbon price 7.5 per cent lower than its first best.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

1 Introduction

Climate change is a clear and current threat to our societies, especially in developing countries, due to their vulnerability and low adaptive capacity. Yet, only 28 nations have implemented carbon taxes. For example, according to the World Bank database of Carbon Pricing, in 2022 these policies would cover 3 GtCO2e, approximately 5 per cent of global greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.Footnote 1 If we want to achieve sustainable development and encourage a global and efficient energy transition, we need to price carbon, but we should do it right.

A central idea in the macro-climate literature for the setting of carbon prices is that we should discount the future marginal social costs of current emissions using the market interest rate because it represents the real opportunity cost of capital (Nordhaus, Reference Nordhaus2008). Nonetheless, what if the aggregate capital is not at its first-best level? How should climate policy be implemented? To answer these questions, we layout an overlapping generations (OLG) model with idiosyncratic labor income risk and a climate externality, from using fossil energy sources, to examine the implications of capital over-accumulation, due to precautionary savings, on climate policy, i.e., carbon prices.Footnote 2

The objective of this paper is thus to study the implications of distortions in intertemporal margins for the conduct of climate policy. We do so by introducing a framework that combines a standard two-period OLG model with a tractable model of household heterogeneity, in which over-accumulation of capital arises from idiosyncratic risk. Our objective is not to claim that the only motive for capital taxes is because people engage in precautionary savings, and the government decides to tax capital at a positive rate to move the economy closer to the first best. Rather, we want to put forward some analytical macroeconomic tools to think about capital taxation as a form of intertemporal distortions and examine the implications of this idea for the implementation of carbon prices.

Specifically, this paper considers a global economy with two different externalities. First, households face uninsurable idiosyncratic labor income risk when they get older.Footnote 3 The government would like to provide social insurance to people facing labor income risk by means of individual transfers but it is constrained to do so because markets are incomplete.Footnote 4 Notwithstanding, given that people respond to such a risk by increasing their precautionary savings when they are young, there is over-accumulation of capital. This creates an incentive for the government to implement capital income taxes to avoid the aggregate capital becoming too high. The government then uses such fiscal revenues for partial risk-sharing. The intuition for this mechanism is as follows. When people face uninsurable labor productivity shocks, the presence of a precautionary motive for saving then creates a pecuniary externality, i.e., households do not internalize the effect of a higher saving rate on current and future wages and interest rates. The government thus would like to tax capital in order to move the economy closer to its efficient level (Aiyagari, Reference Aiyagari1995; Krueger et al., Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021).

Second, the production of the final good generates carbon dioxide ($\text {CO}_2$) emissions by using fossil fuel energy as an input. Emissions accumulate in the atmosphere, increase the pollutant stock over time, and raise the level of atmospheric concentrations of $\text {CO}_2$, causing global warming. It turns out that higher temperature levels decrease future output through a multiplicative damage function. When the representative firm maximizes its profits, it does not internalize the future marginal social costs associated with the use of energy, creating a negative externality. To correct this externality, the government can implement a tax on $\text {CO}_2$ emissions, the so-called carbon price. To set the carbon price, a government would calculate the net present value of future marginal damages from climate change using the market interest rate.Footnote 5

How are then these two externalities related? If the aggregate level of capital is too high relative to the first best, due to the precautionary saving motive, it would imply a lower market interest rate and higher carbon prices, since the future becomes more important. From the perspective of a social planner, these allocations are inefficient. Given the set of instruments available to the government, hence, it can use a capital income tax to avoid the over-accumulation of capital. However, since that policy cannot replicated completely the first best because of incomplete markets, the economy ends up with a lower aggregate level of capital and a higher market interest rate. It follows that if the government uses the market interest rate to evaluate the marginal social costs of current emissions, it would yield a lower carbon price relative to the first best.

To derive a simple formula for the carbon price, as in recent macro-climate literature, we do rely on some crucial assumptions in spirit of Iverson and Karp (Reference Iverson and Karp2021), Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b), and Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014): (i) a logarithmic utility function; (ii) multiplicative climate damages which are proportional to output; (iii) carbon stocks being linear in emissions, and (iv) a constant saving rate.Footnote 6 In principle, a constant saving rate implicitly requires additional assumptions: (i) full capital depreciation, (ii) exogenous labor supply, and (iii) income for the young is a constant fraction of total output. Finally, to introduce idiosyncratic labor income risk in a tractable manner, we follow closely Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021), Harenberg and Ludwig (Reference Harenberg and Ludwig2015) and Hiraguchi and Shibata (Reference Hiraguchi and Shibata2015).

Our key findings are then as follows. Firstly, we show that in the first best, when the government can provide full insurance to the households, the saving rate is constant, there is not capital over-accumulation, capital income taxes are thus zero, and the optimal carbon price equals the Pigouvian tax (the so-called social costs of carbon). In particular, we show that the carbon price is then proportional to output, it grows at the same rate of the economy, and only depends on the intergenerational discount factor and a reduced-form multi-box representation of the carbon cycle and temperature adjustments, quite similar to the ones derived in Iverson and Karp (Reference Iverson and Karp2021), Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018a, Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b), and Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014).

Secondly, we show that in the second best, the saving rate is also constant but increases with the level of idiosyncratic labor income risk, it depends positively on the intergenerational and private discount factor, and, as expected, decreases with capital income taxes. We then show that the optimal carbon price is again proportional to output, but it now depends on both the intergenerational and private discount factor, productivity level for the old, the capital share and the parameters associated to the climate module. Finally, exploiting these analytical results, in a numerical exercise, we find that uninsurable labor productivity shocks lead to a capital income tax rate of 35 per cent and a carbon price of $24.33e/t{\text{CO}}_2$, approximately 7.5 per cent lower than its first best. The intuition is straightforward as pointed out above. Since the capital tax distorts the saving decisions for the households, it alters the aggregate level of capital and the implied market interest rate, and the carbon price should be adjusted accordingly.

This paper contributes to several strands of the literature. First, we contribute to the emerging literature on simple formulae for the carbon price. For instance, Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014) derive a simple formula for the social cost of carbon using a standard infinitely-lived representative agent model depending on a few parameters. Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b) also derive a simple formula bearing in mind time-inconsistency issues in social preferences. Gerlagh et al. (Reference Gerlagh, Jaimes and Motavasseli2017) present an analytical formula for understanding the implications of demographic change on climate policy. We add to those an analytical simple formula in a model that features idiosyncratic labor income risk and capital income taxation.

Second, our analysis is also related to the extensive literature about pricing externalities and how those prices should be adjusted in the presence of other distortions in the economy. For example, (Barrage, Reference Barrage2020) studies the role of exogenous income taxation for climate policy using an infinitely-lived representative agent model. Jaimes (Reference Jaimes2021) examines the joint design of climate and fiscal policy in an OLG economy. Likewise, Barrage (Reference Barrage2018) and Belfiori (Reference Belfiori2017) consider the implications of differences between private and social discounting for the setting of carbon prices. We contribute to the analysis by looking specifically at the effects of capital taxation due to precautionary saving motives and idiosyncratic risk on climate policy.

Third, notice that other studies also point out to adjustment in policies when, for instance, distributional concerns are taken into consideration (Chiroleu-Assouline and Fodha, Reference Chiroleu-Assouline and Fodha2011, Reference Chiroleu-Assouline and Fodha2014), firms face financial frictions or productivity shocks (van den Bijgaart and Smulders, Reference van den Bijgaart and Smulders2017; Hoffmann et al., Reference Hoffmann, Inderst and Moslener2017), there is asymmetric information (Tideman and Plassmann, Reference Tideman and Plassmann2010; Kaplow, Reference Kaplow2012; Jacobs and de Mooij, Reference Jacobs and de Mooij2015), or when polluting sources location matters for policy (Marrouch and Sinclair-Desgagné, Reference Marrouch and Sinclair-Desgagné2012). We add to this literature by considering an analytical macro-climate framework with idiosyncratic labor income risk, precautionary savings and capital income taxes, along the lines of Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021), Gottardi et al. (Reference Gottardi, Kajii and Nakajima2015), Hiraguchi and Shibata (Reference Hiraguchi and Shibata2015), and Aiyagari (Reference Aiyagari1995).

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the basic model and deals with optimal policies under idiosyncratic risk and incomplete markets. Section 3 presents a basic quantitative exercise. Section 4 concludes.

2 The model

We consider climate policy in an otherwise standard two-period OLG model with exogenous labor supply extended to include both idiosyncratic labor income risk, along the lines of Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021) and Harenberg and Ludwig (Reference Harenberg and Ludwig2015), and multiplicative damages to future output coming from climate change in spirit of Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014) and Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b). Households only live for two periods, young and old age, and make decisions for consumption in each period and individual savings. They face uninsurable idiosyncratic risk for their productivity when they get older and engage in precautionary savings against such a risk. A representative firm produces the final good using capital, labor and energy. It generates $\text {CO}_2$ emissions as a by-product of output. Emissions accumulate into the atmosphere and change the climate. The government thus uses capital income taxes to reduce the inefficient level of aggregate capital and implements a carbon tax for internalizing the marginal social costs of current emissions on future output.

2.1 Households

We assume a stationary population.Footnote 7 Labor supply is inelastic and only depends upon productivity levels for young, $1-\phi _2$, and older people, $\phi _2$, respectively. Along the lines of Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021) and Hiraguchi and Shibata (Reference Hiraguchi and Shibata2015), we allow for uninsurable idiosyncratic productivity shocks, $\chi _{t+1}$, at old-age, which are independently and identically distributed across agents. Let $\Psi (\chi _{t+1})$ be the cumulative distribution function and $\psi (\chi _{t+1})$ the probability density function. Assuming that $\int \chi d\Psi = 1$, it turns out that the effective labor supply is equal to 1,

(1)\begin{equation} L_t = 1-\phi_2+\phi_2\int \chi\,{\rm d}\Psi = 1 \end{equation}

In order to obtain a closed-form solution for both the savings rate and the optimal carbon prices, we follow tradition in recent analytical macro-climate models, e.g, Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014), van den Bijgaart et al. (Reference van den Bijgaart, Gerlagh and Liski2016), Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018a, Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b), Iverson and Karp (Reference Iverson and Karp2021), and let preferences be represented by a logarithmic function,Footnote 8

(2)\begin{equation} W_t \equiv \log C_{1,t} + \beta \int \log C_{2,t+1}(\chi_{t+1})\,{\rm d}\Psi(\chi) \end{equation}

This utility function, (2), implies that the households receive utility only from consumption over their life-cycle, since we assume that labor supply is inelastic. Importantly, the future is discounted through the parameter, $\beta$, and consumption when they are old is uncertain due to the presence of idiosyncratic labor income risk in the second period of their lives. The sequence of budget constraints, when they are young and old, respectively, are as follows,

(3)\begin{align} C_{1,t}+K_{t+1}& = (1-\phi_2)(w_t+T_{1,t}^E) \end{align}
(4)\begin{align} C_{2,t+1}& =\phi_2\chi_{t+1}(w_{t+1}+T_{2,t+1}^E)+ (1-\tau_{t+1}^K)r_{t+1}K_{t+1}+ T_{2,t+1}^K \end{align}

where $\left \{C_{1,t},\,C_{2,t+1}\right \}$ are consumption levels for young and old people, $r_{t+1}K_{t+1}$ represents capital income, non-capital income is the sum of wages, $\left \{w_t,\,w_{t+1}\right \}$, and lump-sum transfers to households coming from climate policy revenues, $\left \{T_{1,t}^E,\,T_{2,t+1}^E\right \}$, respectively. Likewise, $T_{2,t+1}^K$ denotes lump-sum transfers to the old households coming from taxes on capital income, $\tau _{t+1}^K$, as in Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021). Since there is no labor choice, by solving this problem for capital holdings after replacing the budget constraints into the utility function, the first-order condition yields an usual Euler equation,

(5)\begin{equation} U_{C_{1,t}} = \beta (1-\tau_{t+1}^K)r_{t+1}\mathbb{E}[U_{C_{2,t+1}}] \end{equation}

This expression describes the trade-off between current and future consumption. Using the assumption of logarithmic preferences over consumption, the Euler equation can be rewritten as follows,

(6)\begin{equation} \frac{1}{C_{1,t}}=\beta(1-\tau_{t+1}^K)r_{t+1}\int \left(\frac{1}{C_{2,t+1}(\chi_{t+1})}\right)\,{\rm d}\Psi(\chi_{t+1}) \end{equation}

2.2 Firms

The representative firm uses a Cobb-Douglas technology, $F(\cdot )=\Omega (Z_t)K_t^\alpha [H_t (E_t,L_t)]^{1-\alpha }$, and profit maximization yields standard first-order conditions for capital $K_t$, aggregate labor $L_t$, and energy $E_t$, where the function $H_t(\cdot )$ is a composite labor-energy input in the spirit of Iverson and Karp (Reference Iverson and Karp2021) and Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b). There is full capital depreciation.Footnote 9 As in Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018a, Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b), production leads to $\text {CO}_2$ emissions (one-to-one with the use of energy) that increase the stock of pollution over time, $Z_t=\sum _{i=1}^\infty \theta _i E_{t-i}$, according to a reduced-form multi-box representation of the carbon cycle and temperature adjustments, $\theta _i$. High levels of atmospheric concentrations of $\text {CO}_2$ change the climate and reduce future output through a damage function, $\Omega _t=\text {exp}(-Z_t)$.Footnote 10

The representative firm does not internalize these external marginal costs. Hence, the government would like to implement some sort of climate policy: for instance, a carbon price would aim to reduce the impacts of current emissions on carbon concentrations, changes in temperature, and future production losses due to global warming. The first-order conditions are thus given by,

(7)\begin{align} r_t& =F_{K_t} \end{align}
(8)\begin{align} w_t& =F_{L_t} \end{align}
(9)\begin{align} \tau_{t}^E& =F_{E_t} \end{align}

where $\tau _{t}^E$ denotes the carbon price and $F_{i,t}$ for $i \in \{K,\,L,\,E\}$ represents the marginal productivity of capital, labor, and energy, respectively. At the optimal allocation, all the inputs will be paid the value of their marginal productivity.

2.3 Government

The government has two main goals in this economy. First, due to uninsurable idiosyncratic labor income risk in the second period, households have the incentive to increase their precautionary savings but fail to internalize the general equilibrium effects on wages and capital returns of such decisions. The government can then use capital taxes to move the economy closer to the first best by reducing the level of aggregate capital. As in Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021), we assume that the government uses the revenues from capital taxation to finance transfers to the same generation to provide partial insurance against labor income risk.Footnote 11

(10)\begin{equation} T_{2,t}^K=\tau_t^Kr_tK_t \end{equation}

Second, $\text {CO}_2$ emissions generate a climate externality in the economy by reducing future output. As an available instrument, the government can levy an excise tax on energy use to internalize the associated future marginal economic costs into firm's decisions. Since the government is constrained in the way it distributes resources across generations, we also assume that all tax revenues coming from carbon taxation are rebated to households as lump-sum transfers period-by-period as in Gerlagh et al. (Reference Gerlagh, Jaimes and Motavasseli2017).Footnote 12 Here, since older people also supply labor, the revenues are allocated bearing in mind age-specific productivity levels, that is, transfers for the young and old people are constant fractions of total environmental revenues, formally,

(11)\begin{equation} \tau_t^E E_t = (1-\phi_2)T_{1,t}^E+\phi_2 T_{2,t}^E \end{equation}

2.4 Equilibrium

A competitive equilibrium for this economy can be written as follows,

Definition 1 Given a set of policies $\{\tau _t^K,\,\tau _t^E\}_{t=0}^\infty$, initial capital holdings $K_0$, an initial stock of pollution $Z_0$, a competitive equilibrium in this economy consists of relative prices $\{r_t,\, w_{t}\}_{t=0}^\infty$, transfers $\{T_{1,t}^ E,\, T_{2,t}^ E,\,T_{2,t}^K\}_{t=0}^\infty$, allocations for the households $\{C_{1,t},\, C_{2,t+1}(\chi _{t+1}),\, K_{t+1}\}_{t=0}^\infty$ and allocations for the firm $\{K_t,\,E_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ such that,

  1. 1 The allocations for the households solve, (6), for each realization of $\chi _{t+1}$,

  2. 2 The allocations for the firm solve (7-9),

  3. 3 The budget constraints for the government, $\tau _t^E E_t = (1-\phi _2)T_{1,t}^E+\phi _2 T_{2,t}^E$, and $T_{2,t}^K=\tau _t^Kr_tK_t$ are satisfied period-by-period,

  4. 4 And markets clear,

    (12)\begin{align} C_{1,t}+\int C_{2,t}(\chi_{t+1})\,{\rm d}\Psi+K_{t+1}& =\Omega(Z_t)K_t^\alpha [H_t(E_t,L_t)]^{1-\alpha} \end{align}
    (13)\begin{align} L_t& =1 \end{align}

2.5 The saving rate

We follow Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021) closely to derive an implementability condition for relaxing the government problem and solving for allocations instead of tax rates using the well-known primal approach in the optimal taxation literature (Lucas and Stokey, Reference Lucas and Stokey1983; Erosa and Gervais, Reference Erosa and Gervais2002). Since labor supply is exogenous and preferences are logarithmic, the government can determine allocations by choosing only saving rates. Below, we show that the optimal saving rate can be decentralized as a competitive equilibrium using capital income taxes. Let $s_t$ be the saving rate, which is a fraction of total income for the young, i.e., labor income and transfers from carbon taxation revenues,

(14)\begin{equation} s_t=\frac{K_{t+1}}{(1-\phi_2)(w_t+T_{1,t}^E)}\end{equation}

Using the sequence of budget constraints described above and the definition for the saving rate, we can rewrite the Euler equation as,

(15)\begin{equation} 1=\beta(1-\tau_{t+1}^K)\int \frac{1-s_t}{\frac{\phi_2\chi_{t+1}\hat{w}_{2,t+1}}{r_{t+1}(1-\phi_2)\hat{w}_{1,t}}+ (1-\tau_{t+1}^K)s_t+ \frac{T_{2,t+1}^K}{r_{t+1}(1-\phi_2)\hat{w}_{1,t}}}\,{\rm d}\Psi(\chi_{t+1})\end{equation}

where $\hat {w}_{i,t}=w_t+T_{i,t}^E$ for $i=\{1,\,2\}$ is the non-capital income for households as in Iverson and Karp (Reference Iverson and Karp2021). Given the assumption about technology and the energy–labor composite input, it can be shown that factor compensations are then a constant fraction of output, that is,

(16)\begin{align} & w_t L_t + \tau_t^E E_t = (1-\alpha)Y_t \end{align}
(17)\begin{align} & r_t K_t = \alpha Y_t \end{align}

Hence, by substituting prices and transfers in terms of aggregate variables into the Euler equation, assuming that the government distributes carbon tax revenues bearing in mind productivity levels, and given an initial capital stock, $K_0$, one can obtain an expression for the dynamics of capital as follows, which also hinges on the level of idiosyncratic labor income risk in old age, $\Phi$,

(18)\begin{equation} 1=\alpha \beta (1-\tau_{t+1}^K) \left[\frac{(1-\phi_2)(1-\alpha)Y_t-K_{t+1}}{K_{t+1}}\right]\underbrace{\int \frac{1}{\phi_2 \chi_{t+1}(1-\alpha)+\alpha}\,{\rm d}\Psi(\chi_{t+1})}_{\Phi = \Phi(\phi_2,\alpha;\Psi)} \end{equation}

Notice that since the term in the integral is convex in $\chi _{t+1}$, $\Phi$ is increasing in the level of idiosyncratic risk. For vanishingly small spread, then it converges to $\frac {1}{\phi _2 \chi _{t+1}(1-\alpha )+\alpha }$. Finally, along the lines of Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021), for a given tax policy $\tau _{t+1}^K \in (-\infty,\,1]$, we can solve for the saving rate in competitive equilibrium to obtain,

Proposition 1 The saving rate in competitive equilibrium is given by,

(19)\begin{equation} s_t = \frac{1}{1+\frac{1}{\alpha \beta (1-\tau_{t+1}^K)\Phi(\phi_2,\alpha;\Psi)}} \end{equation}

Proof. In appendix A1.

This constant saving rate is unique and independent of climate policies and capital stocks, but dependent of the capital income tax policy and the level of idiosyncratic risk. Specifically, a positive tax on capital reduces the incentives for saving but labor income risk increases it. As one may expect, a higher subjective discount factor, $\beta$, and a larger capital share, $\alpha$, also increase the saving rate. This will be crucial for the setting of fiscal and climate policies as discussed below. Indeed, as shown in Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021), and following the primal approach, the government can then solve directly for the saving rate and then decentralize it by choosing capital income taxes.

2.6 First-best allocations

To begin with, we solve for the first-best allocations under the case of idiosyncratic labor income risk and global warming. We then perform a comparative analysis about the implications of constraints on policy instruments. In the first best, the government would like to: (i) internalize future climate damages by means of a carbon tax, and (ii) provide full insurance to households facing productivity shocks, and in order to do so, it should be able to transfer resources across generations. By solving the social planner's problem, it follows that,

Proposition 2 The unconstrained government finds it optimal to implement a constant saving rate,

(20)\begin{equation} s^{*}=\frac{\alpha \gamma}{(1-\phi_2)(1-\alpha)} \end{equation}

and a carbon price given by,

(21)\begin{equation} \tau_t^E= Y_t \sum_{i=1}^\infty \gamma^i \theta_i \end{equation}

where $\gamma$ is the intergenerational discount factor used for the social planner in its welfare maximization problem.

Proof. In appendix A2.

As expected, given the assumptions about technology and preferences, the saving rate, (20), is constant over time and increasing in the intergenerational discount factor, $\gamma$, the capital share, $\alpha$, and the productivity for the old people, $\phi _2$. As in recent literature related to simple formulae for the social costs of carbon, i.e., as in Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014), the optimal carbon price, (21), is proportional to output (and grows at the same rate) and rises with higher future weights and damages.

In the first best, the carbon price thus equals both the market costs of carbon, i.e., the present value of future marginal damages discounted using the market interest rate, and the Pigouvian tax. Since the government would like to avoid intertemporal distortions, by providing full insurance to households through transfers, optimal policies yield a zero capital income tax rate and a carbon price that fully internalizes the future marginal damages of one additional unit of $\text {CO}_2$ emissions today. The key difference here is the use of a distinct discount factor which depends upon government preferences and not on the households’ discount factor. If we assume that those discount factors coincide, we are back into the seminal simple formula for the carbon price derived by Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014) using an infinitely-lived representative agent model and a particular climate module, that is,

Corollary 1 If the government uses the same discount factor as the households, $\gamma =\beta,$ then the optimal carbon price resembles the one in Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014),

(22)\begin{equation} \tau_t^E= Y_t \sum_{i=1}^\infty \beta^i \theta_i \end{equation}

2.7 Second-best allocations

When the government cannot either implement a carbon tax or transfer resources across generations for risk-sharing the first-best allocation could not be attained. In a second-best scenario, the problem then is to choose optimal policies given the set of policy instruments available to the government. In particular, we assume that the government can implement carbon taxes to internalize climate externalities and rebate such fiscal revenues to household via lump-sum transfers, and tax capital income in order to make lump-sum transfers to members of the same generation as a means of partially insuring people against idiosyncratic labor income risk.

In a second-best world, the government now chooses carbon taxes and capital income taxes such that the resulting allocation maximizes the welfare of current and future generations. From the previous section, we can solve a relaxed problem by choosing the saving rate directly instead of tax rates. By solving the government maximization problem the saving rate, the optimal capital tax, and the optimal carbon tax are given by,

Proposition 3 The constrained government finds it optimal to implement a constant saving rate,

(23)\begin{equation} s^{*}=\frac{\alpha(\beta+\gamma)}{1+\alpha \beta} \end{equation}

a constant capital income tax,

(24)\begin{equation} \tau^K=1-\frac{\beta+\gamma}{(1-\alpha \gamma)\beta \Phi(\phi_2,\alpha; \Psi)} \end{equation}

and a carbon price given by,

(25)\begin{equation} \tau_t^E= Y_t \sum_{i=1}^\infty \hat{\gamma}^i \theta_i, \text{ with } \hat{\gamma} \equiv \frac{(\beta+\gamma)(1-\phi_2)(1-\alpha)}{1+\alpha \beta} \end{equation}

Proof. In appendix A3.

From proposition 3, it turns out that the optimal saving rate, (23), is constant over time, it depends on the capital share as before, and positively on both the subjective and intergenerational discount factors, but it is independent of idiosyncratic risk. The government can decentralize this saving rate using a constant capital income tax rate (24), which is increasing in the level of idiosyncratic risk, $\Phi$ and decreasing concerning the discount factors. The intuition for this expression is as follows. If households face a higher level of idiosyncratic labor income risk in old age, they would like to save more to insure against that risk. Hence, the aggregate capital would be higher than the efficient level. The government can correct this inefficiency by taxing capital income.

Furthermore, the carbon price in the second best, (25), takes a similar form as before, but now it uses a modified discount factor, $\hat {\gamma }$, for the Ramsey planner. It happens because capital income taxes distort an intertemporal margin, i.e., how much to consume in each period. Recall also that climate externalities also distort an intertemporal margin. Hence, the government finds it optimal to implement a lower carbon price to move the economy closer to its efficient level. Importantly, in the second best, the adjusted-discount factor, $\hat {\gamma }$, depends on the capital share, the productivity of the old, and both the subjective and intergenerational discount factors. As in the first best, note that we can get a simple formula for the carbon price because the saving rate is constant and we obtain a closed-form solution for the market interest rate.

3 A numerical example

Contributing to the recent literature that proposes simple formulae for the social costs of carbon following the work of Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014), we exploit the closed-form solutions for the optimal carbon prices derived in the previous sections for an OLG economy with idiosyncratic labor income risk. To see the implications of different saving rules in the setting of carbon taxes, we proceed to calculate the path of optimal carbon taxes in both a first-best scenario, when the government can provide full insurance to households, and a second-best world, where the presence of idiosyncratic risk and incomplete markets lead to over-accumulation of capital and the government implements a capital income tax to correct for pecuniary externalities.

3.1 Climate module

We follow Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b) and van den Bijgaart et al. (Reference van den Bijgaart, Gerlagh and Liski2016) closely in modeling climate change and use a multi-box representation for the carbon cycle and temperature adjustments. As shown in Gerlagh et al. (Reference Gerlagh, Jaimes and Motavasseli2017), the response function to current emissions, $\theta _i$, can be written as,

(26)\begin{equation} \theta_{i} = \sum \nolimits_{j} \sum \nolimits_{k} a_j b_k \pi \varepsilon_k \frac{(1-\eta_j)^i-(1-\varepsilon_k)^i}{\varepsilon_k-\eta_j}, \end{equation}

where $\eta _j$ presents the rates for atmospheric depreciation factors, $\varepsilon _k$ denotes the temperature adjustment speeds, $a_j$ sets the shares of carbon emissions entering the reservoirs considered i.e., atmosphere and upper ocean, biomass and deep oceans, $b_k$ designates how temperature responds to changes in carbon stocks, and $\pi =0.0167$ is the climate sensitivity which comes from a linear approximation to the relationship between carbon concentrations, temperature changes, and damages. Below, we determine the paths of this response function for the remainder of this century, by using the procedure explained in Gerlagh et al. (Reference Gerlagh, Jaimes and Motavasseli2017), when the saving rate depends only on a few parameters, i.e., it is constant over time, and the parameter values for the climate system as reported in table 1. Calibrated parameters come from van den Bijgaart et al. (Reference van den Bijgaart, Gerlagh and Liski2016).Footnote 13

Table 1. Median parameter values for the climate system

3.2 Optimal carbon and capital taxes

This subsection describes the calibration procedure and presents the numerical exercise using the simple formulae derived above for the capital income tax and the carbon price in both a first-best and a second-best world. Nonetheless, notice that the purpose is not to provide a completed calibration and characterization of policies but to present a quantitative illustration of the possible impacts of the given externalities on climate and fiscal policy in our simplified model.Footnote 14

As a benchmark, we only look at the situation when the government uses the same discount factor as the households, $\gamma =\beta$, and we set $\beta =0.985$, as in Eggertsson et al. (Reference Eggertsson, Mehrotra and Robbins2019), which is a standard value for OLG models.Footnote 15 Following Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021), we also assume a value for old age productivity of $\phi _2=0.3117$, a capital share, $\alpha =0.2071$, a total labor supply normalized to 1, full depreciation of capital, a constant elasticity of intertemporal substitution equal to one, and the other calibrated parameters for the mean and variance of idiosyncratic labor income risk as described in the table 2.

Table 2. Calibrated parameters for the benchmark model

Note: The value for $\mu _{\ln \chi }$ is set such that $\mathbb {E}\chi =1$.

Figure 1 shows the path for carbon prices in the first-best and second-best world for the remainder of the century. Two features stand out. On the one hand, carbon taxes grow at 2 per cent per year. That is, at the same growth rate we assume for the economy, because carbon prices are proportional to output. On the other hand, in contrast to Barrage (Reference Barrage2018), even if the government resembles the same level of impatience than the households, the optimal carbon taxes in a second-best world are approximately 7.5 per cent lower than those derived in the first-best scenario. The intuition for this is straightforward. Since the government cannot provide full insurance to households and the capital income tax is not able to replicate completely the first best, the government finds it optimal to adjust downwards the carbon price accordingly.

FIG. 1. Optimal carbon taxes, 2010–2100. Notes: Optimal carbon taxes in a first-best world vs. second-best policy. The value of standard (private) discounting is 0.985.

A closer look at capital and carbon taxes across different scenarios yields interesting insights. Under the baseline case in which $\beta =\gamma$, table 3 reports saving rates for the competitive equilibrium without fiscal and climate policy, the first-best allocation and the constrained efficient allocation or second-best with both capital and carbon taxes.Footnote 16

Table 3. Optimal climate and fiscal policy, 2020

Notes: Values for $\beta =0.985^{30}$, $\gamma =0.985^{30}$, $\alpha =0.2082$, $\phi _2=0.3117$, and $\Phi (\phi _2,\,\alpha ;\Psi (\chi ))=3.55$ where $\chi \sim LN(-0.125,\,0.25)$. Carbon taxes in €/$\text {tCO}_2$.

In the first case, as one may expect, the presence of idiosyncratic labor income risk creates a motive for precautionary savings and therefore a saving rate of 0.319, a rate that is too high from the perspective of a social planner. In contrast, the optimal saving rate in a world where the government can provide full insurance to households is just 0.243, while at the same time being able to implement an optimal carbon tax (at its Pigouvian level, since there are not intertemporal distortions coming from taxing capital) of 26.27€/$\text {tCO}_2$ at 2020. However, when the government can provide only partial insurance, due to the presence of incomplete markets, it finds it optimal to tax capital at a rate of 35 per cent, yielding a saving rate of $0.234$, and to set a lower carbon tax of 24.33€/$\text {tCO}_2$ relative to the first best.

Despite of being an analytical climate-economy model, this framework is able to provide reasonable values for macroeconomic policies. For example, according to empirical estimates for a set of countries, in her analysis, Barrage (Reference Barrage2020) uses as baseline for the capital tax a value of 33.40 per cent. Similar values for baseline capital taxes, 41.1 per cent for US and 36.8 per cent for Europe, can be found in Trabandt and Uhlig (Reference Trabandt and Uhlig2012) and Trabandt and Uhlig (Reference Trabandt and Uhlig2011). Likewise, the level of the carbon prices (26.27€/$\text {tCO}_2$ is approximately equal to 110 USD/tC, bearing in mind the fact that 1 $\text {tCO}_2$ = 3.67 tC and 1€ is about 1.142 USD) reported in table 3 are in line, for instance, with some of the estimations made by Barrage (Reference Barrage2020) and Nordhaus (Reference Nordhaus2017) using infinitely-lived representative agent models.

4 Discussion

In this paper we characterize the effects of precautionary saving, due to uninsurable idiosyncratic labor income risk and incomplete markets, for the conduct of climate policy and the setting of carbon prices. We do so in a standard two-period OLG model extended to include income risk and climate change. We find that the optimal capital tax cannot replicate completely the first best, because the government can only use transfers to partially insure people in old age. It turns out that the economy ends up with a lower aggregate level of capital and a higher market interest rate relative to the first best, and the government finds it optimal to adjust downwards the carbon price.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S1355770X22000328

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to the Editor as well as to the Associate Editor and two anonymous referees for careful readings and helpful recommendations. I also thank Reyer Gerlagh and Sjak Smulders for their continuous guidance and support. All errors are my own.

Conflict of interest

The author(s) declare none.

Footnotes

1 The Wold Bank also reports that in 2022 alternative initiatives such as cap-and-trade schemes have been implement in 9 nations and would cover 7GtCO2, representing 11 per cent of global GHG emissions.

2 Despite physical capital being instrumental for economic growth and development, too much capital in an economy would generate allocations that are not dynamically efficient. For an in-depth discussion about dynamic efficiency see, for example, de la Croix and Michel (Reference de la Croix and Michel2002). This paper shows that a capital income tax can help the government to restore efficiency. Indeed, recent empirical evidence supports the idea that capital taxation is not growth-deterring and points out heterogeneous effects across countries depending on their stage of development (ten Kate and Milionis, Reference ten Kate and Milionis2019).

3 In order to make the model tractable, as in Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021) and Harenberg and Ludwig (Reference Harenberg and Ludwig2015), we assume that people supply labor inelastically in both periods.

4 For simplicity, we also assume that the government only has access to capital income taxes and it does not have additional public spending requirements. Note that to focus only on taxes that distort intertemporal margins, we ruled out labor income taxes and lump-sum transfers.

5 Notice that we follow the positive (or descriptive) approach as in Nordhaus (Reference Nordhaus2008, Reference Nordhaus2017) for setting the appropriate discount rate. For a normative (or prescriptive) approach see, for instance, Stern (Reference Stern2007).

6 See, van den Bijgaart et al. (Reference van den Bijgaart, Gerlagh and Liski2016), Rezai and van der Ploeg (Reference Rezai and van der Ploeg2015), and Barrage (Reference Barrage2014), for details of the robustness of simple formulae for carbon prices.

7 As in standard OLG models, we ruled out population growth and within-generation heterogeneity.

8 It is also important to note that assuming a unitary elasticity of intertemporal substitution is not uncommon in two-period OLG models since each period in the model spans approximately 30 years.

9 This assumption is typical in two-period OLG models since each period is equivalent to 30 years.

10 Multiplicative damages factors are standard in integrated assessment models of climate and the economy. The assumption of an exponential function follows from its simplicity, see, for instance, Golosov et al. (Reference Golosov, Hassler, Krusell and Tsyvinski2014), Gerlagh and Liski (Reference Gerlagh and Liski2018b) and Iverson and Karp (Reference Iverson and Karp2021).

11 For simplicity, distribution of resources across generations and government debt are ruled out.

12 Otherwise, the government could use these revenues to provide additional insurance to old people facing labor income shocks. We do not consider the implications of this channel on optimal policies, but it is an interesting area for future research.

14 A fully-fledged climate-economy model with heterogeneity within and across generations, an elastic labor supply, more than two periods, a more realistic depreciation rate for capital, and a general functional form for the utility function would be computationally intensive. We leave it for future research.

15 Typically, in infinitely-lived representative agent models, this parameter is calibrated to match a particular interest rate.

16 To calculate the constant $\Phi (\phi _2,\,\alpha ;\Psi )$, we assume that $\chi$ is log-normally distributed and approximate it using a Gaussian quadrature with 20 nodes along the lines of Krueger et al. (Reference Krueger, Ludwig and Villalvazo2021).

References

Aiyagari, SR (1995) Optimal capital income taxation with incomplete market, borrowing constraints, and constant discounting. Journal of Political Economy 103, 11581175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrage, L (2014) Sensitivity analysis for golosov, hassler, krusell and tsyvinski (2014): ‘optimal taxes on fossil fuel in general equilibrium’. Econometrica 82, 4188. Econometrica Supplementary material.Google Scholar
Barrage, L (2018) Be careful what you calibrate for: social discounting in general equilibrium. Journal of Public Economics 160, 3349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrage, L (2020) Optimal dynamic carbon taxes in a climate-economy model with distortionary fiscal policy. Review of Economic Studies 87, 139.Google Scholar
Belfiori, ME (2017) Carbon pricing, carbon sequestration and social discounting. European Economic Review 96, 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caldeira, K and Myhrvold, NP (2013) Projections of the pace of warming following an abrupt increase in atmospheric carbon dioxide concentration. Environmental Research Letters 8, 034039.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiroleu-Assouline, M and Fodha, M (2011) Environmental tax and the distribution of income among heteregeneous workers. Annals of Economics and Statistics 103/104, 7192.10.2307/41615494CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiroleu-Assouline, M and Fodha, M (2014) From regressive pollution taxes to progressive environmental tax reforms. European Economic Review 69, 126142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D and Michel, P (2002) A Theory of Economic Growth: Dynamics and Policy in Overlapping Generations. 1st edn. Cambridge University Press, pp. 82–84, Chapter 2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, GB, Mehrotra, NR and Robbins, JA (2019) A model of secular stagnation: theory and quantitative evaluation. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 11, 148.Google Scholar
Erosa, A and Gervais, M (2002) Optimal taxation in life-cycle economies. Journal of Economy Theory 105, 338369.10.1006/jeth.2001.2877CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerlagh, R, Jaimes, R and Motavasseli, A (2017) Global demographic change and climate policies. CESifo Working Paper No. 6617.Google Scholar
Gerlagh, R and Liski, M (2018a) Carbon prices for the next hundred years. The Economic Journal 128, 728757.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerlagh, R and Liski, M (2018b) Consistent climate policies. Journal of the European Economic Association 16, 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golosov, M, Hassler, J, Krusell, P and Tsyvinski, A (2014) Optimal taxes on fossil fuel in general equilibrium. Econometrica 82, 4188.Google Scholar
Gottardi, P, Kajii, A and Nakajima, T (2015) Optimal taxation and debt with uninsurable risks to human capital accumulation. American Economic Review 105, 34433470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harenberg, D and Ludwig, A (2015) Social security in an analytically tractable overlapping generations model with aggregate and idiosyncratic risk. International Tax and Public Finance 22, 579603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hiraguchi, R and Shibata, A (2015) Taxing capital is a good idea: the role of idiosyncratic risk in an olg model. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 52, 258269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffmann, F, Inderst, R and Moslener, U (2017) Taxing externalities under financing constraints. The Economic Journal 127, 24782503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iverson, T and Karp, L (2021) Carbon taxes and climate commitment with non-constant time preference. Review of Economic Studies 88, 764799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, B and de Mooij, RA (2015) Pigou meets mirrless: on the irrelevance of tax distortions for the second-best pigouvian tax. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 71, 90108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaimes, R (2021) Optimal climate and fiscal policy in an olg economy. Vniversitas Económica Working Paper (21)3.Google Scholar
Joos, F, Roth, R, Fuglestvedt, JS, Peters, GP, Enting, IG, von Bloh, W, Brovkin, V, Burke, EJ, Eby, M, Edwards, NR, Friedrich, T, Frölicher, TL, Halloran, PR, Holden, PB, Jones, C, Kleinen, T, Mackenzie, FT, Matsumoto, K, Meinshausen, M, Plattner, G-K, Reisinger, A, Segschneider, J, Shaffer, G, Steinacher, M, Strassmann, K, Tanaka, K, Timmermann, A and Weaver, AJ (2013) Carbon dioxide and climate impulse response functions for the computation of greenhouse gas metrics: a multi-model analysis. Atmospheric Chemistry and Physics 13, 27932825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, L (2012) Optimal control of externalities in the presence of income taxation. International Economic Review 53, 487509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ten Kate, F and Milionis, P (2019) Is capital taxation always harmful for economic growth?. International Tax and Public Finance 26, 758805.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, D, Ludwig, A and Villalvazo, S (2021) Optimal taxes on capital in the olg model with uninsurable idiosyncratic income risk. Journal of Public Economics 201, 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, REJ and Stokey, N (1983) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy in an economy without capital. Journal of Monetary Economies 12, 5593.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marrouch, W and Sinclair-Desgagné, B (2012) Emission taxes when pollution depends on location. Environment and Development Economics 17, 433443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nordhaus, W (2008) A question of balance: weighing the options on global warming policies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W (2017) Revisiting the social cost of carbon. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 114, 15181523.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rezai, A and van der Ploeg, F (2015) Robustness of a simple rule for the social cost of carbon. Economics Letters 132, 4855.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stern, N (2007) The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambrigde University Press.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tideman, TN and Plassmann, F (2010) Pricing externalities. European Journal of Political Economy 26, 176184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trabandt, M and Uhlig, H (2011) The laffer curve revisited. Journal of Monetary Economics 58, 305327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trabandt, M and Uhlig, H (2012) How do laffer curves differ across countries? Working Paper 17862, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van den Bijgaart, I and Smulders, S (2017) Does a recession call for less stringent environmental policy? a partial-equilibrium second-best analysis. Environmental and Resource Economics 70, 807834.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van den Bijgaart, I, Gerlagh, R and Liski, M (2016) A simple formula for the social cost of carbon. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 77, 7594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Median parameter values for the climate system

Figure 1

Table 2. Calibrated parameters for the benchmark model

Figure 2

FIG. 1. Optimal carbon taxes, 2010–2100. Notes: Optimal carbon taxes in a first-best world vs. second-best policy. The value of standard (private) discounting is 0.985.

Figure 3

Table 3. Optimal climate and fiscal policy, 2020

Supplementary material: PDF

Jaimes supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Jaimes supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 221.4 KB