Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T08:56:07.187Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

MEASURING GROUP FITNESS IN A BIOLOGICAL HIERARCHY: AN AXIOMATIC SOCIAL CHOICE APPROACH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 October 2013

Walter Bossert
Affiliation:
University of Montreal, [email protected]
Chloe X. Qi
Affiliation:
Boston Consulting Group, [email protected]
John A. Weymark
Affiliation:
Vanderbilt University, [email protected]

Abstract

This article illustrates how axiomatic social choice theory can be used in the evaluation of measures of group fitness for a biological hierarchy, thereby contributing to the dialogue between the philosophy of biology and social choice theory. It provides an axiomatic characterization of the ordering underlying the Michod–Viossat–Solari–Hurand–Nedelcu index of group fitness for a multicellular organism. The MVSHN index has been used to analyse the germ-soma specialization and the fitness decoupling between the cell and organism levels that takes place during the evolutionary transition to multicellularity. It is argued that some of the axioms satisfied by the MVSHN group fitness ordering are not appropriate for all stages in this transition.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Blackorby, C. and Donaldson, D.. 1984. Social criteria for evaluating population change. Journal of Public Economics 25: 1333.Google Scholar
Blackorby, C., Primont, D. and Russell, R. R.. 1978. Duality, Separability, and Functional Structure: Theory and Economic Applications. New York: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Blackorby, C., Bossert, W. and Donaldson, D.. 2002. Utilitarianism and the theory of justice. In Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare, Vol. 1, ed. Arrow, K. J., Sen, A. K. and Suzumura, K., 543596. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Blackorby, C., Bossert, W. and Donaldson, D.. 2005. Population Issues in Social Choice Theory, Welfare Economics, and Ethics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bossert, W. and Weymark, J. A.. 2004. Utility in social choice. In Handbook of Utility Theory. Volume 2: Extensions, ed. Barberà, S., Hammond, P. J. and Seidl, C., 10991177. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Bossert, W., Qi, C. X. and Weymark, J. A.. 2013. Extensive social choice and the measurement of group fitness in biological hierarchies. Biology and Philosophy 28: 7598.Google Scholar
Calcott, B. 2011. Alternative patterns of explanation for major transitions. In The Major Transitions Revisited, ed. Calcott, B. and Sterelny, K., 3551. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Conradt, L. and List, C.. 2009. Group decisions in humans and animals: a survey. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 364: 719742.Google Scholar
Damuth, J. and Heisler, I. L.. 1988. Alternative formulations of multilevel selection. Biology and Philosophy 3: 407430.Google Scholar
d'Aspremont, C. and Gevers, L.. 2002. Social welfare functionals and interpersonal comparability. In Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare, Vol. 1, ed. Arrow, K. J., Sen, A. K. and Suzumura, K., 459541. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Godfrey-Smith, P. 2009. Darwinian Populations and Natural Selection. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Godfrey-Smith, P. 2011. Darwinian populations and transitions in individuality. In The Major Transitions Revisited, ed. Calcott, B. and Sterelny, K., 6581. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Grafen, A. 2007. The formal Darwinism project: a mid-term report. Journal of Evolutionary Biology 20: 12431254.Google Scholar
Herron, M. D. and Michod, R. E.. 2007. Evolution of complexity in the volvocine algae: transitions in individuality through Darwin's eye. Evolution 62: 436451.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kirk, D. L. 2005. A twelve-step program for evolving multicellularity and a division of labor. BioEssays 27: 299310.Google Scholar
Lewontin, R. C. 1970. The units of selection. Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics 1: 118.Google Scholar
List, C. 2004. Multidimensional welfare aggregation. Public Choice 119: 119142.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. and Szathmáry, E.. 1995. The Major Transitions in Evolution. Oxford: W. H. Freeman/Spektrum.Google Scholar
Michod, R. E. 1999. Darwinian Dynamics: Evolutionary Transitions in Fitness and Individuality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Michod, R. E. 2005. On the transfer of fitness from the cell to the multicellular organism. Biology and Philosophy 20: 967987.Google Scholar
Michod, R. E. 2011. Evolutionary transitions in individuality: multicellularity and sex. In The Major Transitions Revisited, ed. Calcott, B. and Sterelny, K., 169197. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Michod, R. E. and Nedelcu, A. M.. 2003. On the reorganization of fitness during evolutionary transitions in individuality. Integrative and Comparative Biology 43: 6473.Google Scholar
Michod, R. E., Viossat, Y., Solari, C. A., Hurand, M. and Nedelcu, A. M.. 2006. Life-history evolution and the origin of multicellularity. Journal of Theoretical Biology 239: 257272.Google Scholar
Miller, S. M. 2010. Volvox, chlamydomonas, and the evolution of multicellularity. Nature Education 3 (9): 65.Google Scholar
Okasha, S. 2006. Evolution and the Levels of Selection. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Okasha, S. 2009. Individuals, groups, fitness and utility: multi-level selection meets social choice theory. Biology and Philosophy 24: 561584.Google Scholar
Okasha, S. 2012. Social justice, genomic justice, and the veil of ignorance: Harsanyi meets Mendel. Economics and Philosophy 28: 4371.Google Scholar
Okasha, S. and Binmore, K.. 2012. Evolution and Rationality: Decisions, Co-operation and Strategic Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ooghe, E. and Lauwers, L.. 2005. Non-dictatorial extensive social choice. Economic Theory 25: 721743.Google Scholar
Roberts, K., 1995. Valued opinions or opinionated values: the double aggregation problem. In Choice, Welfare, and Development: A Festschrift in Honour of Amartya K. Sen, ed. Basu, K., Pattanaik, P. and Suzumura, K., 141165. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rokas, A. 2008. The origins of multicellularity and the early history of the genetic toolkit for animal development. Annual Review of Genetics 42: 235251.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. 1970. Collective Choice and Social Welfare. San Francisco, CA: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
Simpson, C. 2011. How many levels are there? How insights from evolutionary transitions in individuality help measure the hierarchical complexity of life. In The Major Transitions Revisited, ed. Calcott, B. and Sterelny, K., 199225. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Suppes, P. 1966. Some formal models of grading principles. Synthese 6: 284306.Google Scholar