Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-02T23:53:54.207Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

‘Learning to bring dead capital to life’: the Riksens Ständers Bank and the credit market in seventeenth-century Sweden

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 July 2019

Christopher Pihl*
Affiliation:
Department of History, Uppsala University
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

Successful mortgage lending is often said to require a system of registration, which records the ownership of, and any encumbrances on, a particular piece of real estate. Here we analyse how Sweden's Riksens Ständers Bank handled the uncertainties of the mortgage lending market c. 1680–1700, when there was no coherent system of property registration. The bank tried to make registration compulsory, but when influential groups opposed this move, the bank had to modify its lending practices. The study thus sheds light on the somewhat fraught initial stages of the shifts in the credit system, which from the latter half of the seventeenth century onwards, saw personal trust replaced by system trust, and private credit replaced by institutional credit.

French abstract

On dit souvent que le succès d'un prêt hypothécaire repose sur un bon système d'enregistrement de la propriété d'un bien immobilier, y compris les charges qui en découlent précisément. Nous analysons comment la banque suédoise Riksens Ständers a géré les incertitudes touchant le marché du crédit hypothécaire entre 1680 et 1700 environ, alors qu'il n'existait aucun système cohérent d'enregistrement de la propriété. Cette banque a tenté de rendre cet enregistrement obligatoire, mais les groupes d'influence se sont opposés à ce changement, et elle a dû modifier ses pratiques de prêt. L'article éclaire par quels chemins tortueux le système de crédit put être modifié, menant, à partir de la seconde moitié du dix-septième siècle, à remplacer confiance en une personne par confiance dans un système, crédit privé se trouvant remplacé par crédit institutionnel.

German abstract

Nach landläufiger Auffassung erfordern Hypothenkreditgeschäfte ein Register, in dem die Eigentumstitel und Belastungen jedes einzelnen Grundstücks verzeichnet sind. In diesem Beitrag wird analysiert, wie die schwedische Riksens Ständers Bank mit den Unsicherheiten des Hypothekenkreditmarktes im Zeitraum von zirka 1680–1700 umging, als es noch kein kohärentes System der Grundstücksregistrierung gab. Die Bank versuchte, die Registrierung verpflichtend zu machen, aber als einflussreiche Gruppen sich diesem Schritt widersetzten, musste sie ihre Kreditvergabepraktiken modifizieren. Die Untersuchung beleuchtet somit die ziemlich angespannten Anfangsstadien in der Entwicklung des Kreditsystems, in denen ab dem späten 17. Jahrhundert das persönliche Vertrauen durch Vertrauen ins System und der private Kredit durch institutionellen Kredit ersetzt wurde.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Notes

1 Muldrew, C., The economy of obligation: the culture of credit and social relations in early modern England (Basingstoke, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, ch. 5; Hardwick, J., Family business: litigation and the political economies of daily life in early modern France (Oxford, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Paul, K. T., ‘Credit, reputation, and masculinity in British urban commerce: Edinburgh, c. 1710–70’, Economic History Review 66, 1 (2013), 226–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Fontaine, L., The moral economy: poverty, credit, and trust in early modern Europe (Cambridge, 2014)Google Scholar.

2 Muldrew, C., ‘Interpreting the market: the ethics of credit and community relations in early modern England’, Social History 18, 2 (1993), 163–83CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Hoffman, P. T., Postel-Vinay, G. and Rosenthal, J.-L., Priceless markets: the political economy of credit in Paris 1660–1870 (Chicago, 2000)Google Scholar.

4 Temin, P. and Voth, H.-J., Prometheus shackled: goldsmith banks and England's financial revolution after 1700 (Oxford, 2013), 34–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 Temin, P., ‘Financial intermediation in the early Roman Empire’, Journal of Economic History 64, 3 (2004), 709–11CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Braudel, F., Civilization and capitalism 15th–18th century, volume II: the wheels of commerce (London, 1982)Google Scholar; Hardwick, Family business, 130.

7 North, D. C. and Thomas, R. P., The rise of the Western world: a new economic history (Cambridge, 1973)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Thompson, E. P., ‘The grid of inheritance: a comment’, in Goody, J. ed., Family and inheritance: rural society in Western Europe, 1200–1800 (Cambridge, 1976), 328–60Google Scholar; North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R., ‘Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England’, Journal of Economic History 49, 4 (1989), 803–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar; de Soto, H., The mystery of capital: why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else (London, 2000)Google Scholar.

8 De Soto, Mystery of capital.

9 Bochove, C. van, Deneweth, H. and Zuijderduijn, J., ‘Real estate and mortgage finance in England and the Low Countries, 1300–1800’, Continuity and Change 30, 1 (2015), 938CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

10 Ito, S., ‘Registration and credit in seventeenth-century England’, European Financial History Review 20, 2 (2013), 141Google Scholar, 144, 148; Muldrew, C., ‘Afterword: mortgages as mediation between kin and capital’, in Briggs, C. and Zuijderduijn, J. eds., Land and credit: mortgages in the medieval and early modern European countryside (Cham, 2018), 309–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Temin, P. and Voth, H.-J., ‘Banking as an emerging technology: Hoare's Bank, 1702–1742’, Financial History Review 13, 2 (2006), 150, 167–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12 Luhmann, N., Trust and power (Chichester, 1979), 4864Google Scholar; Müller, L., The merchant houses of Stockholm, c. 1640–1800: a comparative study of early-modern entrepreneurial behaviour (Uppsala, 1998), 36–8Google Scholar. See Muldrew, Economy of obligation, 5–7, for a critical discussion of Luhmann.

13 Luhmann, Trust, 32–46.

14 Wetterberg, G., Money and power: from Stockholm's Banco 1656 to Sveriges Riksbank today (Stockholm, 2009)Google Scholar.

15 Private credit markets in Sweden have been studied by Müller, Merchant houses; Fagerlund, S., Handel och vandel: vardagslivets sociala struktur ur ett kvinnoperspektiv (Lund, 2002)Google Scholar; Ågren, M., Domestic secrets: women and property in Sweden, 1600–1857 (Chapel Hill, NC, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Franzén, B., Sturetidens monetära system: pant eller penningar som information i köpstaden Arboga (Stockholm, 1998)Google Scholar.

16 Mennings, C. B., Charity and state in late Renaissance Italy: the monte de pietà of Florence (Berkeley, 1993)Google Scholar; Fontaine, Moral economy.

17 Brisman, S., Sveriges riksbank 1668–1918: bankens tillkomst och verksamhet 1 (Stockholm, 1918), 91–2Google Scholar.

18 Ågren, M., Jord och gäld: social skiktning och rättslig konflikt i södra Dalarna ca 1650–1850 (Uppsala, 1992), 4750Google Scholar; Franzén, Sturetidens monetära system, 116–20.

19 ‘Instruction. Hwarefter Sweriges Rijkes … 1668’, printed in Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix VIII, paras LVII, LX and LXIV; Ågren, M., State as master: gender, state formation and commercialisation in urban Sweden, 1650–1780 (Manchester, 2017), 65–6CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20 Lamoreaux, N. R., Insider lending: banks, personal connections and economic development in industrial New England (Cambridge, 1991)Google Scholar; Brunt, L., ‘Rediscovering risk: country banks as venture capital firms in the first industrial revolution’, Journal of Economic History 66, 1 (2006), 74102CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix I, 7–8.

22 Ibid., 129.

23 Söderberg, J., ‘Long-term trends in real wages of labourers’, in Edvinsson, R. et al. eds., Exchange rates, prices, and wages, 1277–2008 (Stockholm, 2010), 473Google Scholar. The price of one barrel of rye (146.6 litres) in 1680 was 2.5 d sm; Hansson, G., Såld spannmål av kyrkotionden: priser i Östergötland under Sveriges stormaktstid (Umeå, 2006)Google Scholar.

24 Swedish National Archives (hereafter SNA), 6211/6211.11/G V a/2859, 2860, 2861, 2862, 2863.

25 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, 124–5.

26 Ibid., 153.

27 Ibid., 168–77.

28 Ibid., 153.

29 Heckscher, E. F., Sveriges ekonomiska historia från Gustav Vasa. D. 1, Före frihetstiden, Bok 2, Hushållningen under internationell påverkan 1600–1720 (Stockholm, 1936), 295–6Google Scholar.

30 SNA 6211.01/A II a/310, 321–4; Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, 152–3; Ågren, Domestic secrets, 60–3.

31 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank; Fredriksson, B., Försvarets finansiering: svensk krigsekonomi under skånska kriget 1675–1679 (Uppsala, 1976), 71–2Google Scholar.

32 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, 207–30.

33 Ibid., 147, 155.

34 Corin, C.-F., Stockholms förmyndarkammare 1667–1956 (Stockholm, 1956), 1112Google Scholar.

35 Stockholms stadsarkiv (Stockholm City Archive), Bouppteckningar, förmyndarkammaren, F 1 A:35, 36, 50, 51, 52, 56.

36 ‘Instruction. Hwarefter Sweriges Rijkes … 1668’, printed in Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix VIII, paras LVII, LX and LXIV.

37 Ibid., para. L.

38 Ågren, Jord och gäld, 42–6.

39 Benckert, K., Bidrag till inteckningsinstitutets historia (Stockholm, 1920), 1923Google Scholar, 44–52.

40 Ågren, Jord och gäld, 48.

41 Jordabalken, section 73, Konung Magnus Erikssons stadslag, Corpus iuris Sueo-Gotorum antiqui XI, ed. C. J. Schlyter (Lund, 1865); Jordabalken, section 10, Konung Christoffers landslag, Corpus iuris Sueo-Gotorum antiqui XII, ed. C. J. Schlyter (Lund, 1869).

42 Jordabalken, sections 12, 20, 21, Konung Magnus Erikssons landslag, Corpus iuris Sueo-Gotorum antiqui X, ed. C. J. Schlyter (Lund, 1862) (hereafter MEL).

43 Ågren, M., Att hävda sin rätt: synen på jordägande i 1600-talets Sverige (Stockholm, 1997), 63–4Google Scholar, 183–7; Muldrew, Economy of obligation, 150; Smail, D. L., The consumption of justice: emotions, publicity, and legal culture in Marseille, 1264–1423 (Ithaca, 2003), 209–13Google Scholar.

44 SNA 6211.02/A I a/873, 512.

45 SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 260; 6211.02/A I a/869, 161; 6211.02/A I a/870, 171, 699; 6211.02/A I a/873, 696; 6211.02/A I a/874, 6.

46 According to the law, married women and widows were possible guarantors. SNA/RA 6211/6211.02/A I a/859, 599.

47 Jägerskiöld, Handelsbalkens utländska källor, 210.

48 SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 353, 595; 6211.02/A I a/869, 161, 660; 6211.02/A I a/870, 699, 1053, 1080, 1175; 6211.02/A I a/873, 452; 6211.02/A I a/874, 56.

49 Jordabalken, section 21, MEL: ‘If title deeds are destroyed’.

50 Hoffman et al., Priceless markets, 25–7; van Bochove et al., ‘Real estate’, 11–15, 21; C. Briggs, ‘Introduction: law courts, contracts and rural society in Europe, 1200–1600’, Continuity and Change 29, 1 (2014), 5–7.

51 SNA 6211.02/A I a/873, 452. 1 daler kopparmynt = 1/3 daler silvermynt.

52 SNA 6211.02/A I a/870, 1180.

53 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 354; 6211.02/A I a/860, 2, 7, 48.

54 Jägerskiöld, Handelsbalkens utländska källor, 209.

55 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 19, 213; 6211.02/A I a/860, 48; 6211.02/A I a/865, 104, 113, 303, 372.

56 SNA/RA 6211/6211.01/A II a/305, 401–05; SNA/RA 6211/6211.01/A II a/306, 147–9.

57 Jägerskiöld, Handelsbalkens utländska källor, 204–09.

58 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 188–9, 245, 258, 264.

59 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 258, 264.

60 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, 160–1; Bernt Johansson, ‘Godsförvärv och likviditetsproblem’ (unpublished licentiate thesis, Uppsala University, 1969), 118–19.

61 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 28.

62 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 218–19.

63 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 222.

64 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 224.

65 Sandberg, R., ‘Huvudstad i ett stormaktsvälde 1560–1720’, in Nilsson, Lars ed., Staden på vattnet: del I 1252–1850 (Stockholm, 2002), 128Google Scholar.

66 Jägerskiöld, Handelsbalkens utländska källor, 208.

67 Ågren, Hävda sin rätt, 174–8, 183–7.

68 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 112; 6211.02/A I a/860, 100; 6211.02/A I a/865, 712, 745; 6211.02/A I a/866, 149, 235.

69 Printed in Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix IX.

70 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix IX, sub-section 1.

71 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix IX.

72 SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 227.

73 De Soto, Mystery of capital; van Bochove et al., ‘Real estate’.

74 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix IX.

75 SNA 6211.02/A I a/869, 44.

76 Jägerskiöld, Handelsbalkens utländska källor, 197; Pedersen, E. L., ‘Jordværdi og kreditmarked i Danmark 1630–1730’, Historisk Tidskrift 15 (1990), 318Google Scholar; Ågren, Domestic secrets, 92–3; Ito, ‘Registration and credit’, 141, 148–50.

77 SNA 6211.02/A I a/869, 827, 1136. See also 6211.02/A I a/865, 199, 595, 601; 6211.02/A I a/870, 291; 6211.02/A I a/873, 130; 6211.02/A I a/874, 183.

78 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, appendix IX.

79 SNA 6211/6211.02/A I a/870, 45, 157, 194, 1072; SNA 6211/6211.02/A I a/874, 390, 509–10, 703; A. Jansson, Bördor och bärkraft: borgare och kronotjänare i Stockholm 1644–1672 (Stockholm, 1991), 24–6, 106–08.

80 SNA 6211.02/A I a/870, 168. See also SNA 6211.02/A I a/866, 72; 6211.02/A I a/869, 305; 6211.02/A I a/870, 1187; 6211.02/A I a/873, 266; 6211.02/A I a/874, 501.

81 SNA 6211.02/A I a/860, 127.

82 SNA 6211.02/A I a/866, 267.

83 SNA 6211.02/A I a/870, 1057.

84 Muldrew, Economy of obligation, chs. 6 and 7; Hardwick, Family business, ch. 4; Shepard, A., Accounting for oneself: worth, status, and the social order in early modern England (Oxford, 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, ch. 2.

85 SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 191. Cf. SNA 6211.02/A I a/866, 40; 6211.02/A I a/870, 542.

86 SNA 6211.02/A I a/869, 44–5. Cf. SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 618; 6211.02/A I a/866, 476; 6211.02/A I a/869, 407; 6211.02/A I a/870, 1057; 6211.02/A I a/873, 130.

87 SNA 6211.02/A I a/866, 149. Cf. SNA 6211.02/A I a/866, 108, 149; 6211.02/A I a/870, 704, 1054, 1103, 1187; 6211.02/A I a/873, 160.

88 Muldrew, Economy of obligation, 152–7; Hardwick, Family business, ch. 4; Paul, ‘Credit, reputation, and masculinity’.

89 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 235.

90 SNA 6211.02/A I a/859, 171. Cf. SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 837.

91 Brisman, Sveriges riksbank, 117.

92 SNA 6211.02/A I a/869, 521.

93 SNA 6211.02/A I a/873, 333.

94 SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 190.

95 SNA 6211.02/A I a/870, 1025, 1178.

96 SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 45, 163, 650; 6211.02/A I a/869, 135, 214, 399, 462; 6211.02/A I a/870, 704, 1004; 6211.02/A I a/873, 200.

97 SNA 6211.02/A I a/869, 135.

98 SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 799.

99 SNA 6211.02/A I a/870, 704. See also SNA 6211.02/A I a/866, 108, 399; 6211.02/A I a/874, 378.

100 Cf. van Bochove et al., ‘Real estate’, n. 5.

101 SNA 6211.02/A I a/866, 293.

102 SNA 6211.02/A I a/870, 901.

103 For examples from all around the Swedish realm, see SNA 6211.02/A I a/865, 111 (Uppsala and Eksjö), 228 (Uppsala), 630 (Uppsala); 6211.02/A I a/866, 541 (Eksjö); 6211.02/A I a/870, 86 (Kristinehamn), 100 (Uppsala), 612 (Linköping); 6211.02/A I a/873, 400 (Helsinki).

104 North and Weingast, ‘Constitutions and commitments’; Hoffman, P. T. et al. , ‘The role of trust in the long-run development of French financial markets’, in Cook, K. S. et al. eds., Whom can we trust? How groups, networks, and institutions make trust possible (New York, 2009), 308–39Google Scholar.