Introduction
On 1 July 1968, the six member countries of the European Economic Community (EEC) lifted all customs duties and restrictions within the new common market. Eleven years after the treaty of Rome was signed on 25 March 1957, the liberalisation process finally achieved its last step to maximise the economic competition between the Six. The day before, on 30 June 1968, the Gaullist party had won the second round of the legislative elections in France. The new conservative majority would put an end to the students’ movement and workers’ strikes of May 68. Despite seven weeks of economic chaos, the French government decided to keep the commitment to its partners and renounced protection of the economic recovery by postponing the European deadline. The other member countries, who had already prepared for another scenario, welcomed de Gaulle's courageous decision with relief.
Far from calling into question the European integration process, the unrest in France highlighted the interdependencies created by the common market. The growing competition among the Six increased pressure on the national economies and accelerated the diplomatic negotiations to facilitate economic convergence. Two years and a half after May 68, following the ‘relance’ during The Hague summit in December 1969, the Werner committee proposed a ten year plan to create an Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) among the Six. In the meantime, the transnational economic consequences of the May events in France had spread to other member states, stressing the need for common policy to accompany the economic convergence. West Germany quickly recovered from the 1966–7 economic crisis and faced a rapid growth that pushed the Deutsche Mark (D-Mark) up against the weakening French franc. The German government's refusal to revaluate led to a large diplomatic crisis with its Western allies during the Bonn monetary conference in November 1968. In West Germany, this monetary crisis ended in the autumn of 1969 in a large strike movement that started a trend of wage increases during the following decade.
The protest movements of the ‘1968s’ have often been described either as the fruitful failure of an anti-capitalist political revolutionFootnote 1 or as the result of a successful consumerist cultural change.Footnote 2 Although economic issues play a central role in these interpretations of the protests, the economic context of the movements has been less studied. Boltanski's New Spirit of Capitalism emphasised the contrast between the limited economic demands and the importance of the material responses of the governments and trade unions to the protests.Footnote 3 On the contrary, historians highlighted the role of material demands like better wages and higher budgets for education policies in the widespread climate of contest.Footnote 4 Fuelling the debate on the legacy of May 68, Margairaz and Tartakowski stressed the necessity to consider economic and social liberalisation in parallel with political and cultural liberation.Footnote 5 The European integration process is a key element of this liberalisation, as it forced European societies to accept a higher competition level, economic challenges and hard governmental or corporate decisions that favoured protests. Although the link between social movements and the European integration process is often mentioned to explain the growing contests of the 1960s, few studies have systematically taken this issue seriously. German and French authors studied the role of workers’ and farmers’ unions in the European integration process, but without a specific focus on 1968.Footnote 6 Unlike decolonisation or de-Stalinisation, European integration as a response to the economic globalisation and to the destabilisation of the international monetary system is rarely considered as a relevant factor to explain the social protests of the ‘1968s’ as a transnational or global event.
For their part, historians of European integration recently stressed the importance of taking into account the social and political consequences of the growing economic competition between European societies, as well as the role of non-state actors.Footnote 7 However, historical research on the 1960s focussed mainly on diplomatic crises of the EEC.Footnote 8 The influence of European integration on social demands and the impact of social movements on the European process have been emphasised by political scientists for recent periods.Footnote 9 The impact of the European liberalisation process on workers’ demands and government education policies has never been systematically studied. While actors and academics have highlighted the gradual awareness of economic interdependencies within the common market, they have not shed light on the impact of social and political factors in the decision to launch the EMU process. Some authors tried to depict the influence of the transnational economic consequences of students’ and workers’ movements on the European diplomatic relaunch of The Hague in December 1969.Footnote 10 However, the link between the economic and social instability of 1968 and the decision to commit the EEC to building a ‘community of stability’ remains largely unexplored.
This article contextualises the first EMU project and the emergence of the dissemination of the ‘stability policy’ in the framework of social protests and proposes a new reading of May 68 in the light of the European integration history. The connection between social and political history of the nation-states on the one hand and the diplomatic and institutional history of European integration on the other seems particularly relevant. It appears necessary for a better understanding of the Europeanisation process, of the alternatives and various choices that contributed to the acceptance of an increasing integration and to the design of the EMU.Footnote 11 Taking into account interdependencies implies writing a transnational and connected history that follows the circulating economic causes and consequences of political events and decisions.Footnote 12 This article intends to explore some decisive aspects of this history, based on the particularly relevant case of the Franco-German interdependences for European integration and the 1969 relaunch. It will highlight the impact of the growing competition within the common market on social destabilisation, stress transnational links between French and German protest movements of spring 1968 and autumn 1969, and emphasise their key role in the emergence of the ‘community of stability’ as the main European project of the following decades.
Social Unrest of the Early 1960s: The French Economy Facing the Challenge of European Competition
‘It would be absurd for a country like ours to lock itself into customs and trade barriers as we used to do in the past. Therefore, to keep up with the times, day after day, competition is needed once again.’Footnote 13 In his television interview on 14 December 1965, General de Gaulle pointed out the decisive choice France had made by signing and implementing the treaty of Rome in effect from 1 January 1958. During the following decade, France successfully joined the common market and even pushed to accelerate the liberalisation schedules. This choice was based on a fundamental change in the French global strategy, the abandonment of mercantilist politics within a colonial empire and the conversion to international competition as a key factor for the modernisation of the country.Footnote 14 It was an essential pillar of the ‘politics of Grandeur’ implemented by de Gaulle to restore France's rank in the world during the 1960s.
For French society, this new strategy meant increased competition and a rapid economic liberalisation with major social changes. Gehrke and Horn as well as Martin pointed out that the protests of 1968 were preceded by years of workers’ and farmers’ movements in Western Europe.Footnote 15 In 1963–4, strikes broke out in Italy and the Netherlands to protect wages and working conditions. In France, the miners’ strike of March 1963 and the Sud-Aviation strike in April 1968 circumscribe a period of growing protest before May 68. However, the link between these movements and the gradual implementation of the common market is rarely highlighted. Yet the strike in the textile factories of the Rhodiacéta in 1967 was caused by a reduction of the company's activity in order to restructure production to face European competition. Similarly, the fishermen's strike in Boulogne-sur-mer in March 1968 was motivated by an increase in productivity introduced to maintain activity in the face of falling prices on European markets. Few actors were as clear in their criticism of European liberalisation as the farmers opposing the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) with the slogan: ‘We don't want two Europes, one for the rich and one for the poor’.Footnote 16 The following lines will try to clarify the conditions under which the French economy entered the European competition to better understand not only the rise of demands and protests in Europe, but also their specific scale in the case of France.
The conversion to a liberal policy meant a massive transformation of the French economy and was thus a major challenge for all actors. Unlike its partners and competitors, France was poorly prepared for this level of international competition. The French trade balance had been almost constantly in deficit since the end of the nineteenth century, and French trading culture remained largely protectionist.Footnote 17 The rapid transformation of French society during the Trente Glorieuses was more radical than in any other country of the EEC except Italy. The French economy adapted quickly to a new level of international competition. In 1955, 12 per cent of French output was exported, compared to 21 per cent of German output. Nineteen years later, the French level (22 per cent) had caught up with that of Germany (27 per cent).Footnote 18 This was mainly the result of the liberalisation within the EEC. The share of the common market in French foreign trade grew from one quarter to one half during the first decade.
To face the unprecedented competition among the Six, the French governments under de Gaulle introduced an economic liberalisation accompanied by an ‘expansion’ policy that focused on catching up with Germany in order to improve industrialisation and trade balance. Deepening the reforms undertaken by the last governments of the Fourth Republic, the economic consolidation programme of 1959 (called the ‘Pinay-Rueff plan’) balanced the budget, created a new currency (Nouveau franc) and freed prices and wages.Footnote 19 This policy broke with the inflationary tradition of French society and with the double-digit inflation of the 1950s. Between 1962 and 1968, the inflation rate (21.5 per cent) was still higher than in West Germany (15.6 per cent), but it soon became one of the lowest among Western countries.Footnote 20 The growing Franco-German trade relations within the common market were not only a profitable partnership but also a major source of competition. Both countries became each other's main trading partner in 1958–62. However, this new partnership quickly turned to the advantage of West Germany.Footnote 21 As in the other EEC member countries, the French reconstruction and expansion were largely dependent on German exports of manufactured goods and coal. This dependence led to a growing external deficit in France (Table 1).Footnote 22
Table 1. French trade with West Germany between 1960 and 1967 (in millions of French francs)

Source: Centre des Archives économiques et financières (CAEF), 1A-0000046, folder ‘Problème du déficit commercial de la France envers la R.F.A.’, Annex 1: ‘Problème du déficit commercial de la France envers la R.F.A.’, September 1968.
Despite French industrial policy, industrial production grew faster in West Germany (63.7 per cent) than in France (50.7 per cent) in 1958–66. While Italy (104.9 per cent) and the Netherlands (78.9 per cent) were effectively catching up, this was not the case with France.Footnote 23 Facing this situation, de Gaulle called for a revival of France's trade policy in February 1965.Footnote 24 The Quay d'Orsay painted a very worrying picture: the French GNP was now 8 per cent lower than in West Germany, whereas it had been 7 per cent higher in 1958.Footnote 25 Diplomats feared that the weakness of French industries would turn small and medium-sized enterprises into subcontractors of German firms.Footnote 26 The first years of the common market had proved that ‘the view of a Europe where French agricultural exports would counterbalance German industrial exports [was] outdated’.Footnote 27 This situation was to worsen with the completion of the common market in 1968. France would lose the sectorial quota protection implemented to soften the initial shock of market opening. The modernisation of French industry had to accelerate, putting pressure on wages, employment and working conditions. The same applied to agriculture, where the Fifth Plan foresaw an accelerated reduction in the number of farms.
A New Wage Pressure in the EEC: The Economic Crisis in West Germany in 1966–7
The limits of the French catching up were not the only cause of the growing social unrest that can be connected to European liberalisation. European competition also increased because of the first effects of economic interdependence between France and West Germany on French working conditions as well as public budgets. Many studies emphasised the importance of material demands in the movements of 1967–8. The students’ demands were based on academic studies stressing the importance of investing in education policy to meet the challenge of global competition (Picht, Fourastié, Aron).Footnote 28 At the same time, spending restrictions and the attempt to introduce selection at university through the Fouchet reform sparked student movements in the summer of 1967.Footnote 29 Among workers, wages and job protection were the two main demands of the multiple movements breaking out in 1967–8.Footnote 30 Bantigny stressed that these growing material demands created a ‘situation of generation’ shared by young students and young workers, leading to a convergence of struggles in France in the spring of 1968.Footnote 31 That said, it seems important to explain this increase in material demands by economic considerations. Although economic causes are not absent, the analysis of spring 68 focused on national explanations to the detriment of a transnational and comparative perspective. Indeed, the transnational economic context of 1967 and spring 1968 sheds light on the interdependencies within the common market and their consequences for the social context in France, in particular for the increased pressure on wages and public policy budgets.
The French economy was affected by the indirect negative repercussions of the German economic crisis of 1966–7. The recession in West Germany boosted the German trade surplus by lowering wages and reducing prices. In fact, German growth was undergoing a transition after the ‘economic miracle’. Productivity gains remained limited and inflation increased.Footnote 32 The restrictive monetary policy of the Bundesbank worsened the situation and caused a recession in the autumn of 1966. The Grand Coalition government formed in December 1966 reoriented economic policy. In June 1967, the social-democrat Federal Minister for Economics, Karl Schiller, passed a stability and growth law and launched an economic stimulus package. One of the most important measures was the introduction of a ‘concerted action’ that promoted a social dialogue between the federal and regional governments, the Bundesbank, trade unions and employers’ organisations.Footnote 33 The success of the ‘concerted action’ contributed to limiting wages in the following years. In the context of rising unemployment, trade unions proclaimed a wage moderation in order to support the SPD's return to power. West German wages grew by only 1 to 2 per cent in 1967 and 4 to 5 per cent in 1968.Footnote 34 Facing a contraction of domestic demand, West German companies reorganised their production and intensified their efforts to conquer foreign markets. The competitiveness of German products increased by 7.2 per cent in 1969.Footnote 35 Inflation was almost zero (0.4 per cent) and the inflation gap with France (4.6 per cent) increased. Between 1964 and 1968, costs and prices remained almost the same in West Germany, while they increased by 7 points among their main West European competitors.Footnote 36 All this contributed to the excellent figures on a foreign balance sheet whose surpluses reached 18.4 billion in 1968.Footnote 37 The German trade surplus even became worrying for the balance of the world economy.
On the eve of the abolition of the last customs barriers, West German stabilisation policy contributed to increasing pressure on wages in the other EEC countries. In Western Europe, the 1960s were a decade of rapid wage increase that saw ‘the end of the proletariat’ (Table 2).Footnote 38 In spite of this convergence, significant national disparities remained. After Italy, France was the country with the highest increase (+103 per cent). French wages were gradually catching up with those of the Germans (+86 per cent).Footnote 39 However, this was not the case for industry, where the wage increase remained limited in France (+70 per cent). The share of wages in production costs in France remained lower than in other Western European countries. Finally, the average number of hours worked per year was higher in France (2,259) than in the other EEC countries and in particular in West Germany (2,078).Footnote 40 Overall, West German employees enjoyed better wage and working conditions than the French. In the spring of 1968, the French government and trade unions agreed that there was a wage problem in France. The press spread the idea that French salaries were among the lowest in the EEC.Footnote 41 These debates maintained a climate of social protest and opposition to the stabilisation policy led by the Gaullist government.
Table 2. Index of gross hourly wages in the industry between 1958 and 1966 (1958 = 100)

Source: AN, 540 AP-13, folder ‘Problème monétaire international’, Direction de la Prévision économique – Division de l'Actualité économique, table VI ‘Indice des salaires horaires bruts dans l'industrie’, October 1966.
The social climate worsened in France as Pompidou's government strengthened the consolidation policy during the winter of 1967–8. In response to the deterioration in trade with West Germany and to prepare for the 1 July deadline, the Minister of Economy and Finance, Michel Debré, limited public spending to slow growth and reduce inflation.Footnote 42 Imitating West Germany's stabilisation policy, the French government encouraged companies to moderate wages. For the first time since 1960, the purchasing power and the minimum wage (SMIG) stagnated from the second half of 1967. At the same time, the deterioration of the economic situation caused fears of a return to mass unemployment. Despite the creation of the national job agency (ANPE) in July 1967, the unsatisfied employment applications peaked at 465,000 in April 1968, which was more than in the post-crisis West Germany.Footnote 43 Even if the official rate was only 2.6 per cent, unemployment was the first concern of French workers and students during the first months of 1968. In education, the rapid growth of public budgets during the early 1960s was replaced by an anti-inflation policy in 1967–8. Facing a budget deficit, the government chose to cut civil servants’ wages, to limit hiring in education and to postpone necessary but expensive pedagogic reforms.Footnote 44 In addition to implementing the selection process already provided in the Fouchet plan, the government was planning to limit teacher recruitment as well as construction of new university buildings. All these measures came into direct conflict with the students’ main demands. The risk of an economic slowdown and the pressure from the political opposition forced the government to implement a late and limited economic stimulus in January 1968.
Was this final convergence effort the ‘spark’ that ignited the protests in May? This hypothesis has been suggested by the Minister of Social Affairs, Jean-Marcel Jeanneney,Footnote 45 and by de Gaulle's economic advisor, Alain Prate:
But one may wonder whether, by imposing such a rigorous discipline on the French economy, the Plan was not asking too much of the French people […] at the cost of a growing malaise. Of course, its reasons were not all of an economic nature, but this malaise was to contribute to the virulence of the events of 1968.Footnote 46
The trade unions shared this diagnosis and stressed the low level of French wages in comparison with other EEC countries.Footnote 47 In a period of rapid economic growth, the population poorly understood the stabilisation efforts required by the government for diplomatic and economic goals within the EEC. Pressure on wages and budget cuts in education created a particularly explosive social climate in France. Historians stressed the continuity between the strike movements of early spring 1968 and the protests of May 68.Footnote 48 The strikes that broke out on 13 May in support of the student movement were fuelled by demands relating largely to pressure on working conditions and wages. At the Renault factory in Cléon, which played a key role in the start of the national movement, the workers decided to occupy the work site in order to obtain the end of temporary contracts, higher wages and shorter working hours.Footnote 49 The causes of May 68 are obviously not exclusively of an economic nature, but the context of the new convergence policies and the lack of harmonisation of working conditions within the common market also deserve better consideration in the analysis of the growing unrest in France on the eve of May 68.
European Interdependencies: The Economic Consequences of May 68
Unlike most protest movements in Western countries in 1967–8, in France, a wave of strikes accompanied the student movement and triggered a political crisis but also serious economic consequences on the eve of the common market's completion. The French upheaval has long been explained by demands for democratisation and the influence of internationalism within minority groups of neo-Marxist students. Over the last twenty years, historians have emphasised the importance of the material demands of students, workers and farmers, who played a key role in the French mobilisation behind trade unions.Footnote 50 This explains the importance of the material response given by the government and the unions through the Grenelle negotiations, despite the dissatisfaction of a large part of the rank-and-file with their results. As shown by Frank, the ‘Grenelle agreements’ also played a central role in the French debate on the consequences of 1968, which were supposedly the starting point of the country's economic decline.Footnote 51 However, little attention has been paid so far to the European deadline of 1 July, although this is a key issue for both companies and the government. Similarly, the economic consequences have hardly been analysed transnationally in terms of interdependence between European economies. Inflation, trade imbalances, as well as speculation waves also deserve an in-depth study to highlight the consequences of social unrest on European integration. Three major consequences could have threatened French competitiveness: the fall of industrial production, the wage increase after the ‘Grenelle agreements’ and the currency speculation with massive capital flight.
The break in production was at first the main concern for French and European governments. For the vice-president of the European Commission, Raymond Barre, it was an unprecedented ‘phenomenon that had never occurred before on this scale in any of the EEC countries’.Footnote 52 However, these analyses soon proved to be far too alarmist. The disruption was limited to five weeks and affected only some of the companies.Footnote 53 Contrary to popular belief, there was no general strike. The movement did not affect more than six to seven million employees during the last weeks of May. The return to normal occurred gradually in June. In spite of the standstill in railway traffic during two weeks, road traffic and stocks limited the difficulties of supply. Overall, 750 million working hours had been lost and the output gap was estimated at 3 per cent of the annual production. The fall in production in May and June was sharp in the automobile industry (−58 per cent), in electric power generation and in the steel industry (−34 per cent). However, these few weeks of partial break in production could not jeopardise the annual balance of a growing economy. The strikes were followed by a rapid catch-up, which partly compensated the production loss of the spring.Footnote 54 Finally, the annual GNP growth reached 4.3 per cent in 1968.
The second concern for de Gaulle was the long-term consequences of wage increases on national competitiveness.Footnote 55 On 27 May, Pompidou's government, trade unions and employers’ organisations concluded the so-called ‘Grenelle agreements’, which included better working conditions and a major wage increase.Footnote 56 The 1 July 1968 deadline was the backdrop to these negotiations.Footnote 57 On the one hand, French companies wanted to avoid a long-term degradation of their competitiveness by too high wage increases. On the other hand, they feared being driven out of international markets by their competitors were the strikes to continue. Facing a revolutionary situation, employers chose to concede immediately with high wage increases that would be rapidly wiped out by an inevitable devaluation of the franc. The government had hoped to avoid such a scenario, but had to accept it.Footnote 58 In the following months, the ‘Grenelle agreements’ led to a 12.9 per cent wage increase overall and a 35 per cent increase to the minimum wage.Footnote 59 This was 8.3 per cent more than the projected increase for the year 1968, far from the major salaries adjustments in France in 1936 or in the Netherlands in 1963–1964 (+18 per cent).Footnote 60 The wage increase boosted consumption and accelerated inflation (4.3 per cent), widening the inflation gap with West Germany (+1.8 per cent). In one year, inflation wiped out most of the wage gains of ‘Grenelle’ (Table 3).Footnote 61
Table 3. Consumer prices inflation in the major Western economies between 1967 and 1969

Source: Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, ‘Im Sog des Booms’. Jahresgutachten 1969/70 (Stuttgart-Mainz: Kohlhammer Verlag, 1969), 4.
More than the temporary loss of foreign markets, increased domestic demand deteriorated the French trade balance. In addition to wage increases, domestic demand was also sustained by the stimulus package implemented by the government to avoid a recession.Footnote 62 While the French trading situation had improved during the first months of 1968 thanks to the return of German growth, the catch-up of demand until the autumn led to growing deficits in 1968 and 1969.Footnote 63 Half of the French deficit (3 billion francs) was due to Franco-German trade. Despite this, the government refused to postpone the 1 July deadline. It unilaterally introduced temporary export compensations and quotas on the French sectors most vulnerable to competition (automobile, textiles, steel).Footnote 64 Supported by the European Commission, France asked for solidarity from its partners by requesting a ‘mutual assistance’ procedure (art. 108 of the EEC-Treaty). West Germany took an increasing share in the support granted to France. It provided a quarter of the international financial aid granted to France in the summer and autumn of 1968.Footnote 65 Currency quickly became the main concern of the French government. During the 1960s, the new French franc had acquired a solid reputation of stable and strong currency. The policy of the franc fort had been one of the pillars of de Gaulle's ‘politics of Grandeur’.Footnote 66 However, the beginning of the workers’ strike on 13 May launched speculative waves and a flight of capital. The government was forced to reintroduce capital controls on 31 May. Speculation peaked in the last week of June, but continued during the summer, spurred by government stimulus and budget deficit. The removal of capital controls on 4 September triggered a second wave of speculation that would degenerate into currency panic in November. On 20 November, the French government was forced to close the markets. By this time, the Banque de France had lost half the comfortable reserves (34 billion francs) it held before the crisis.Footnote 67 Six months after the protest, the French economy was facing the prospect of a devaluation.
Ultimately, as it had been the government's key diplomatic choice since 1958, May 68 did not stop the 1 July deadline from being met. However, it did reveal to French and Germans alike the importance of European interdependencies and the limits of the stabilisation policy within the new common market. It also placed France under increased speculative pressure, as well as financial and monetary dependence on its partners, particularly West Germany.
A Transnational Consequence of May 68: The German Wildcat Strikes
Despite these domestic causes, the crisis of the French currency was also a part of a bigger picture. Historians of international monetary relations usually depict the monetary crisis following May 68 as an episode in the general crisis of the international monetary system after the devaluation of the British pound in November 1967 and the negotiations on the Special Drawing Rights proposed by the United States to compensate the fall of the dollar.Footnote 68 The diplomatic consequences of this monetary crisis have also been described as well as the failure of the Bonn conference in November 1968 to force a revaluation of the D-Mark.Footnote 69 However, most authors insist on the ‘limited impact of student protest’ on this economic and diplomatic history.Footnote 70 Indeed, the domestic importance of this monetary and diplomatic crisis for the resolution of social unrest in France is never placed in a transnational perspective explaining the French position by European interdependencies, especially by the German domestic context. The same can be said of the evolution of the West German economic culture and of the extension of social tensions to West Germany. As a diplomatic consequence of May 68, the monetary crisis of November 1968 highlighted a major factor blocking Europeanisation, namely the limits of solidarity in the face of interdependences. It revealed the Germans’ attachment to their currency and their reluctance to give up its strength. It also gave shape to the criticism levelled by France and other Europeans at the monetary power and lack of solidarity of the Germans in Europe. The fundamental oppositions over future monetary union negotiations had thus emerged in the wake of May 68. Finally, the economic and social consequences of the November diplomatic crisis have barely been analysed in a transnational perspective by the German literature on the wildcat strikes of autumn 1969.Footnote 71 By linking the French protest to the German strike movement of autumn 1969, the monetary crisis demonstrates the relevance of economic interdependences for the transnational history of 1968.
Amongst the main Western economies, only the D-Mark remained a strong currency after May 68. Trade surpluses and speculative waves inflated the Bundesbank's gold and dollar reserves from 4.7 billion D-Mark in January 1968 to 33.3 billion in November.Footnote 72 Under those circumstances, West Germany's allies asked for a revaluation of the D-Mark. However, the idea of a revaluation was against the economic culture of West German political leaders. Monetary stability had been a fundamental element of the ‘Social Market Economy’ since 1948. The rapid export boom during the ‘economic miracle’ was underpinned by the undervaluation of the D-Mark that reduced the price of West German products. As Germany demonstrated, the monetary undervaluation remained a keystone of the first West German economic model in the 1950s–1960s.Footnote 73 Nevertheless, the Bundesbank and most German experts were already in favour of a revaluation in the summer of 1968. According to the Council of Economic Experts (Sachverständigenrat) and the Scientific Council of the Federal Ministry for Economics, a revaluation was necessary to fight against ‘imported inflation’ that was caused by other countries’ trade deficits.Footnote 74 While the Federal Minister for Economics, Karl Schiller, was concerned about jeopardising the recovery, the Federal Minister of Finance, Franz Josef Strauß, supported the interests of export industries and farmers.Footnote 75 Above all, German opinion considered that monetary imbalances were the result of policies and social unrest in other countries. It was therefore not West Germany's responsibility to change its model to resolve them.
Following these domestic debates, the Bonn conference on 20–22 November 1968 was a failure, despite combined pressure from the Western allies. To avoid a revaluation, the Bundestag adopted a series of temporary measures to rebalance Franco-German trade: a 4 per cent tax on West German exports and a 4 per cent subsidy on imports. At the same time, West Germany was taking an increasing share in international financial support to France ($1.65 billion in credit), now playing a financial role equivalent to that of the United States.Footnote 76 Meanwhile, the French government launched a new stabilisation programme with significant budget cuts and the reintroduction of exchange controls.Footnote 77 The franc was saved temporarily. However, the diplomatic consequences of the monetary crisis were disastrous. The international press reported loudly on the German diplomatic ‘victory’. The Bild-Zeitung headlined: ‘Now, the Germans are number one in Europe’.Footnote 78
These domestic and diplomatic debates on the revaluation of the D-Mark raised the question of the West German monetary strategy in world trade. Whether West Germany could keep an undervalued D-Mark and continue to favour its exports and accumulate a trade surplus, or if it could assume the strength of its economy with a strong currency, a higher purchasing power for the population, but also increased political responsibilities within the international monetary order. The Grand Coalition postponed this fundamental political choice to the general election of September 1969. In the meantime, the pace of German growth accelerated, supported by the strength of US and French domestic demand. Under these circumstances, the measures taken in November by the Bundestag soon proved insufficient to limit the German trade surplus.Footnote 79 The economy was almost overheating and the inflation gap with Germany's main trade partners was now over seven points.Footnote 80 Once again, the French context reopened the debate on German revaluation. De Gaulle's withdrawal on 27 April 1969 triggered a new wave of speculation on the D-Mark even stronger than those in May and November 1968. Between 28 April and 9 May 1969, 17 billion D-Mark were traded. Not only the experts and the Bundesbank, but now also the Federal Minister for Economics called for a revaluation. Schiller saw imported inflation as a greater evil that would force him to pursue a restrictive fiscal policy in the long term and risk fuelling the growing social protest among workers.Footnote 81 A revaluation would mean an increase in the purchasing power of employees. Schiller asked for a 6.25 revaluation but was outvoted in the government by a coalition behind Strauß.Footnote 82 The revaluation became a campaign theme of the SPD (Social Democratic Party) with the support of the unions. On the other side, Strauß and the CDU/CSU (Christian Democratic Union/Christian Social Union) defended the interests of the export industry and of the farmers who would lose a substantial part of the European subsidies in case of a revaluation.
Most importantly, the revaluation debate questioned the monetary model of an undervalued D-Mark that had contributed to the ‘economic miracle’ in the 1950s. Most experts considered that the fight against inflation should become the first priority of the monetary policy.Footnote 83 Therefore, the consequences of a strong D-Mark had to be accepted by exporting companies that were now ready to face international competition. In other words, West Germany had to assume its newfound economic power. This fundamental debate became a major issue in the campaign of the parliamentary elections and blocked the international monetary situation for months. In France, the deterioration of the trade and monetary situation did not justify in itself a devaluation. However, the franc was no longer able to resist the speculative wave that was looming with the German elections in September. The German elections were a ‘monetary horizon’ for the French government that decided to devalue the franc by 12.5 per cent on 11 August 1969.Footnote 84
In the meantime, West Germany experienced an adjustment inflation resulting from the undervaluation of the D-Mark and from the wage moderation. Since the 1966–7 crisis, the ‘concerted action’ had kept wages low. In 1968, average wage growth was limited to 4 per cent for a growth rate of 7.2 per cent.Footnote 85 However, the return of growth and inflation called slowly this wage moderation into question.Footnote 86 Paradoxically, the good health of the West German economy and its growing trade surplus contributed to social discontent. The workers demanded their share of the large profits made by the companies abroad. The 8 per cent wage increase negotiated by the unions during the summer was deemed insufficient in view of the 10 per cent production growth.Footnote 87 Wildcat strikes broke out in Dortmund in the first days of September 1969. In the following weeks, the movement spread to 140,000 workers in steel, metal, mining, textile industries and public services, mainly in the Ruhr and the Saarland.Footnote 88 These strikes gave the signal for a general revision of wage agreements in West Germany. While the planned increase under the ‘concerted action’ was 7 per cent, wage increases averaged 9.5 per cent in 1969.Footnote 89 By challenging the credibility of the ‘concerted action’, the wildcat strikes opened a cycle of social demands and wage inflation that lasted until the mid-1970s.Footnote 90
The strike movement fed the revaluation's debate on the eve of the 28 September parliamentary elections. A new wave of speculation forced the government to suspend the D-Mark's value and to close currency exchanges.Footnote 91 The timing could not be worse for Chancellor Kiesinger, who finally lost the chancellorship to a SPD/FDP coalition. During the coalition negotiations, the government decided unilaterally to let the D-Mark float on 30 September. In order to mitigate the negative effects of the rising D-Mark on West German agricultural prices, it introduced temporarily monetary compensatory amounts supporting exports in this sector. These compensatory amounts had been first introduced after the French devaluation to compensate its effects on European agriculture prices by limiting exports. These measures were strongly criticised by Germany's partners and the European Commission.Footnote 92 The formation of the Brandt government on 21 October resolved the crisis and paved the way for an 8 per cent revaluation on 27 October.Footnote 93 After the devaluation of the franc, the revaluation of the D-Mark restored the balance of parities and confidence in currencies, ending a two-year monetary crisis.
The crisis opened by the events of May 68 highlighted the interdependence of West European economies within the common market. The higher consumption in France after the ‘Grenelle agreements’ increased inflation in West Germany and was therefore one of the indirect factors of the wildcat strikes by calling into question the German trade model. The speculation waves in France had a major impact not only on the West German economic policy, but also on the 1969 elections. Hence, the influence of the 1968–9 movements on the ‘second foundation’ of West Germany was both direct, through Brandt's adoption of some of the demands of the German student movements, and indirect, through the economic and social effects of the European social context. The exchange rate changes of the second semester 1969 were followed by the introduction of monetary compensatory amounts that disorganised European agriculture markets and were a lasting problem for the CAP until the creation of the Euro. The crisis had definitely proved wrong the idea of an automatic convergence of European economies within the common market. On the contrary, the growing interdependences within the EEC made more economic cooperation and monetary solidarity necessary to let national economies converge.
The Origins of the European Monetary Union: The Project of a ‘Community of Stability’
Then came the spring of 1968 and the explosion in France of the student unrest, which, after the United States, had spread to Europe. […] Our isolated countries were now vulnerable to the currents of violence sweeping the world, and none of them could protect themselves alone. On trips to Bonn, I realised that the Germans felt more than we did the dangers whose shock waves had hit them first. They were anxious to see the dramatic effects on French society and had seen the main axis of European policy in Paris waver. (Jean Monnet)Footnote 94
These lines from the memoirs of Jean Monnet, who was the architect of the conference of The Hague, illustrate the major role played by May 68 in the European relaunch of 1969. It raised awareness of the growing interdependencies within the EEC. The literature highlighted how de Gaulle's withdrawal opened the way for new discussions between Pompidou and Brandt based on a triptych: completion of the CAP, widening the community, deepening the economic cooperation and monetary solidarity.Footnote 95 This monetary part of the relaunch has also been analysed to explain the failure of the first draft of the EMU project (Werner report) in 1970 because of a fundamental and lasting opposition between a ‘monetarist’ and an ‘economic’ view.Footnote 96 However, these diplomatic explanations only partially shed light on the European socio-economic context of these different national EMU projects emerging in the wake of the monetary crisis of 1968. The central objective of stabilising European economies is often described in a transatlantic perspective, without reference to Western European protest movements.Footnote 97 While the Six recognised the need for the relaunch of The Hague, the lessons learned from 68 led them to very different visions of the European project. Drawing on new German sources, the following lines will highlight the influence of the protest movements of 1968–9 on the German project for a ‘community of stability’ as well as on its rejection by France.
The idea of a common European currency was not new. In 1962, the European Commission submitted a first memorandum for a common currency and a second one in February 1968 in response to the first effects of the crisis of the international monetary system.Footnote 98 The plan of the Commission's French vice-president, Raymond Barre, proposed to introduce an automatic monetary support mechanism and was adopted by the Community's Council on 17 July 1969. The creation of a European monetary solidarity mechanism first had to be accepted by the main contributors, starting with West Germany. Following this logic, Monnet chose to rely on Brandt, to whom he passed on the project of a European Reserve Fund.Footnote 99 For Brandt, the issue was not only economic but also, and above all, political, considering that West Germany's economic power should be put at the service of the European convergence. On 27 November, the chancellor informed Pompidou of a draft that seemed to satisfy the main French demands.Footnote 100 The European Reserve Fund project thus became one of the pillars of a joint relaunch at the conference of The Hague on 1–2 December and paved the way to negotiations on the EMU that started in March 1970 within the Werner committee. However, this traditional narrative of the relaunch forgets one decisive aspect: Brandt's speech at the conference referred to an ‘economic policy coordination’ that was actually the core project of German ministries.Footnote 101 The Auswärtiges Amt and the Federal Ministry for Economics were both sceptical about Monnet's proposal and refused to jeopardise Germany's reserves and stability to finance the lax monetary policy of its partners.
To counter Monnet's initiative and the ‘monetarist’ view of the EMU, the German Federal Ministry for Economics prepared an ‘economist’ proposal summed up in the ‘Schiller Plan’. This plan aimed to create a ‘community of stability’ (Stablitätsgemeinschaft) between EEC countries. The new community would generalise stability policy and make the fight against inflation the key to European convergence.Footnote 102 The architect of this plan was Hans Tietmeyer, who would become the Bundesbank's president and one of the most important figures in European monetary history.Footnote 103 The Schiller Plan built on the West German analysis of the movements of 1968–9 and of the consequences of the interdependencies created by the common market. For the Council of Economic Experts, the transnational consequences of May 68 had proved that West Germany could not ignore its partners any more by pursuing an isolated stability policy that could now be jeopardised by an ‘imported inflation’.Footnote 104 It had therefore become imperative to link the issues of convergence and monetary stability within the EEC. In June 1968, the Federal Ministry for Economics drafted its first plans to relaunch European integration through the convergence of economic policies and the creation of a single market with free movement of services, persons and capital.Footnote 105 This implied the definition of an ambitious European policy aimed at spreading stability throughout the entire EEC.
Although this strategy had already been discussed before in the context of recurring imbalances in the international monetary system, it became West Germany's European strategy after the economic and social turbulences of 1968–9. For the German government, the priority was now to avoid the economic consequences of another May 68 in France or elsewhere in Europe. This strategy could seem ambitious, but it was credible in the eyes of the Germans precisely because of the consequences of May 68 in France. The events in France had demonstrated the fragility of the French economy's conversion to stability since the end of the 1950s.Footnote 106 Therefore, the EMU process had to be based on a new political commitment of the nations to the stability policy. Nevertheless, Schiller and the Bundesbank were convinced that French elites were now ready to accept large concessions, including supranational economic control, to access German monetary support.Footnote 107
However, the German diplomacy deeply overestimated the concessions France was ready to accept. The Werner report of October 1970 was largely inspired by the Schiller Plan and proposed a step-by-step plan based on the precedence of economic convergence to stability over monetary solidarity.Footnote 108 Pompidou was very critical of the German liberalism that led to a ‘brutal and uncontrolled capitalism’.Footnote 109 Above all, the French president considered it dangerous to abandon monetary instruments that guaranteed a margin of manoeuvre for economic policy in the event of a return to social protest:
If there is a new May 1968, it is not Mr. Malfatti [President of the Commission] who will speak to the Séguy [Secretary General of the General Confederation of Labour] of that time. We do not govern machines; we govern people. […] If we had the Community as it is proposed, with rigid budgets that are out of balance, we would have the Communists in power in France and Italy, and it is not the Community that could change anything to it.Footnote 110
Finally, the fear of a new May 68 justified Pompidou's refusal of a premature EMU.Footnote 111 It explains also the French reluctance to accept further liberalisation during the following decades. Exchange controls had been abolished in December 1967 but were restored in November 1968 until 1989. Price controls were maintained until 1986. Wage indexation to inflation was abolished in 1959 and reintroduced in autumn 1969 until 1983. Liberal convergence to stability policy was going to be a long road. First saved by the compromise between Brandt and Pompidou in February 1971, the Werner plan was abandoned in 1974.
Conclusion
Connecting the history of the common market's completion and that of social protests of the ‘1968s’ reveals the extent of interdependencies within the early European Community and their economic, social, political and diplomatic consequences on a transnational scale. The social protest can also be read in the light of its economic causes and consequences in the framework of European integration. Beyond cultural and political demands, the increased European competition created pressure on wages and work conditions that provided a favourable context for social protest. This pressure was all the stronger in countries like France trying to catch up economically before the complete opening up to European competition. Even accentuated by the European and international context, the economic consequences of the strike wave did not stop the completion of the common market nor initiate a general decline of a growing French economy. However, the following monetary crisis raised awareness of interdependencies within the EEC and led to the first EMU negotiations. Far from reinforcing the social dimension of European integration, the interpretations of May 68 had a major influence on the design of the first EMU project by focusing it on German stability policy.
This convergence process originated in a social and monetary crisis interpreted by actors as a crisis of adaptation to the economic modernisation imposed by the common market. In the meantime, the protest opened a parenthesis in the liberalisation of the French economy, postponing for political reasons the liberalisation of exchange, price and wage controls to the 1980s. On the French side, May 68 appears as one of the first social movements challenging the stability policy spreading in the EEC. First, the social demands of May 68 can be read as a critique of the pressure for competitiveness created by the liberalisation of European markets and a challenge to the anti-inflation policy implemented during the early 1960s. Second, the fear of a return of protest led to a pause in the liberalisation process in France, but more broadly at the level of the EEC with the failure of the EMU process until the late 1980s. In this perspective, the protest can be interpreted, as Ross does, as an ‘interruption’ in the economic convergence process in European societies.Footnote 112 Conversely, the German interpretation of the French and German protest movements of 1968 and 1969 resulted in the adoption of the concept of ‘community of stability’ designed to spread stability policy to all EEC countries. On the German side, the crisis forced West Germany to accept a new monetary and trade model with a strong D-Mark and an increased responsibility in the international monetary system. It created the conditions for the first experiment of floating the D-Mark, which was to make a major contribution to West Germany's challenge to the international monetary system in the 1970s and to the creation of a ‘D-Mark zone’ based on stability policy in Western Europe. In this perspective, May 68 can also be interpreted, as Malinowski and Sedlmaier do, as a ‘catalyst’ of further developments of the capitalist society.Footnote 113 However, this article introduces a third interpretation. The transnational perspective on economic issues suggests an understanding of the ‘1968s’ as embedded in a long period including economic and diplomatic aspects, starting with the first phase of European liberalisation between the implementation of the common market and the negotiations on the single European act (1958–85).
Beyond these major consequences for European integration, this transnational and multidimensional history of May 68 invites us to write a more connected history of the Europeanisation process. In spite of the recent interest in a non-teleological history that takes into account the debates and alternatives,Footnote 114 the narrative of the European integration remains often rather disconnected from the social and political contexts of the member states. The same applies to the compared history of protest movements and to the transnational history of the ‘1968s’, which mostly pay little attention to the growing economic and social interdependencies resulting from diplomatic choices. On the contrary, the transnational study of the multidimensional consequences of the European convergence process, of its progress and limits, makes it possible to connect these histories and opens the way to writing the history of the Europeanisation of the national societies. By connecting the different scales of European narratives, it tells a different story, that of a difficult and long-term process of liberalisation and convergence towards a European economic and social model.
Funding statement
This research has been co-funded by the European Union (Jean-Monnet Chair EU-CONV). Views and opinions expressed are, however, those of the author only and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Union or the European Education and Culture Executive Agency (EACEA). Neither the European Union nor EACEA can be held responsible for them.