Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T05:08:59.314Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Gold, Debt and the Quest for Monetary Order: The Nazi Campaign to Integrate Europe in 1940

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 March 2017

STEPHEN G. GROSS*
Affiliation:
Department of History and Center for European and Mediterranean Studies, New York University, 53 Washington Square South, Floor 4E, New York, NY 10012; [email protected]

Abstract

This article explores Nazi visions for a new monetary order in 1940 and compares these plans with European monetary integration after 1945. It shows how Nazi experts identified the same core monetary challenges facing Europe as Allied planners did during and after the Second World War, above all challenges stemming from the Great Depression and associated with the gold standard, international debts, capital scarcity and bilateral treaties. This comparison suggests a certain logic was inherent to reconstructing European monetary relations after the depression, insofar as few viable alternatives seemed open – either in 1940 or after 1945 – to some form of multilateral payment system that was divorced from gold, yet that still fixed Europe's currencies to one another. Ultimately, it argues that 1940 marks an important step in a longer process in which Europe moved away from territorial currencies toward a monetary union, and in doing so expanded the framework of fiat currency beyond national markets to encompass the continent.

Type
Forum
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Lipgens, Walter, ed., Documents on the History of European Integration (New York: De Gruyter, 1985)Google Scholar, doc. 6.

2 Tooze, Adam, Wages of Destruction: the Making and Breaking of the Nazi War Economy (New York: Penguin Press, 2006)Google Scholar; Klemann, Hein and Kudryashov, Sergei, Occupied Economies: an Economic History of Nazi-Occupied Europe, 1939–1945 (New York: Berg, 2012)Google Scholar; Aly, Gotz, Hitler's Beneficiaries: Plunder, Racial War, and the Nazi Welfare State (Frankfurt a.M.: Fischer Verlag, 2005)Google Scholar.

3 Herbst, Ludolf, Der Totale Krieg und die Ordnung der Wirtschaft: Die Kriegswirtschaft im Spannungsfeld von Politik, Ideologie und Propaganda (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, 1982), 127–43Google Scholar; Burleigh, Michael, The Third Reich: A New History (New York: Hill and Wang, 2000), 422–31Google Scholar; James, Harold, ‘Post-War German Currency Plans’, in Buchheim, Christoph, Hutter, Michael and James, Harold, eds., Zerrissene Zwischenkriegszeit: wirtschaftshistorische Beiträge. Knut Borchardt zum 65. Geburtstag (Baden-Baden: Nomos, 1994), 205–18Google Scholar.

4 Dinan, Desmond, Ever Closer Union: An Introduction to European Integration (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 2010)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gillingham, John, European Integration, 1950–2003. Superstate or New Market Economy? (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Leucht, Wolfram Kaiser, Brigitte and Rasmussen, Morten, eds., The History of the European Union: Origins of a Trans- and Supranational Polity, 1950–72 (New York: Routledge, 2009)Google Scholar; Steil, Ben, The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Eichengreen, Barry, Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2008)Google Scholar. An exception is Skidelsky, Robert, John Maynard Keynes 1883–1946: Economist, Philosopher, Statesman (New York: Penguin Books, 2003), 669–78Google Scholar.

5 Quotation from Sandkühler, Thomas, ‘Europa und der Nationalsozialismus. Ideologie, Währungspolitik, Massengewalt’, Zeithistorische Forschungen/Studies in Contemporary History, 9 (2012), 428–41Google Scholar, here 433; See also Sandkühler, Thomas, ed., Deutsche Hegemonialpolitik gegenüber Westeuropa, 1920–1960 (Göttingen: Wallstein, 2002)Google Scholar; Mazower, Mark, Dark Continent: Europe's Twentieth Century (New York: Vintage Books, 1998), 150–1Google Scholar; Mazower, Mark, Hitler's Empire: Nazi Rule in Occupied Europe (New York: Penguin, 2008), 102–36Google Scholar, 570–2; Volkmann, Hans-Erich, ‘Zur Europäischen Dimension nationalsozialistischer Wirtschaftspoltitik’, in Volkmann, Hans-Erich, ed., Ökonomie und Expansion: Grundzüge der NS-Wirtschaftspolitik (Munich: Oldenbourg Verlag, 2003), 1944 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Eichengreen, Barry, Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995)Google Scholar; Gallarotti, Guilio M., The Anatonomy of an International Monetary Regime: The Classical Gold Standard, 1880–1914 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995)Google Scholar.

7 Helleiner, Eric, The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2003), 140–62Google Scholar.

8 Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital; Frieden, Jeffry, Global Capitalism: Its Fall and Rise in the Twentieth Century (New York: W.W. Norton, 2006)Google Scholar.

9 Dyson, Kenneth, Elusive Union: The Process of Economic and Monetary Union in Europe (New York: Longman, 1994)Google Scholar; Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital; Steil, Bretton Woods; Helleiner takes a different view, tracing the origins to American money doctors in Latin America during the interwar years. Helleiner, Eric, Forgotten Foundations of Bretton Woods: International Development and the Making of the Postwar Order (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2014)Google Scholar.

10 As Alan Milward suggested thirty years ago, ‘Western Europe was reconstructed, not from the destructive consequences of the Second World War only, but from those of the catastrophic economic collapse of 1929–1932’. Milward, Alan, The Reconstruction of Western Europe, 1945–1951 (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1984)Google Scholar, 463; see also Boyce, Robert, The Great Interwar Crisis and the Collapse of Globalization (London: Palgrave MacMillan, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Roselli, Alessandro, Money and Trade Wars in Interwar Europe (New York: Palgrave MacMillan, 2014)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Moravscik, Andrew, The Choice For Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1998)Google Scholar; Milward, Alan, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (New York: Routledge, 2000)Google Scholar; Lipgens, Walter, A History of European Integration: The Formation of the European Unity Movement, Vol. I (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1982)Google Scholar.

12 Ribbentrop's experts wanted to integrate Western Europe in one fell swoop immediately after the end of hostilities, but the other planning authorities rejected this shock approach. Surprisingly, Krosigk hardly figured in these debates; only occasionally did he enter in the conversation to advance a gradualist approach. On the power struggle between Göring and Ribbentrop see Amt, Auswärtiges, Documents on German Foreign Policy (DGFP), (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1949–64)Google Scholar, Vol. X, doc. 103, 115 and doc. 142, 170; Marc Buggeln, ‘Währungspläne für den europäischen Grossraum’, in Sandkühler, ed., Deutsche Hegemonialpolitik, 41–76, here 50–1; On Krosigk's noteworthy absence see the integration forum, ‘Um ein neues Europa: Die Stellung der deutschen Exportwirtschaft’, with essays from all the major players, though not him, in Die Deutsche Volkswirtschaft, 10/9 (1940).

13 Buggeln, ‘Währungspläne’; Marc Buggeln, ‘Europa-Bank oder Dollar-Freihandel?’ in Sandkühler, ed., Deutsche Hegemonialpolitik, 127–44.

14 Ruggie, John Gerard, ‘International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order’, International Organization, 36, 2 (1982), 379415 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Helleiner, Bretton Woods, 7.

15 Ritschl, Albrecht, Deutschlands Krise und Konjunktur 1924–1934 (Berlin: Akademie Verlag, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; James, Harold, The End of Globalization: Lessons from the Great Depression (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2001), 5163 Google Scholar; Ellis, Howard, Exchange Control in Central Europe (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1941), 158–89Google Scholar, figures from 170 and 177; Ahamed, Liaquat, The Lords of Finance: The Bankers who Broke the World (New York: Penguin Books, 2009), 393421 Google Scholar; Kindleberger, Charles, The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (Berkeley: UC Press, 1986)Google Scholar, 153; Tooze, Wages, chs. 3, 4 and 5; Ebi, Michael, Export um jeden Preis. Die Deutsche Exportförderung von 1932–1938 (Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag, 2004)Google Scholar.

16 Roselli, Trade Wars, 120.

17 Ellis, Exchange Control, 261, 290–372; Banken, Ralf, ‘Das nationalsozialistische Devisenrecht als Steuerungs- und Diskriminierungsinstrument 1933–1945’, in Bahr, Johannes and Banken, Ralf, eds., Wirtschaftssteuerung durch Recht im Nationalsozialismus (Frankfurt a.M: Vittorio Klostermann, 2006), 121236 Google Scholar; The Nazis also used capital controls to dispossess emigrating Jews of their assets. Dean, Martin, Robbing the Jews: The Confiscation of Jewish Property in the Holocaust, 1933–1945 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2008)Google Scholar.

18 ‘Die Möglichkeit einer allgemeinen Währungsangleichung nach dem Kriege’, 30 Mar. 1940, Bundesarchiv Berlin (BAB), 2501, 6433; Roselli, Trade Wars, 105–37.

19 Karl Ritter's memo on bilateralism in DGFP, Vol. V, doc. 511, 17 Aug. 1936; Gross, Stephen G., Export Empire: German Soft Power in Southeastern Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20 Eichengreen, Golden Fetters, 337–55; James, Harold, The Nazi Dictatorship and the Deutsche Bank (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2004)Google Scholar, 187. See also Spreng, R., ‘Vereinfachung der Devisenbewirtschaftung’, Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift für Bank- und Börsenwesen, 39 (1939)Google Scholar, 537.

21 Buggeln, ‘Währungspläne’, 50–51; DGFP Vol. X, doc. 103 and doc. 142; Milward, Alan, The New Order and the French Economy (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1970), 46–7Google Scholar; quotation from Göring in Reich Chancellery Memorandum ‘Organization of the German Economy’, 9 July 1940, doc. 3, in Lipgens, Documents, 57.

22 Bajohr, Frank: Aryanisation’ in Hamburg: The Economic Exclusion of Jews and the Confiscation of their Property in Nazi Germany (New York: Berghahn Books, 2001)Google Scholar; Buggeln, ‘Währungspläne’, 51.

23 The initial queries went out on 22 July 1940. Reichstelle für Aussenhandel, Response of Foreign Trade Office for Lower Rhine, 10 Aug. 1940, BAB, R9, 122, 3/3.

24 Response from North Westphalia and Ruhr, 16 Aug. 1940, BAB, R9, 122 3/3.

25 Response from Lower Rhine / Düsseldorf, 10 Aug. 1940, BAB, R9, 122 3/3.

26 Response from Saxony, 16 Aug. 1940, BAB, R9, 122 3/3.

27 Response from North Bavaria, 16 Aug. 1940, BAB, R9, 122 3/3.

28 Herbst, Totale Krieg, 145; Li, Wei, Deutsche Pläne zur europäische wirtschaftlichen Neuordnung 1939–1945 (Hamburg: Verlag Dr. Kovac, 2007), 75114 Google Scholar.

29 Freytag, Carl, Deutschlands ‘Drang nach Südosten’: Der Mitteleuropäische Wirtschaftstag und der ‘Ergänzungsraum Südosteuropa’ 1931–1945 (Vienna: Vienna University Press, 2012)Google Scholar.

30 Hayes, Peter, Industry and Ideology: IG Farben in the Nazi Era (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), 266–73Google Scholar; Schnitzler, von and Krueger, Dr., ‘Concerning the “New Order” Planning for the Chemical Field in Relation to the Possible Formation of a European Economic Sphere’, 3 Aug. 1940, in Nuremberg Military Tribunals, Vol. VII (Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, 1953), 1451–62Google Scholar.

31 ‘Schreiben des Rheinisch-Westfälischen Kohlensyndikats an Reichswirtschaftsminister Funk’, 3 Sept. 1940, doc. 118 in Opitz, Reinhard, ed., Europastrategien des deutschen Kapitals 1900–1945 (Bonn: Pahl-Rugenstein, 1994), 766–9Google Scholar.

32 On cartels see Gillingham, John, Coal, Steel, and the Rebirth of Europe, 1945–1955. The Germans and French from Ruhr Conflict to Economic Community (Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press, 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Ziegler, Dieter, ‘A Regulated Market Economy? New Perspectives on the Nature of the Economic Order of the Third Reich’ in Berghoff, Hartmuff, ed., Business in the Age of Extremes (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2013), 139–52Google Scholar.

33 ‘Aus einem Tätigkeitsbericht des Hauptgeschäftsführers der Reichsgruppe Industrie, Karl Guth’, 15 July 1940, doc. 105, in Opitz, Europastrategien, 702–3; Wilhelm Zangen's (of RGI) response to Gustav Schlotterer, 3 Oct. 1940, doc. 620 in Noakes, J. and Pridham, G., eds., Nazism 1919–1945. Volume 3: Foreign Policy, War and Racial Extermination. A Documentary Reader (Exeter: University of Exeter Press, 1988), 894–8Google Scholar; ‘Aus einer streng vertraulichen Aktennotiz des Geschäftsführers der Wirtschaftsgruppe Feinmechanik/Optik, Karl Albrecht’, 19 June 1940, doc. 98 in Opitz, Europastrategien, 684–5.

34 Quotation from ‘Punkte für die Satzung der Bank für europäischen Zahlungsausgleich’, 3 July 1940, BAB, Reichsbank R2501, 6428.

35 Buggeln, ‘Währungspläne’, 55, fn 45.

36 ‘Währungsfragen im europäischen Grossraum’ from Martini, likely late June or early July, BAB, R2501, 6428, 24; Report from Albert Pietzsch, President of Reichswirtschaftskammer, ‘Zur Frage der Ordnung des europäischen Wirtschaftsraums’, 24 July 1940, doc. 108 in Schumann, Wolfgang and Nestler, Ludwig, eds., Weltherrschaft im Visier (Berlin: Deutscher Verlag der Wissenschaften, 1975), 268–70Google Scholar.

37 ‘Währungsfragen im europäischen Grossraum’, BAB, R2501, 6428.

38 ‘Währungsfragen im europäischen Grossraum’, BAB, R2501, 6428. See also Reichsbank's comments on Martini's proposals in ‘Währungsfrage im Europäischen Grosswirtschaftsraum’, 6 July 1940, Ibid.

39 ‘Aus der Niederschrift einer Besprechung im RWM über “Fragen der wirtschaftlichen Neugestaltung Europas”’, 15 July 1940, doc. 107 in Schumann and Neslter, Weltherrschaft, 266–7.

40 ‘Karl Albrecht: Gustav Schlotterer's views on the “New Order in Europe”’, 19 July 1940, doc. 4 in Lipgens, Documents, 59–60; ‘Aus einer streng vertraulichen Aktennotiz des Geschäftsführers der Wirtschaftsgruppe Feinmechanik/Optik, Karl Albrecht’, 19 June 1940, doc. 98 in Opitz, Europastrategien, 684–5; see also Li, Deutsche Pläne, 54.

41 Quotation from Schlotterer to RGI Sitzung, 3 Oct. 1940, BAB, R8122, 125. See also report of meeting between Puhl and Schlotterer, 2 July 1940, BAB, 2501, 7017; ‘Aus der Niederschrift einer Besprechung im Reichswirtschaftsministerium’ 15 July 1940, doc. 107 in Schumann and Nestler, 266–7; Roselli, Trade Wars, 180–4.

42 ‘Karl Albrecht: Gustav Schlotterer's views on the “New Order in Europe”’, 19 July 1940, Lipgens, Documents, doc. 4; ‘Aus der Niederschrift über eine Sitzung der Reichsgruppe Industrie zum Thema “Neu Ordnung im europäischen Wirtschaftsraum”’, 4 Sept. 1940, doc. 120, in Opitz, Europastrategien, 771–6; ‘Bericht über eine Besprechung in der Hauptabteilung II des RWM’, 30 July 1940, doc. 110, and ‘Albert Pietzsch, Zur Frage der Ordnung des europäischen Wirtschaftsraums’, 24 July 1940, doc. 108 in Schumann and Nestler, Weltherrschaft, 271–3, 268–70.

43 Friedrich Landfried, ‘Das deutsche Wirtschaftspotential: eine der stärksten Grundlagen der künftigen europäischen Zusammenarbeit’, Die Deutsche Volkswirtschaft, 30, 1940, 936–40.

44 On the exchange of ideas between the Reichsbank and the banking community see, for instance, the memo authored by the Deutschen Institut für Bankwissenschaft und Bankwesen, ‘Zur Deutschen Aussenwirtschafts– und Währungspolitk nach dem Kriege’, 9 Sept. 1940, BAB, 2501, 7017.

45 Born, Karl Erich, International Banking in the 19th and 20th Centuries (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1983), 287–90Google Scholar; Wandel, Eckhard, Das deutsche Bankwesen im Dritten Reich (1933–1945) (Frankfurt a.M.: Instituts für bankhistorische Forschung e.V., 1983)Google Scholar.

46 ‘Währungsfrage im Europäischen Grosswirtschaftsraum’, 6 July 1940, BAB, R2501, 6428.

47 Klemann and Kudryashov, Occupied Economies, 210; Ritschl, Albrecht, ‘Nazi Economic Imperialism and the Exploitation of the Small: Evidence from Germany's Secret Foreign Exchange Balances, 1938–40’, Economic History Review, 54 (2001), 224–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

48 Tooze, Wages, 387.

49 Plfeiderer, Otto, ‘Die Feuerprobe der Währungssysteme’, Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift für Bank- und Börsenwesen, 39 (1939), 481–5Google Scholar.

50 ‘Der Zahlungsverkehr im europäischen Grosswirtschaftsraum’, 20 July 1940, BAB, R2501, 6428.

51 Reichsbank Memo ‘Probleme der äusseren Währungspolitik nach Beendigung des Krieges’, 20 June 1940, doc. 98 in Opitz, Europastrategien, 685–90.

52 Czichon, Eberhard, Deutsche Bank. Macht, Politik, Faschismus, Krieg und Bundesrepublik (Cologne: Papy Rossa Verlag, 2001), 136–42Google Scholar; Hermann Josef Abs, ‘Aktive Kapitalpolitik’, Presentation to the Deutschen Instituts für Bankwissenschaft und Bankwesen, 25 Oct. 1940, doc. 124, Opitz, Europastrategien, 794; Herbst, totale Krieg, 143–4; Tooze, Wages, 390–1.

53 Briefwechsel zwischen Funk und Göring betr. Kontinental- und Grossraumwirtschaft, 6–17 Aug. 1940, document 114 in Opitz, Europastrategien, 755–8.

54 James, ‘Currency Plans’; Klemann and Kudryashov, Occupied Economies, 210.

55 ‘Probleme der äusseren Währungspolitik nach Beendigung des Krieges’, 20 June 1940, BAB, R2501, 7015; See also ‘Währungs- und Kreditpolitische Forderungen der Deutschen Reichsbank für einen Friedenvertrag mit Frankreich’, 13 July 1940, doc. 104 in Opitz, Europastrategien, 699–702.

56 German gold reserves in 1939 were just 150 million dollars. By contrast Britain and France's were 2 and 3 billion dollars, respectively. Romer, Christina, ‘What Ended the Great Depression?’, The Journal of Economic History, 52, 4 (1992), 757–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Einzig, Paul, World Finance, 1937–1938 (New York: Macmillan Company, 1938), 2568 Google Scholar; quotation from Shirras, Findlay, ‘The Position and Prospects of Gold’, The Economic Journal, 50, 198/199 (1940), 207–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar; DGFP, Vol. IX doc. 354; For public discussion of gold in Germany see Pritzkoleit, Kurt, ‘Das Gold im Kriege’ and other articles in Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift für Bank- und Börsenwesen, 40 (1940), 215–8Google Scholar.

57 Report on Puhl's Rundfunkvortrag in English, 3 May 1940, BAB, R2501, 6428.

58 DAZ-Gespräch mit Vizepräsident Emil Puhl, 5 Nov. 1940, BAB, R2501, 6428.

59 ‘Zur Frage der Neuordnung der deutschen Währung nach dem Kriege unter besonderer Berücksicktigung des Goldproblems’, 4 July 1940, BAB, R2501, 7015.

60 The Reichsbank pursued a publicity campaign throughout the war to propagate the view that a currency's value is based on confidence rather than gold. See the culture films produced with help of the Reichsbank: ‘Was ist Geld?’. ‘Herstellung eines Kulturfilms über das Geldwesen’, 18 Feb. 1942, BAB, R2501, 6428.

61 Knapp, Georg Friedrich, Staatliche Theorie des Geldes (Munich: Duncker & Humblot, 1921/1905)Google Scholar; Ellis, Howard, German Monetary Theory, 1905–1933 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1934)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

62 For instance, Burkheiser, Karl, ‘Konjunkturgestaltung, Weltwirtschaft und Währung’, and Otto Pfleiderer, ‘Die Feuerprobe der Währungssysteme’, in Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift für Bank- und Börsenwesen, 39 (1939), 356–61Google Scholar and 481–5; Janssen, Hauke. Nationalökonomie und Nationalsozialismus: die deutsche Volkswirtschaftslehre in den dreissiger Jahren (Marburg: Metropolis-Verlag, 1998), 301–18Google Scholar.

63 Weber, Adolf, ‘Ende der Goldwährung?Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift für Bank- und Börsenwesen, 40 (1940), 275–7Google Scholar.

64 Quotations from Hohlfeld, H. H., ‘Europa ohne Gold’, Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift für Bank- und Börsenwesen, 40 (1940), 277–80Google Scholar; see also Hunscha, Kurt, ‘Gold, Devise, oder Clearing? Eine Währungspolitische Bilanz’, Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift für Bank- und Börsenwesen, 40 (1940), 302–4Google Scholar. The main unresolved issue was whether gold should have a role in international payments between continental blocs, or if even this could be replaced with an ‘immaterial measure of value’. Lorenz, Charlotte, ‘Goldstandard und Rechnungswährung’, Die Deutsche Volkswirtschaft, 24 (1940), 742–4Google Scholar.

65 Puhl wanted to allow value of the reichsmark to fluctuate within a band of plus or minus five percent around gold for transactions between large economic zones. Quotation from ‘Zur Frage der Neuordnung’, 4 July 1940, BAB, R2501, RB 7015. See also, ‘Probleme der äusseren Währungspolitik’, 20 June 1940, Ibid.

66 Report of meeting between Puhl and Schlotterer, 2 July 1940, BAB, R2501, 7017.

67 Steinberg, Jonathan, The Deutsche Bank and its Gold Transactions During the Second World War (Munich: Beck, 1999)Google Scholar; Trepp, Gian, Bankgeschäft mit dem Feind: Die Bank für Internationalen Zahlungsausgleich im Zweiten Weltkrieg (Zurich: Rotpunktverlag, 1993)Google Scholar; Smith, Arthur, Hitler's Gold: The Story of Nazi War Loot (New York: Berg, 1989)Google Scholar.

68 Dickhaus, Monika, Die Bundesbank im westeuropäischen Wiederaufbau: Die internationale Währungspolitik der Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1948 bis 1958 (Munich: Oldenbourg Verlag, 1996), 61–3CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Johnson, Peter A., The Government of Money: Monetarism in Germany and the United States (Cornell: Cornell University Press, 1998), 32–8Google Scholar.

69 ‘Währungsfrage im Europäischen Grosswirtschaftsraum’, 6 July 1940, BAB, 2501, 6428; ‘Probleme der äusseren Währungspolitik nach Beendigung des Krieges’, 20 June 1940, BAB, R2501, 7015.

70 ‘Karl Albrecht: Gustav Schlotterer's Views on the “New Order in Europe”’, 19 July 1940, doc. 4 in Lipgens, Documents, 59–60.

71 ‘Wem obliegt die deutsche Währungspolitik?’, 27 Sept. 1940, BAB, 2501, 6428; ‘Zur Frage der Neuordnung’, 4 July 1940, BAB, R2501, 7015.

72 ‘Memorandum by the Director of the Economic Policy Department’, 31 July 1940, doc. 267 in DGFP, Vol. X, 381.

73 These points he did not publicly admit, but declared in internal discussions with Göring held several days before his public announcement. Geheimes Staatsarchiv Preussischer Kulturbesitz (GSPK), I. HA, Rep. 151 Finanzministerium, Geheimakten – I C Nr. 9401, Report on Meeting from 22 July 1940.

74 ‘Walther Funk: The Economic Organization of Europe’, 25 July 1940, doc. 6 in Lipgens, ed., Documents, 65–71.

75 As money doctor Edwin Kemmerer remarked in 1922, when he rejected calls for monetary union at the League of Nations: territorial currencies are ‘a natural reasonable function of a sovereign state’. Helleiner, National Money, 145.

76 See Cambridge economist and government consultant Guillebaud, C. W., Hitler's New Economic Order for Europe’, The Economic Journal, 50, 200 (1940), 449–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a critical perspective, Einzig, Paul, ‘Hitler's New Order in Theory and Practice’, The Economic Journal, 51, 201 (1941), 118 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

77 Keynes, John Maynard, ‘Letter to Harold Nicholson’ and idem, ‘Proposals to Counter the German “New Order”’, in Moggridge, Donald and Johnson, Elizabeth, eds., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXV (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980), 110 Google Scholar; Skidelsky, Keynes, 669–78.

78 Quotation from Milward, Reconstruction, 320–6, 333; Steil, Bretton Woods, 141–3.

79 Neebe, Reinhard, Weichenstellung für die Globalisierung: deutsche Weltmarktpolitik, Europa und Amerika in der Ära Ludwig Erhard (Cologne: Böhlau Verlag, 2004), 99103 Google Scholar.

80 Keynes, Collected Writings Vol. XXV, 3.

81 Keynes, Collected Writings Vol. XXV, 74–84; Killick, John, The United States and European Reconstruction 1945–1960 (Chicago: Fitzroy Dearborn Publishers, 1997), 2331 Google Scholar; Dyson, Elusive Union, 60–5.

82 Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital, 100–4; Eichengreen, Barry, The European Economy Since 1945: Coordinated Capitalism and Beyond (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007)Google Scholar, 77.

83 In the EPU, the Bank for International Settlements assumed the role of Keynes's International Clearing Union or Martini's Europa-Bank. Milward, Reconstruction, 320–6, 333; Diebold, William, Trade and Payments in Western Europe: A Study in Economic Cooperation, 1947–1951 (New York: Harper & Brothers, 1952), 87110 Google Scholar; Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital, 104–7.

84 Keynes, Collected Writings, Vol. XXV, 21.

85 Diebold, Trade and Payments 19–27; Killick, European Reconstruction, 32–41, 65–77; Clark, Peter, The Last Thousand Days of the British Empire: Churchill, Roosevelt, and the Birth of the Pax Americana (New York: Bloomsbury Press, 2008), 383–4Google Scholar, 399–404.

86 Abelshauser, Werner, ‘Der Kleine Marshallplan. Handelsintegration durch innereuropäische Wirtschaftshilfe 1948–1950’, in Berding, Helmut, ed., Wirtschaftliche und politische Integration in Europa im 19. und 20. Jahrhundert (Göttingen: Vandehoeck & Ruprecht, 1984), 212–24Google Scholar.

87 Gerold Ambrosius, ‘Europäische Integration und wirtschaftliche Entwicklung der Bundesrepublik Deutschland in den fünfziger Jahren’, in Berding, ed., Wirtschaftliche und politische Integration, 271–94.

88 Buggeln, ‘Europabank oder Freihandel’; Hermann Josef Abs, ‘Fragen der Wirtschaftlichen Zusammenarbeit in Europa’, 5 Dec. 1955, and ‘Fragen zur wirtschaftlichen Einigung Europas’, 14 Dec. 1956, in Abs, Hermann Josef, Zeitfragen der Geld- und Wirtschaftspolitik (Frankfurt a.M.: Fritz Knapp Verlag, 1959), 92101 Google Scholar, 101–11.

89 Neebe, Globalisierung, 270–6; Grünbacher, Armin, Reconstruction and Cold War in Germany: The Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau, 1948–1961 (Burlington, VT: Ashgate, 2004)Google Scholar, 85; Dickhaus, Bundesbank, 62–3, 83–5.

90 Grünbacher, Kreditanstalt, ch. 4 and 10; Harries, Heinrich, Financing the Future: KfW–the German Bank with a Public Mission (Frankfurt a.M.: Fritz Knapp, 1998), 165 Google Scholar.

91 Marshall Plan High Commissioner John McCloy said much the same thing to Adenauer, Abs, Hermann J., Entscheidungen, 1949–1955: Die Entstehung des Londoner Schuldenabkommens (Mainz-Munich: v. Hase & Koehler, 1991), 54–5Google Scholar.

92 American and British officials, including Keynes, hatched virtually the same idea for Britain, planning to write off British wartime clearing debts to its colonies like India and Egypt by 30–70 percent. Clark, Thousand Days, 383–4, 399–404; Tooze, Adam, ‘Reassessing the Moral Economy of Post-war Reconstruction: The Terms of the West German Settlement in 1952’, Past & Present, Supplement 6 (2011), 4770 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Timothy Guinnane, ‘Financial Vergangenheitsbewältigung: The 1953 London Debt Agreement’, Center Discussion Paper no. 880, Economic Growth Center, Yale University (2004); Albrecht Ritschl, ‘Transfers Small, Debt Relief Big: The Marshall Plan, Postwar Germany, and the Historical Roots of the Eurozone Debt Crisis’, paper presented at the Social Science and Policy Forum, University of Pennsylvania, 2 Nov. 2012.

93 Hans Fürstenberg of the Berliner Handels-Gesellschaft, quoted in Buggeln, ‘Europa Bank oder Freihandel’, 140; Mierzejewski, Alfred C., Ludwig Erhard: A Biography (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2004)Google Scholar, 23.

94 ‘We could not get what we all wanted’, Keynes reflected, ‘except by dethroning gold and creating a system of international credits so that trade was not limited by the amount of gold available’. Keynes, Collected Writings XXV, 141; see also Harris, S. E., ‘American Gold Policy and Allied War Economics’, Economic Journal, 50, 198/199 (1940), 224–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shirras, ‘Prospects of Gold’.

95 Triffin, Robert, Europe and the Money Muddle: From Bilateralism to Near-Convertibility, 1947–1956 (London: Oxford University Press, 1957), 222 Google Scholar, 88–93; Boyce, Interwar Crisis, 210–2.

96 In 1953 German officials criticised the Beyen Plan for a customs union because it ignored what they saw as the ‘central question’, namely, the issue of currency stability. Neebe, Globalisierung, 267–8; In 1957 the Treaty of Rome declared, in paragraphs 103–7, that ‘each member shall treat its policy with regard to rates of exchange as a matter of common concern’.

97 Keynes went the furthest in calling for a purely fiat international money – Bancor – that would be completely independent of gold. Steil, Bretton Woods, 129–30, 140–2.

98 Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital, 91–133; Panitch, Leo and Gidin, Sam, The Making of Global Capitalism: The Political Economy of American Empire (New York: Verso Books, 2012), 6789 Google Scholar; Block, Fred, The Origins of International Economic Disorder: A Study of United States International Monetary Policy from World War II to the Present (Berkeley: UC Press, 1977)Google Scholar.

99 Gilpin, Robert, Global Political Economy: Understanding the International Economic Order (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001), 234–60Google Scholar.

100 Steil, Bretton Woods, 153; Johnson, Money, 38–9.

101 Ruggie, ‘Embedded Liberalism’.

102 Johnson, Money, 32–8.

103 A German textile producer on German authority in Europe. 3 Report from Saxony, 16 Aug. 1940, BAB, R 9, 122/3.