Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vsgnj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-21T16:14:05.089Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rural Marketing in China: Repression and Revival

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 February 2009

Extract

Rural markets and peasant marketing did not fare well during the Maoist era, which extended from well before the consolidation of communist power in China to the triumphal return of Deng Xiaoping as the central political figure in 1977. Maoist radicals, who in broad perspective may be said to have held the political initiative throughout the era, can be fairly characterized as having an anti-market mentality. While this set of attitudes derives in part from Marxism, it is also rooted in the ideological preconceptions of late-imperial Confucian bureaucrats. The Maoist elite in the People's Republic and the traditional bureaucratic elite of the late empire were equally unhappy with market exchange, and both showed a preference for redistribution.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The China Quarterly 1985

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Samuelson, Paul A., Economics: An Introductory Analysis (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1964), 6th ed., p. 621.Google Scholar

2. This argument is spelled out in Skinner, G. W., “Urban development in imperial China,” in Skinner, G. W. (ed.), The City in Late Imperial China (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1977), pp. 1726.Google Scholar

3. For an abstract diachronic treatment contrasting the goals and strategies of local systems with those of the state apparatus, see Skinner, G. W., “Chinese peasants and the closed community: An open and shut case,” Comparative Studies in Society and History, Vol. 13, No. 3 (07 1971), pp. 270–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4. The overall scheme and dating of the first seven cycles are set out in Skinner, G. W. and Winckler, Edwin A., “Compliance succession in rural Communist China: A cyclical theory,” in Etzioni, Amitai (ed.), A Sociological Reader on Complex Organization (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1969), 2nd ed., pp. 410–38.Google Scholar The analysis of subsequent cycles, completed in 1977, has not yet been published.

5. In the dialectical model, critical policy decisions occur in the middle of each segment, although it is only in the subsequent segment that implementation becomes apparent. Since the decision to Radicalize, which initiates each cycle, comes in the middle of Normalcy, that segment is numbered 1 in the sequence of six segments. But it should be remembered that Normalcy (and the liberal phase which encompasses it along with Demobilization) “bridges” two successive cycles, ending the one and beginning the other.

6. Strangely enough, however, a recent and otherwise balanced treatment of the extent and causes of the Great Leap subsistence crisis fails even to mention the closure of rural markets. See Ashton, Basil, Hill, Kenneth, Piazza, Alan and Zeitz, Robin, “Famine in China, 1958–61,” Population and Development Review, Vol. 10, No. 4 (12 1984), pp. 613–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7. Donnithorne, Audrey, China's Economic System (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1967), pp. 283–85.Google Scholar

8. Ibid. p. 285. See also Donnithorne, Audrey, “The organization of rural trade in China since 1958,” The China Quarterly (C.Q.), No. 8 (12 1961), pp. 7791.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9. For an analysis of the vicissitudes of the private plot that is admirably attuned to policy fluctuation, see Walker, Kenneth R., Planning in Chinese Agriculture: Socialization and the Private Sector, 1956–1962 (London: Frank Cass, 1965), pp. 2433, 8990.Google Scholar

10. Cf. Walker, Kenneth R., “Chinese agriculture during the period of the readjustment. 1978–83,” C.Q., No. 100 (12 1984), p. 788.Google Scholar

11. Cf. Bucknall, Kevin, “Capitalism and Chinese agriculture, 1960–66,” Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, No. 1 (1979), pp. 6990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12. The importance of taxation at rural markets for meeting the costs of post-Leap rehabilitation was also explicitly recognized during the liberal phase of 1961–62. Cf. Donnithorne, , China's Economic System, p. 377.Google Scholar

13. Chan, Anita and Unger, Jonathan, “Grey and black: The hidden economy of rural China,” Pacific Affairs, Vol. 55, No. 2 (Fall 1982), p. 459CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Weiss, Udo, “China's rural marketing structure,” World Development, Vol. 6 (1978), p. 658CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bucknall, , “Capitalism and Chinese agriculture,” p. 71Google Scholar; Deshan, Sun, “Active village markets and flourishing rural economies,” Zhongguo caimao bao (Chinese Financial and Trade News), 22 09 1981, p. 3Google Scholar; and Jingpei, He, “Vigorously promote the healthy development of trade in urban and rural markets,” Jingji quanti (Economic Management), No. 5 (1965), pp. 1214.Google Scholar

14. Skinner, G. W., “Marketing and social structure in rural China, Part III,” Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 24, No. 3 (05 1965), pp. 340–42Google Scholar; Donnithorne, , China's Economic System, pp. 307–09.Google Scholar

15. Skinner, G. W., “Marketing and social structure in rural China, Part I,” Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 24, No. 1 (11 1964), p. 31CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Skinner, G. W., “Cities and the hierarchy of local systems,”Google Scholar in Skinner, (ed.), The City in Late Imperial China, pp. 340–42.Google Scholar

16. Skinner, , “Marketing, Part I,” pp. 2124.Google Scholar

17. Shiba, Yoshinobu, “Ningpo and its hinterland,”Google Scholar in Skinner, (ed.). The City in Late Imperial China, pp. 428–30.Google Scholar

18. See, e.g., Renmin ribao (People's Daily), 19 09 1979Google Scholar; Di, Ni and Xi, You, “Guanyu Ciyutuo di jishi di xingwang gei chengshi fuzhuang ye di qishi” (“Regarding the impetus given to Ciyutuo's textile industry by the prosperity of the town's market”), Jingji quanli (Economic Management), No. 3 (1984), pp. 4647Google Scholar; Chan, and Unger, , “Grey and black: The hidden economy of rural China,” p. 457.Google Scholar

19. Ningqi, Tao (comp.), Changli xianzhi (Changli County Gazetteer), 1933 (Taibei: Chengwen chubanshe, 1968 [reissue]).Google Scholar

20. Renmin ribao, 19 09 1979. p. 3.Google Scholar

21. The figure for 1965 is cited in Jingpei, He, “Vigorously promote the healthy development of trade”Google Scholar and in various yearbooks. For the source of the 1978 datum, see Table 1. For two other estimates of the number of rural markets China-wide, both problematic, see Datong, Guan, “Guanyu nongcun jishi maoyi” (“On trade in rural markets”), Hongqi (Red Flag), No. 18 (1961), pp. 1622Google Scholar; and Qing, Chu, Zhongjian, Zhu and Zhiming, Wang, Woguo nongcun shichang di gaizu (The Reorganization of Rural Markets in China) (Beijing: Caizheng jingji chubanshe, 1957).Google Scholar Guan gives 40,000 without specifying source or date; I surmise that it is a round figure for the total prior to the Great Leap. Chu et al. give a total of 36,710, presumably for 1956; that the figure is an undercount is clear from the description of procedures followed in collecting and aggregating the data.

22. For a reflective “revisit” of my 1964–65 analysis, see “Rural marketing in China: Revival and reappraisal,” in Plattner, Stuart (ed.), Markets and Marketing (Lanham, Maryland: University Press of America, 1985)Google Scholar, which also includes portions of the present article.

23. Skinner, , “Marketing, Part III.”Google Scholar

24. These estimates of the rural population are derived from the annual series for total and urban populations in Banister, Judith, “An analysis of recent data on the population of China,” Population and Development Review, Vol. 10 (1984), pp. 241–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

25. The mini-radicalizations began, respectively, in early 1979, spring 1981 and summer 1983. Only the second had discernable impact on rural economic policy. These radic-alizations appear to differ from their counterparts during the Maoist era not only in severity but also in their fundamental dynamic. But see Schram, Stuart, “Economics in command? Ideology and policy since the Third Plenum, 1978–84,” C.Q., No. 99 (09 1984), pp. 417–61.Google Scholar

26. See Travers, Lee, “Post-1978 rural economic policy and peasant income in China,” C.Q., No. 98 (06 1984), pp. 241–59Google Scholar; and Walker, , “Chinese agriculture during the period of readjustment, 1978–83.”Google Scholar

27. As Kenneth Walker points out (ibid. p. 786), contracting down to the household was hardly a post-Mao innovation. There had been recourse to it during the liberal phases bridging Cycles 4 and 5, Cycles 6 and 7, and Cycles 7 and 8.

28. Renmin ribao, 31 01 1978.Google Scholar

29. Ibid. 23 December 1978.

30. Ibid. 19 February 1979.

31. Jingpei, He, “Vigorously promote the healthy development of trade.”Google Scholar

32. Trans, in Foreign Broadcast Information Service Daily Report, 18 04 1983, pp. K1K13.Google Scholar

33. Although the Central Committee's “Document No. 1 (1984)” was issued on 1 January, its publication was delayed until 11 June (Xinhua News Agency). For the official text, see Renmin ribao, 12 06 1984Google Scholar; for a full translation, see C.Q., No. 101 (03 1985).Google Scholar

34. Skinner, G. W., “Marketing and social structure in rural China, Part II,” Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 24, No. 2 (02 1965), p. 209.Google Scholar

35. I am grateful to Carol Benedict for calling these cases to my attention.

36. Weihui, Xu (comp.), Liaozhong xianzhi (Liaozhong County Gazetteer), 1930 (Taibei: Chengwen chubanshe, 1974 [reissue]).Google Scholar

37. Di, Ni and Xi, You, “Guanyu Ciyutuo di jishi.”Google Scholar

38. Renmin ribao, 19 09 1978, p. 3Google Scholar; Renmin ribao, 14 10 1981, p. 2.Google Scholar

39. Skinner, , “Marketing, Part II,” pp. 195211.Google Scholar

40. Chengrui, Li, “Cong renkou pucha kan Zhongguo renkou di xianzhuang” (“China's population as revealed in the population census communiqué”), Jingji yanjiu (Economic Research), No. 12 (1982), pp. 3132.Google Scholar

41. Zhongguo jingji nianjian 1983 (Almanac of the Chinese Economy, 1983), Section IV, p. 129.Google Scholar

42. Beijing, 9 January 1984. Trans, in Joint Publications Research Service (JPRS): CEA-84–007, 30 01 1984.Google Scholar

43. News analysis by Ye, Ma, Ganwu, Yuan and Bingkun, Wei in Tianjin ribao (Tianjin Daily) 27 07 1982, p. 2.Google Scholar

44. Ibid.

45. Xue Muqiao, Ma Hong and Liu Mingfu. Their analysis was summarized by Zhongguo xinwenshe, Beijing, 30 January 1982.

46. Chonghai, Li, “Take off on two wings and build Wuhan into an economic center,” Wuhan Daxue xuepao (Wuhan University Journal), No. 6 (28 11 1983), pp. 7178.Google Scholar Trans, in JPRS: CEA-84–052, pp. 5–21.

47. Interesting reports of early resistance appeared in Guangming ribao, 18 08 1978Google Scholar, and in Renmin ribao, 28 03 1979.Google Scholar

48. Xi'an Mandarin broadcast, 15 April 1984. Trans, in JPRS: CAG-84–013, 4 May 1984.

49. Provincial rural populations were extrapolated from the 10 per cent sample of 1982 census data. Provincial totals of rural markets in 1982 were pieced together from Zhongguo jingji nianjian (Almanac of the Chinese Economy) 1981, 1982, 1983Google Scholar, and from JPRS China: Economic Reports during 1983.Google Scholar

50. Deshan, Sun, “Active village markets.”Google Scholar

51. Nanfang rihao (Nanfang Daily), 18 12 1982.Google Scholar

52. Wen, Han, “Foster the establishment of markets, promote circulation of commodities,” Shaanxi ribao (Shaanxi Daily), 23 04 1984.Google Scholar Trans, in JPRS: CEA-84–053, pp. 110–111.

53. Cf. Walker, , “Chinese agriculture,” p. 801.Google Scholar