Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-04T20:16:09.525Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Policy Oscillations in the People's Republic of China: A Critique

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 February 2009

Extract

That Chinese policy since 1949 has been characterized by a pattern of left-right oscillations is one of the most widespread, but least examined, assumptions among analysts of Chinese politics. In the popular press, we often read of a “return to a moderate phase” or a “resurgence of radicalism,” while in academic writing, we frequently find contemporary Chinese history set in periods according to the alternate ascendancy of “bureaucratic” or “mobilizational” “models” or of “realist” and “visionary” groups of leaders. Of course, to some extent the policy oscillations model is only a kind of shorthand, convenient for summarizing the content of policy and its changes. We all understand that there have been secular changes in China both in what has been accomplished and in the terms of policy debate. Thus, it has become increasingly common to describe the pattern of policy change in China in terms of a combination of cyclical and secular patterns, to refer to policy oscillations in passing while presenting a chronology which actually indicates secular change, to offer the oscillations model explicitly as just a convenient simplification; or to ignore oscillations entirely in discussing the development of policy.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The China Quarterly 1976

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

* I gratefully acknowledge the comments on earlier drafts of this paper of Thomas P. Bernstein, Steven I. Levine, Sharon G. Nathan, Michel C. Oksenberg, Thomas G. Rawski, Thomas W. Robinson, Lynn T. White, III, and Roxane Witke.

1. Townsend, James R., Politics in China (Boston: Little, Brown and Co., 1974), pp. 141–60; Byung-joon Ahn, “The Cultural Revolution and China's search for political order,” The China Quarterly 58 (April/June, 1974), pp. 249–285.Google Scholar

2. Pye, Lucian W., China: An Introduction (Boston: Little, Brown and Co., 1972), pp. 184208.Google Scholar

3. Etō, Shinkichi, “Communist China: moderation and radicalism in the Chinese Revolution,” in Crowley, James B. (ed.), Modern East Asia: Essays in Interpretation (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1970), pp. 341 and ff.Google Scholar

4. Oscillations writers agree most readily in their interpretations of policy cycles of 1955–62. For the early 1950s. some writers see several cycles while others perceive a pre-cyclical mixture of policies. For the period since 1962, some scholars see two major cycles while others see a greater number of more subtle cycles, and still others consider cyclical patterns to have been superseded by secular patterns in either 1962 or 1965. Since this critique is directed at the idea of cycles as such, I will not consider further the distinctions among various periods.

5. For arguments linking foreign policy to domestic policy, see Zagoria, Donald, “The strategic debate in Peking,” in Tsou, Tang (ed.). China in Crisis, Vol. II, China's Policies in Asia and America's Alternatives (Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 1968), pp. 237–39;Google ScholarWhitson, William W. with Chen-hsia Huang, The Chinese High Command: A History of Communist Military Politics, 1927–1971 (New York: Praeger, 1973), pp. 518–47;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Hinton, Harold C., “Evolution of foreign policy” in Wu, Yuan-li (ed.). China: A Handbook (New York: Praeger, 1973), p. 297. The oscillations element is present in these analyses to varying degrees and with differing chronologies.Google Scholar

6. Eckstein, Alexander, “Economic fluctuations in Communist China's domestic development,” in Ho, Ping-ti and Tsou, Tang (eds.), China in Crisis. Volume I. China's Heritage and the Communist Political System (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1968), Bk. 2, p. 693.Google Scholar This essay is also available in Eckstein's, China's Economic Development: The Interplay of Scarcity and Ideology (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 1975).Google Scholar

7. Ibid. p. 709.

8. Skinner, G. William and Winckler, Edwin A.. “Compliance succession in rural Communist China: A cyclical theory;.” in Etzioni, Amitai (ed.). A Sociological Reader in Complex Organizations (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1969), 2nd edit., pp. 410, 424–26.Google Scholar

9. Eckstein, “Fluctuations,” pp. 721–22; Skinner and Winckler. “Compliance.” pp. 432–38.

10. Lowenthal, Richard, “Development vs. utopia in communist policy,” in Johnson, Chalmers (ed.), Change in Communist Systems (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1970), p. 53. The argument is specifically applied to China on pp. 60–66.Google Scholar

11. Schurmann, Franz, Ideology and Organization in Communist China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1966), pp. 101, 104.Google Scholar

12. Ibid. p. 55.

13. Ibid. p. 493.

14. Schram, Stuart, Mao Tse-tung (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1966), p. 277.Google Scholar

15. Chang, Parris H., Power and Policy in China (University Park, Pa.: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 1975), p. 176.Google Scholar

16. Michel Oksenberg and Steven Goldstein, “The Chinese political spectrum,” Problems of Communism (March–April 1974), pp. 1–13.

17. Nathan, Andrew J., “A factionalism model for CCP politics,” The China Quarterly, No. 53 (1973), p. 60. I do not think that the factionalism model is invalidated for China if one rejects the notion of policy oscillations, but this is a question for consideration in some other context.Google Scholar

18. As noted earlier, many oscillations writers themselves point this out with respect to particular periods.

19. “On contradiction,” Selected Works of Mao Tse-tung (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1965), Vol. I, p. 313.Google Scholar In another context Mao is reported as observing approvingly that “the principle of Kings Wen and Wu was to alternate tension and relaxation”; see Rice, Edward E., Mao's Way (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1972), p. 478.Google Scholar

20. Yu, Hung. “History develops in spirals,” Peking Review. No. 43 (25 October 1974), pp. 1011, transl. from Hung-ch'i (Red Flag). No. 10 (1974).Google Scholar

21. Ibid. pp. 11–12.

22. Rawski, Thomas G., “Recent trends in the Chinese economy,” The China Quarterly, No. 53 (1973), pp. 133.Google Scholar