Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-18T20:50:57.842Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economic growth and the politics of entitlement

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 January 2012

Robin Osborne*
Affiliation:
King's College, Cambridge

Extract

Discussions of economic growth in antiquity have been primarily concerned with whether or not it occurred. Can we, from the array of unsystematic and often random information we have about individual and community wealth, and in the face of our very considerable ignorance about even such basic matters as population levels, find ways of measuring either aggregate or per capita growth? The second focus of scholarly energy has been on how growth might have been achieved, on levels of productivity and what limited them, on how institutions might have impeded or facilitated growth, and on the degree to which barriers may have been deliberately removed over time and growth consciously encouraged. This paper is not directly interested in either of those sets of questions. It is interested in who wanted growth in the first place.

The default assumption in discussions of growth often seems to be, at least implicitly, that it is brought about either by need or by greed. The desire of individuals to satisfy their needs more fully leads to an increase in, at the very least, aggregate productivity, and might be expected inevitably to drive growth from the supply side. The desire of individuals to increase their consumption drives growth from the demand side. The default assumptions tend to stop there, as if what counts as need is absolute, a matter of a certain minimum number of calories or ‘wheat equivalent’ a day, and as if greed is simply part of human nature.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s). Published online by Cambridge University Press 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Bagnall, R. S. and Derow, P. (2004) The Hellenistic period: historical sources in translation, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balot, R. K. (2001) Greed and injustice in classical Athens, Princeton.Google Scholar
Brunt, P. A. (1966) ‘The Roman mob’, Past & Present 35, 327 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
reprinted in Finley, M. I. (ed.) (1974) Studies in ancient society, London, 74102.Google Scholar
Brunt, P. A. (1971) Social conflicts in the Roman Republic, London.Google Scholar
Domingo, Gygax M. (2006) ‘Les origines de l'évergétisme. Échanges et identités sociales dans la cité grecque’, Métis: anthropologie des mondes grecs anciens 4, 269–95.Google Scholar
Finley, M. I. (1953) ‘Land, debt and the man of property in Classical Athens’, Political Science Quarterly 68, 249–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
reprinted in Finley, M. I. (1981) Economy and society in ancient Greece, London, 6276.Google Scholar
Finley, M. I. (1970) Early Greece: the bronze and archaic ages, London.Google Scholar
Foxhall, L. (1997) ‘A view from the top: evaluating the Solonian property classes’ in Mitchell, L. G. and Rhodes, P. J. (eds.) The development of the polis in archaic Greece, London, 113–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallant, T. W. (1991) Risk and survival in ancient Greece, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Garnsey, P. (1970) Social status and legal privilege in the Roman Empire, Oxford.Google Scholar
Garnsey, P. (1975) ‘Descendants of freedmen in local politics: some criteria’ in Levick, B. M. (ed.) The ancient historian and his materials: essays in honour of C. E. Stevens, Famborough, 167–80.Google Scholar
Garnsey, P. (1988) Famine and food supply in the Graeco-Roman world, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garnsey, P. (1998) Cities, peasants and food in classical antiquity, edited by Scheidel, W., Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garnsey, P. (forthcoming a) ‘Roman patronage’ in McGill, S., Sogno, C., and Watts, E. (eds.), From the tetrarchs to the Theodosians: later Roman history and culture, 284–450 AD, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Garnsey, P. (forthcoming b) ‘Cicero on property and justice’ in Carlsen, J. and Cascio, E. Lo (eds.), Agricoltura e scambi nell'Italia tardo-repubblicana, Bari.Google Scholar
Giovannini, A. (1990) ‘Le Parthénon, le trésor d'Athéna, etle tribut des alliées’, Historia 39, 129–48.Google Scholar
Goodman, M. (1997) The Roman world 44 BC–AD 180, London.Google Scholar
Hall, J. M. (2006) A history of the archaic Greek world ca. 1200–479 B.C.E., Oxford.Google Scholar
Hammer, D. (2004) ‘Ideology, the symposium and archaic polities’, AJP 125, 479512.Google Scholar
Harvey, F. D. (1965) ‘Two kinds of equality’, Classica et Mediaevalia 26, 101–46 (with corrigenda in 27 (1966) 96–100).Google Scholar
Hopkins, K. (1978) ‘Economic growth and towns in Classical Antiquity’ in Abrams, P. and Wrigley, E. A. (eds.) Towns in societies: essays in economic history and historical sociology, Cambridge, 3577.Google Scholar
Hopkins, K. (1980) ‘Taxes and trade in the Roman Empire, 200 BC–AD 400’, JRS 70, 101125; revised version reprinted in Scheidel and von Reden (2003).Google Scholar
Hopkins, K. (1983) Death and renewal, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hornblower, S. (1991) A commentary on Thucydides. Vol. 1, books I–III, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, A. H. M. (1940) The Greek city from Alexander to Justinian, Oxford.Google Scholar
Jones, C. P. (1999) Kinship diplomacy in the ancient world, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Jongman, W. (2006) ‘The rise and fall of the Roman economy: population, rents and entitlement’ in Bang, P., Ikeguchi, M., and Ziche, H. (eds.) Ancient economies and modern methodologies: archaeology, comparative history, models and institutions, Bari, 237–54.Google Scholar
Kallet-Marx, L. (1989) ‘Did tribute fund the Parthenon?’, Classical Antiquity 8, 252–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kistler, E. (2004) ‘“Kämpf der Mentalitäten”: Ian Morris’ “Elitist-” versus “Middling-Ideology”’ in Rollinger, R. and Ulf, C. (eds.) Griechische archaik: interne Enrwicklungen -externe Impulse, Berlin, 145–76.Google Scholar
Koortbojian, M. (2006) ‘The freedman's voice: the funerary monument of Aurelius Hermia and Aurelia Philematio’ in D'Ambra, E. and Métraux, G. (eds.) The art of citizens, soldiers and freedmen in the Roman world, Oxford, 91–9.Google Scholar
Kurke, L. (1992) ‘The politics of habrosune in archaic Greece’, Classical Antiquity 11, 90121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurke, L. (1999) Coins, bodies, games, and gold, Princeton.Google Scholar
Lintott, A. W. (1999) The constitution ojthe Roman Republic, Oxford.Google Scholar
Millett, P. C. (2001) ‘The problem of ancient economic growth,’ in Mattingly, D. J. and Salmon, J. (eds.) Economies beyond agriculture in the classical world, London, 1748.Google Scholar
Morris, I. M. (1996) ‘The strong principle of equality and the archaic origins of Greek Democracy’ in Ober, J. and Hedrick, C. (eds.) Dêmokratia: a conversation on democracies, ancient and modern, Princeton, 1948.Google Scholar
Morris, I. M. (1998) ‘Beyond democracy and empire: Athenian art in context’ in Boedeker, D. and Raaflaub, K. A. (eds.) Democracy, empire, and the arts in fifth-century Athens, Cambridge, Mass., 5986.Google Scholar
Morris, I. M. (2000) Archaeology as culture history, Blackwell.Google Scholar
Morris, I. M. (2004) ‘Economic growth in ancient Greece’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160, 709–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mouritsen, H. (1998) Italian unification: a study of ancient and modern historiography, London.Google Scholar
Murray, O. (1980) Early Greece (2nd edition 1993), London.Google Scholar
Nozick, R. (1974) Anarchy, state and Utopia, New York.Google Scholar
Ober, J. (1989) Mass and elite in classical Athens: rhetoric, ideology and the power of the people, Princeton.Google Scholar
Osborne, R. (1991) ‘Pride and prejudice, sense and subsistence: exchange and society in the Greek City’ in Rich, J. and Wallace-Hadrill, A. (eds.) City and country in the ancient world, London, 119–46; reprinted in Osborne (2010).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, R. (1995) ‘The economics and politics of slavery at Athens’ in Powell, A. (ed.) The Greek world, London, 2743; reprinted in Osborne (2010).Google Scholar
Osborne, R. (1996/2009) Greece in the making 1200–479 B.C., London.Google Scholar
Osborne, R. (1997) ‘Law, the democratic citizen, and the representation of women’, Past & Present 155, 333;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
reprinted in Osborne, R. (ed.) (2004) Studies in ancient Greek and Roman society, Cambridge, 3860, and in Osborne (2010).Google Scholar
Osborne, R. (2010) Athens and Athenian democracy, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Patterson, C. (1981) Pericles' citizenship law of 451–50 B.C., New York.Google Scholar
Patterson, J. R. (2006) Landscapes and cities: rural settlement and civic transformation in early imperial Italy, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patterson, O. (1991) Freedom in the making of western culture, New York.Google Scholar
Rhodes, P. J. (1981) A commentary on the Aristotelian Athenaion Politeia, Oxford.Google Scholar
Rhodes, P. J. (1997) ‘Introduction’ in Mitchell, L. G. and Rhodes, P. J. (eds.) The development of the polis in archaic Greece , London, 18.Google Scholar
Rhodes, P. J. and Osborne, R. (2003) Greek historical inscriptions 404–323 B.C., Oxford.Google Scholar
Ste Croix, G. E. M. de (2004) Athenian democratic origins and other essays, edited by Harvey, D. and Parker, R., Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salmeri, G. (2000) ‘Dio, Rome, and the civic life of Asia Minor’, in Swain, S. (ed.) Dio Chrysostom: politics, letters and philosophy, Oxford, 5392.Google Scholar
Scheidel, W. and von Reden, S. (2002) The ancient economy: recent approaches, London.Google Scholar
Schofield, M. (1999) Saving the city: philosopher-kings and other classical paradigms, London.Google Scholar
Seaford, R. A. S. (2002) ‘Reading money: Leslie Kurke on the politics of meaning in archaic Greece’, Arion 3rd series 9.3, 4565.Google Scholar
Seaford, R. A. S. (2004) Money and the early Greek mind, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1981) Poverty and famines. An essay on entitlement and deprivation, Oxford.Google Scholar
Snodgrass, A. M. (1980) Archaic Greece. The age of experiment, London.Google Scholar
Stanier, R. (1953) ‘The cost of the Parthenon’, JHS 73, 6876.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starr, C. G. (1970) Athenian coinage 480–449 B.C., Oxford.Google Scholar
Temin, P. (2001) ‘A market economy in the early Roman Empire’, JRS 91, 169–81.Google Scholar
Temin, P. (2004) ‘The labor supply of the early Roman Empire’, Journal of Interdisciplinary History 34, 513–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Temin, P. (2006) ‘Estimating Roman GDP’ in Cascio, E. Lo (ed.), Innovazione tecnica e progresso economico nel mondo romano, Rome, 3154.Google Scholar
Thomson, G. (1941) Aeschylus and Athens, London.Google Scholar
Ure, P. N. (1922) The origin of tyranny, Cambridge,Google Scholar
van Wees, H. (2000) ‘Megara's majiosi: timocracy and violence in Theognis’ in Brock, R. and Hodkinson, S. (eds.) Alternatives to Athens: varieties of political organization and community in ancient Greece, Oxford.Google Scholar
van Wees, H. (2006) ‘Mass and elite in Solon's Athens: the property classes revisited’ in Blok, J. H. and Lardinois, A. (eds.) Solon of Athens: new historical and philological approaches, Leiden, 351–89.Google Scholar
van Wees, H. (2009) ‘The economy’ in Raaflaub, K. and Wees, H. van (eds.) A companion to archaic Greece, Oxford, 444–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veyne, P. (1976/1990) Le Pain et le cirque: sociologie historique d'un pluralisme politique, Paris; Eng. trans. Bread and circuses: historical sociology and political pluralism, Harmondsworth.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voutsaki, S. and Killen, J. T. (eds.) (2001) Economy and politics in the Mycenaean palace states. Cambridge Philological Society supplementary volume 27, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Wilson, A. (2002) ‘Machines, power, and the ancient economy’, JRS 92, 132.Google Scholar
Wilson, A. (2006) ‘The economic impact of technological advances in the Roman construction industry’ in Cascio, E. Lo (ed.), Innovazione tecnica e progresso economico nel mondo romano, Rome, 225–36.Google Scholar
Wiseman, T. P. (1971) New men in the Roman senate, Oxford.Google Scholar
Zuiderhoek, A. (2005) ‘The icing on the cake: benefactors, economics, and public building in Roman Asia Minor’ in Mitchell, S. and Katsari, C. (eds.) Patterns in the economy of Roman Asia Minor, Swansea, 167–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zuiderhoek, A. (2009) The politics of munificence in the Roman empire: citizens, elites and benefactors in Asia Minor, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar