Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T15:38:21.675Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Trade Openness and Preferences for Redistribution: A Cross-National Assessment of the Compensation Hypothesis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2017

Laia Balcells Ventura*
Affiliation:
Yale University

Abstract

Compensation hypothesis, which has established a link between trade openness of countries and levels of government spending, has been widely accepted in the literature on trade policy and international globalization. However, the nature of the distribution effects produced by trade is likely to determine the existence of more or less redistribution demands from the median voter, and therefore government growth. In this paper I hypothesize that the effects of trade openness on redistribution demands are not homogeneous between countries, and I argue that they depend both on the type-of-factor endowment of the economy and the size of the sectors more likely to be affected by trade. I test this hypothesis with ISSP data for 23 countries, both with a country level and an individual level analysis. The results show that redistribution demands issued from trade openness of the median voter of a country are largely conditional on GDP per capita and size of potential loser sectors such as manufacturing: while trade has a negative effect on pro-redistribution preferences in “poor” and/or in “low manufacturing” countries; it positively affects pro-redistribution preferences in “rich” and/or in “high manufacturing” countries. Additionally, I empirically observe that the size of the loser sector plays a more important mediating role than the type-of-factor endowment of the economy.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © V.K. Aggarwal 2006 and published under exclusive license to Cambridge University Press 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Toril, Aalberg. “Founding the Welfare State: Comparative Public Opinion on Taxes and Redistribution of Income”. Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper Series 180, April 1998.Google Scholar
Adserà, Alicia and Boix, Carles. “Trade, Democracy, and the Size of the Public Sector: The Political Underpinnings of Openness.” International Organization 56, no. 2 (Spring 2002): 229–62.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and La Ferrara, Eliana. “Preferences for Redistribution in the Land of Opportunities”, March 2001. Available from: http://post.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/alesina/papers/landopp1.pdf Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Angeletos, George-Marios. “Fairness and Redistribution”, December 2003. Available from:Google Scholar
Alt, James E. and Chrystal, Alec. Political Economics. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Boix, Carles. “Between Redistribution and Trade: The Political Economy of Protectionism and Compensation”. In Pranab Bardhan, Samuel Bowles and Michael Wallerstein, eds. Globalization and Egalitarian Redistribution. Princeton University and Russell Sage Foundation, 2006.Google Scholar
Boix, Carles. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pereira, Bresser, Carlos, Luiz; María Maravall, José y Przeworski, Adam. Las Reformas Económicas en las Nuevas Democracias. Un Enfoque Socialdemócrata. Madrid: Alianza Editorial, 1995.Google Scholar
Cameron, David. “The expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis”, American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 12431261.Google Scholar
Corneo, G. and Gruner, H.P.Individual Preferences for Political Redistribution.” Journal of Public Economics 83 (2002): 83107.Google Scholar
Dutt, Pushan and Mitra, Devashish. “Endogenous Trade Policy through Majority Voting: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of International Economics 58 (2002): 107–33.Google Scholar
Fernández-Albertos, José. Making globalization endogenous. The domestic determinants of capital mobility. Madrid: CEACS Estudio/Working Paper 2002/172, October 2000.Google Scholar
Fernández-Albertos, José. “Trade Liberalization, Exchange Rate Regimes and Fiscal Policies in Latin America. A Political Account”, Paper presented at the ECPR Joint Sessions, Torino, 2002.Google Scholar
Frieden, Jeffrey A.Invested Interests: the Politics of National Economic Policies in A World of Global Finance”, International Organization 45 no. 4 (1991): 425451.Google Scholar
Garret, Geoffrey. Globalization and Government Spending Around the World. Madrid: CEACS Estudio/Working Paper 2000/155, October 2000.Google Scholar
Gourevitch, Peter. “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics.” International Organization 32, no. 4 (Autumn 1978): 881912.Google Scholar
Katzenstein, Peter J. Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca & London: Cornell University Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Long, Scott J. Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables. Oaks, California: Sage publications, Advanced Quantitative Techniques in the Social Sciences Series, 1997.Google Scholar
Long, Scott J. and Freese, Jeremy. Regression Models for Categorical Dependent Variables Using Stata. College Station, Texas: Stata Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Low, Patrick; Olarreaga, Marcelo y Suárez, Javier. Does Globalization Cause a Higher Concentration of International Trade and Investment Flows? World Trade Organization, Staff Working Paper ERAD-98-08, August 1998.Google Scholar
Mayda, Anna Maria and Rodrik, Daniel. “Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist Than Others?”, January 2002. Department of Economics and JFK School of Government.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H. and Richard, Scott F.A Rational Choice Theory of the Size of Government”. The Journal of Political Economy 89, no. 5 (Oct. 1981): 914927.Google Scholar
Mulé, Rosa. The Politics of Income Redistribution. Factional Strife and Vote Mobilization under Tatcher. Florence: EUI Working Papers, EUF 99/10, 1999.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. “Symposium on Globalization in Perspective: An IntroductionThe Journal of Economic Perspectives 12, no. 4 (Autumn 1998a): 38.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?The Journal of Political Economy 106, no. 5 (October 1998b): 9971032.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington DC: Institute for International Economics, 1997.Google Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald. Commerce and Coalitions. How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments. New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald. “Political Cleavages and Changing Exposure to Trade.” The American Political Science Review 81, no. 4 (December 1987): 1121–37.Google Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth F. and Slaughter, Matthew J.What Determines Individual Trade-Policy Preferences?Journal of International Economics 54 (2001): 267–92.Google Scholar