Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T19:26:14.512Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Serving the People or the People's Note: On the Political Economy of Talent Allocation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 May 2023

Kezhou Xiao*
Affiliation:
Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University, Guangzhou, China
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

An efficient allocation of talents through occupational choice is central to modern economic growth. Removing developmental barriers unfavorable to entrepreneurship and artificially imposed for political reasons (i.e., the cage theory) might be a plausible channel for China's superb economic performance. Using a newly compiled dataset on China's Super Rich Persons, the regression kink design reports supportive evidence on the politically induced structural change in the social composition of entrepreneurs using Deng Xiaoping's Southern Talks as an event shock. Consistent with a pro-market talent allocation framework, this article finds that (1) the share of super-rich entrepreneurs with state sector experience and a college degree declined, suggesting that the period of the Southern Talks opened a window of opportunity for venturing, and (2) the effects on the attributes of the parental father of the entrepreneurs are somewhat limited.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of V.K. Aggarwal

Introduction

Improved talent allocation through occupational choices via entrepreneurial entry is central to modern economic performance. Politically driven changes to the incentive structure by national leaders affect overall economic performance through mobility between the public and private sectors. The removal of developmental barriers unfavorable to entrepreneurship, which were imposed historically for political and ideological reasons, through a resolution of China's high-level elite competition and factional politics, could interact with labor market adjustments and bring developmental outcomes through better allocation of talents. This observation resonates with classical work on entrepreneurship in an economically backward society, where agency-induced institutional changes brought about a sudden spurt of development driven by entrepreneurial entries.Footnote 1 Conceptualizing Deng Xiaoping's Southern Talks at the beginning of 1992 and the insertion of his vision of a socialist market economy at the end of the same year as a political shock with lasting credibility impacts,Footnote 2 this article presents evidence of such political commitment effects by estimating the long-term impact of this resolution of political ideologies on the social composition of super-rich persons in China.

Deng's Southern Talks and their game-changing impacts on China's policy regime offer a unique opportunity to investigate how the consolidation of major political struggles in a socialist context induced young officials in the bureaucratic promotion game to join the wave of entrepreneurs founding businesses. This shock has three distinct features. First, the initiation of the change was driven by prominent national leaders during acute policy uncertainties. Still feeling Tiananmen's specter, Deng's Southern Talks came only one month after the collapse of the Soviet Union, which was seen as a significant setback for the communist and socialist movements. Second, Deng's unprecedented political message was aimed at the forthcoming party congress, which was to be held by the end of 1992. Therefore, the public was expecting a party congress report with either a confirmation of the old agenda (e.g., a return to conservatism or a cage theory view of the market economy) or an announcement of a new political line. Finally, a rumor began circulating in some circles that the older statesmen from the party conservatives, particularly Deng's rival camp, Chen Yun and Li Xiannian, were suffering from health problems near the end of their lives.Footnote 3

Thus, the choice to use the watershed year of 1992 as an identification threshold to investigate entrepreneurial outcomes is not made without institutional context, although thriving rural entrepreneurship was well documented in the 1980s.Footnote 4 The interpretation of Deng's Southern Talks shall not be limited to what he said during his visit to the southern part of the country in January 1992 without holistically taking into account the consolidation of his version of the developmental agenda via a formal party congress held in October of the same year. This episode was memorable for China's contemporary political economy because of its lasting significance for the country's developmental trajectory. Without Deng's political maneuver, the political uncertainty regarding key questions of China's socialist market economy could have severely hampered the subsequent unleashing of genuine entrepreneurship.

In The Rise of Entrepreneurship in China, Tse reported,

In the early 90s, a number of government officials inspired by Deng's “Southern Visit” left their government roles and ventured into businesses. This was a rather speculative move that required great courage. If they failed, the “iron rice bowl” they had abandoned would not welcome them back with open arms. At this time, these people were considered foolish by many for leaving these highly desired positions of stability and prosperity. The majority of this “Gang of 1992” were quite successful in their entrepreneurial pursuits and some of them eventually became industry leaders.Footnote 5

To celebrate the rise of this cohort of entrepreneurs induced by Deng's monumental Southern Talks, a phrase “the 1992 cohort” was coined specifically for this purpose by Chen Dongsheng, a billionaire entrepreneur from a peasant background who would later marry the granddaughter of Mao. Before plunging into his private business, Chen was the deputy editor of Management World, a publication under the Development Research Center of China's State Council. Arranged by an influential circle of China's prominent entrepreneurs, a book of the same title, The 1992 Cohort, was published in 2012 and specifically dedicated to the twentieth anniversary of Deng's Southern Talks.

The title of this article, “Serving the People or the People's Note,” has multifaceted meanings in this context and requires some elaboration. The phrase “Serve the People” is a political slogan going back to Chairman Mao's era, when the chairman wrote an effusive speech commemorating Zhang Side, a People's Liberation Army soldier, for his sacrifice to the party's course. Even today, this phrase is officially recognized as a mission statement of the Communist Party of China (CPC). The other part of the phrase, “the People's Note,” refers to the Chinese currency, the renminbi, representing profit-oriented ventures and the burgeoning market sector. The title of this article describes a trade-off facing elite talents in China around 1992, when the developmental path of their beloved country induced by Deng's final assault on the party conservatives was at crossroads: whether to stay within the party system or join the wave of market reform and become entrepreneurs.

To empirically test the presence of a cohort of entrepreneurship following Deng's Southern Talks, this article utilizes China's Super Rich Persons (CSRP), a unique dataset on the persons or families who entered the top of Hurun's China Rich List at least once between 2000 and 2018. Previously, this dataset has been used to analyze the social space of China's emerging super-rich persons, who are distinguished by their political, cultural, and social capital.Footnote 6 Aided by a regression kink design, the share of super-rich entrepreneurs with state sector experience and a college degree declined after 1992. Confirming the presence of a 1992 cohort of entrepreneurs suggests that the profile of super-rich persons peaked in 1992 in terms of those attributes. Moreover, the limited effects on the characteristics of the parental father of the entrepreneurs suggest that entrepreneurial successes were driven by politically induced market opportunity as opposed to social background. The main findings from this study are robust to a wide range of alternative specifications and robustness checks. The most substantial support of the core message comes from a concentrated bulk of super-rich persons founding companies around the window of Deng's Southern Talks.

My identification strategy based on regression discontinuity design allowed an estimation of politically induced structural changes in the social composition of entrepreneurs. Two identification assumptions are required for valid estimates.Footnote 7 First, the assignment variable, the time location to the Southern Talks, cannot be fully controlled by those choosing entrepreneurship before the Southern Talks yet affects later comers. Given the national publicity and the release of the party congress report by the end of 1992, comparing entrepreneurial profiles before and after 1992 provides an opportunity to detect the impact of these politically induced changes. Second, insurance against manipulation for the continuity of the running variable at the kink needs to be secured. I present evidence in support of these assumptions.

This study reveals the lasting consequences of political as well as ideological resolution in a socialist context on occupational choice. It offers new insights into the importance of entrepreneurial response for China's subsequent economic growth. One novelty of this article is to provide an estimated impact of removing political barriers to entering into entrepreneurship.Footnote 8 Eventually, the changing social composition of super-rich persons and reduction of political uncertainties induced a swarm of highly educated and good-quality talent into private entrepreneurship, resulting in a structural trend change in the social composition of super-rich persons.

This study contributes to three strands of the literature. First, it examines the nature of entrepreneurship and the rise of billionaires in China.Footnote 9 Previous studies have investigated several determinants of entrepreneurship in China, including social networks,Footnote 10 localization and urbanization economies,Footnote 11 local business environment and parental background,Footnote 12 and social composition.Footnote 13 Beyond self-employment, scholarship on entrepreneurship as increasingly focused on superstar billionaires at the top. Progress was made in understanding the sociopolitical profiles of China's super-rich persons,Footnote 14 the social and human capital of internet entrepreneurs,Footnote 15 and spatial mobility patterns.Footnote 16 Unlike previous studies, this study examines the effect of leadership-driven political changes on the affected set of super-rich persons and billionaire entrepreneurs. In doing so, the empirical results offer an important determinant of China's superstar entrepreneurs as key drivers of the country's economic growth in the reform era.

Second, this study fits into a large number of studies on China's private sector development and its relation to the party-state. Prior research on the effect of entrepreneurship on growth has found positive results.Footnote 17 The deepening of market reforms was found to diminish the role of political connections during regional institutional development.Footnote 18 Over different reform stages from 1978 to 1996, the willingness of urban cadres to become self-employed increased over time as payoffs in entrepreneurship experienced a high return.Footnote 19 While there has been a consensus that entrepreneurship and small businesses have contributed to private sector development,Footnote 20 the political nature of this achievement has not been underscored. Tracing China's entrepreneurship cycle to elite politics, this article attempts to understand the effect on private sector development of China's national political dynamics. Who will become entrepreneurs in developing countries, particularly in a context of uncertainty where capitalist roaders are outlawed by socialist ideological shackles? From this angle, Deng's Southern Talk shall be regarded as one of the most significant developmental triumphs in alleviating commitment problems of doing private business in a socialist context.

Third, this study adds to the literature on changing reward structures and mobilities between the public and private sectors. Theoretical attempts have been made to model the divergent career patterns of politiciansFootnote 21 and the supply of elected officials in capitalist democracies.Footnote 22 Building on the occupation view of entrepreneurship,Footnote 23 this study is connected with determinants of the allocation of talents.Footnote 24 Although approaching the problem from a socialist context, this study considers elite competition and policy struggle to be important channels influencing entrepreneurial entry and selection into the public sector.

The remainder of this article is organized as follows. The next section presents the institutional context within the background debate between Chen Yun and Deng Xiaoping over possible blueprints of market socialism. Through this characterization, the historical significance of Deng's Southern Talks can be illuminated. Then, a theoretical framework is offered, linking political as well as ideological debates on the political economy of reform with elite competition and talent allocation. The following section introduces China's Super Rich Persons (CSRP) and presents the identification framework and results. The final section concludes in light of the findings reported in this article.

The political context: Deng Xiaoping's Southern Talks and competing views on market socialism

Chen's cage theory

Historians tend to trace the origin of Chen Yun's cage theory to the period of 1961–62, when Chen was sidelined by Mao, who personally preferred a more radical approach to socialization.Footnote 25 An early study on Chen Yun and Chinese politics noted,

By late 1981 and 1982, Chen devoted more attention to the planned economy. He declared that the relationship between the planned economy and the active economy (i.e., the market) was like a bird and a cage. The plan was the cage and the bird was the market. If the cage was too small, the bird would suffocate. If there was no cage, the bird would fly away. He stressed that planning must continue to govern many parts of the economy, including agriculture.Footnote 26

Chen's restricted view of the market economy contrasted with Deng's more liberated view. The political as well as ideological position differences between these perspectives underlies the tension of the marketization and stabilization debate in the 1980s. Following the Tiananmen tragedy, the promotion of Shanghai party secretary Jiang Zemin was widely seen as Deng's concession to Chen. However, Deng was not pleased with stalled economic reforms and worried about the historical legacies of his economic liberalization policies.Footnote 27 The collapse of the Soviet Union offered Deng the exact moment for a political maneuver to win back the party's support for his version of market socialism.

Deng's political maneuver during the Southern Talks

The identification strategy in this study relied on Deng's Southern Talks to be credible through an immediate change in formal institutions (e.g., the forthcoming party congress). While Deng's message could generate differential expectations in potential entrepreneurs, if not their beliefs about possible future policy reversals, it is essential to note that Deng's political venture and its decisive impact on the planned versus market debate have added a strong sense of irreversibility. This was achieved in a difficult situation beset by a confluence of factors: the collapse of the Soviet Union a month before his visit, the failing health of the older statesmen among the party conservatives,Footnote 28 the fading of memories about Tiananmen, and finally, the urgency that a political report would be drafted at the forthcoming party congress.

Meeting the challenges of the party and new situations globally, Deng Xiaoping went to Guangdong Province, in the southern part of the country, where he spent five days in Shenzhen and another six days in Zhuhai, two of his signature cities in the Special Economic Zone exemplified by his reform and opening programs.Footnote 29 In each place he visited along with his family, Deng Xiaoping reasserted the reformist spirit, exhorting local cadres to experiment with bolder steps and kill their way out for a better future. In particular, Deng looked at Shenzhen and hoped it would one day speed up its development by catching up with the four little dragons: Singapore, South Korea, Hong Kong, and Taiwan.

The most difficult challenge facing the party leadership was ideological obstacles, given the collapse of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union and the tragedy of Tiananmen. The public mood was low and there was an expectation of more crackdowns as policy programs of the anti-color revolution unfolded. The theoretical issues over whether, to what extent, and how a genuine market economy could be compatible with the ideals and theories of classical socialism, however, were deliberatively brushed away, as Deng famously asserted in one of his Southern Talks, which was circulated first as a formal party document and then crystalized posthumously (around 1997) as part of the CPC's official ideologies and guiding principles, Deng Xiaoping Theory:

Whether or not to have more planning or market-based economy is not the deciding difference between socialism and capitalism. The planned economy does not equal socialism, and capitalism has planning too. The market-based economy does not equal capitalism either, and socialism can have markets as well. Plans and markets are nothing but economic means. The fundamental aim of socialism is to unleash and develop productivity, eliminate exploitation and economic polarization so as to achieve common prosperity for all.Footnote 30

While giving informal sessions to local party officials, reporters from Hong Kong spread the notes of Deng's speech, an act that was difficult for the conservatives in Beijing to ignore. Incumbent party secretary Jiang Zemin remained alert to the elders’ reaction and the active shots fired by Deng. Meanwhile, the Hong Kong newspaper and television began to spread Deng's message. By the time the Southern Talks ended on 30 January 1992, the official party media was silent on Deng's trip to Guangdong and made no political announcements as rumors spread from the southern part of the country. Immediately afterward, Deng Xiaoping went to Shanghai with his family to enjoy the Chinese New Year for about three weeks before heading to the capital for a political cleanup, anticipating the outcome of his finale.

The immediate and lasting impacts on China's policy regime regarding the market economy

It was no easy task, even for paramount leader Deng Xiaoping, to solidify his reform program committed to marketization and command the support of the party apparatus. During the celebration of the Chinese New Year, party secretaries and high officials paid visits to Chen Yun for advice, waiting for the changing winds to come. Deng Liqun, a notable party hard-liner, shot back, clearly reflecting the planner's message: “People who stubbornly cling to their liberal beliefs are using anti-leftism as a pretext to oppose the Communist Party leadership and the socialist system.”Footnote 31

However, by then the political tide had shifted entirely in Deng's favor, partly because the conservatives, confronted with new challenges, had nothing new to offer. A notice prepared by Beijing on Deng's talk was circulated to all Central Committee members by the end of February. At the March Politburo meeting, President Yang Shangkun and Party Secretary Jiang Zemin fully supported Deng's statements. The party center implemented Deng's political spirit into concrete policy packages in late May. Jiang, on 9 June, delivered a speech on Deng's address to high-level students at the Central Party School. By then, the reformers had won. As his conservative colleague, Li Xiannian, reached the end of his life, Chen Yun visited Shanghai Pudong and approved further economic development efforts, despite his usual cautious tone. As Deng Xiaoping consolidated his victory and captured the political agenda, the 14th Party Congress held on 12–18 October put a striving goal into the party's politico-economic agenda: a socialist market economy.

The year of Deng's Southern Talks was fascinating as an example of organizational transformation and institutional adaptation marked by a combination of elite-driven policy debates with entrepreneurial responses to the society at large. Fighting over Maoist and quasi-Maoist (e.g., Hua Guofeng), Deng fought back to high-level politics through a Maoist critique of Maoist errors seeking truth from facts. Reigning in party liberals Hu Yaobang and Zhao Ziyang, two successors he had handpicked, Deng Xiaoping scapegoated them for failing to handle strategic criticisms hurled against the party because of liberating policy throughout the reformist path. In the case of Hu Yaobang, a good-hearted comrade indeed, Deng considered him too soft on the party's political enemies, who disagreed with the fundamental lines of the party and could not be reasonably convinced. For Zhao Ziyang, the failed pricing reforms almost invalidated the “dual-track” approach by escalating student protests and public anger over profiting from the gap between “planned price” governed by state quotas and market prices. The moment the policymakers were viewed as both promoters and beneficiaries of reform, the political logic and moral appeals crumbled into tears.

The tragedy of Tiananmen and the subsequent reassertion of power by the party conservatives, not to mention the promotion of Jiang Zemin, Shanghai party chief, seemed to have scored for the conservatives: the markets were allowed but would be kept within strict cages. Biding his time, this is where Deng Xiaoping's Southern Talks came in, taking on the conservatives when the two elders were ailing (Li Xiannian died in 1992 and Chen Yun in 1995). How Deng Xiaoping turned a losing game into a stunning victory for the reformist spirits amid a pessimistic and depressing mood after the Tiananmen tragedy and capitalized on that victory through formal party documents was a major historical event for the CPC. It encapsulated the phrase “market economy” firmly into the ideology of socialism with Chinese characteristics, eventually sidelining the theoretical debate over the relationship between capitalism, socialism, and markets. As such, Deng was rather sincere in saying that “China must watch out for the Right, but mainly defend against the Left.”Footnote 32

Thus, from the perspective of leadership-driven institutional change, Deng's Southern Talks were recognized as a critical watershed event not only because of what he said during the Southern Talks, but also, importantly, how the battle of ideas paved the way for a final consolidation of a political victory over the competing view proffered by the cage theory of market socialism. With Deng Xiaoping and Chen Yun leaving the political podium, China's institutional transition into full-fledged market socialism was the outcome of an inevitable end of a set of conflicting ideological and political battles in the 1980s.Footnote 33 This rather dramatic resolution of political conflicts offered a unique opportunity for estimating its impact on entrepreneurial outcomes.

Theoretical Model

Model setup and initial allocation

Consider an extended political economy model with occupational choicesFootnote 34 and three kinds of agents: public officials, entrepreneurs, and workers. Each person i lives for only one period. There is a stable distribution of entrepreneurial abilities in the population such that it is common knowledge that this distribution has stable support [1, ∞), density function f (A), and cdf F (A). There is a single output y in the private economy. Agent i with ability Ai can become an entrepreneur by exploiting existing technology r(.) by hiring labor units h.

In addition, the quality of the public sector G is taken to be fixed. Upon the occupation choice between workers and entrepreneurs, the talents face a sectoral choice between the public and the private sector, where a mixture of public motivations and rent-seeking opportunities drives the leading officials. The ability of public officials can be allocated between providing good public service for the common good and capturing higher-status rents for themselves.

The quality of the public sector G(.) = G(hP) is assumed to be a function of the number of public sector workers hP, as opposed to bureaucratic elites (i.e., those being able to share rents), where G(.) is imposed with standard concavity and Inada restrictions. The public-mindedness of the agent i is given by public motivation pi, which has a stable support [1, ∞), density function q(p), and cdf Q(p). The variable can be interpreted as the highest gap in materialistic rewards that the public sector can offer less to keep the worker i with the ability Ai participate. A choice governs a trade-off among the elites of the society, i ∈ {P, E}, where P stands for the public sector and E the private economy as described in the previous section. The payoff for workers in the public sector and the private markets is wP and wE, respectively.

This model further assumes that becoming a political elite is more challenging than opening a small business, and therefore the ability cutoff for becoming a political elite (Ā) is higher than the ability cutoff for an entrepreneur (A).Footnote 35 In addition, the linkage between the economy's private and public sector shares is technically bounded such that an additional s unit goes into the state's treasury for each unit surplus generated by the private sector.

The timing of events is as follows:

  • The social guardians (clarified in the next section) set the entry criteria for being a political elite Ā.

  • Agent i solves their optimization problems given their innate ability Ai and public motivation pi and the economy's objective environment {wP, wE, Ā, A, s, r(.), G(.)} and other's optimal decision.

  • Under the equilibrium of this economy, no person i has an incentive to change their choices.

This simple model features a simple static equilibrium characterized in the following proposition, which is proven in the Appendix.

Theorem 1 Under the equilibrium outcome (wP, wE, A, Ā) of this private Lucas economy with a public sector, the allocation of talent is as follows:

  1. (i) For a person such that Ai ∈ [1, A], they are either (a) private sector workers if wE − wP ≥ pi or otherwise (b) public sector workers;

  2. (ii) For person such that Ai ∈ (A, Ā), they become entrepreneurs;

  3. (iii) For persons such that Ai ∈ (Ā, ∞), (a) they become political elites if their returns are higher or otherwise (b) entrepreneurs.

Theorem 1 pins down the initial allocation of talents in this model economy. This also gives the initial size of firms, the fraction of agents becoming workers, and the generated rents for political elites in this economy.

Debating the political economy of reform: elite competition and entry into entrepreneurship

Consider the institutional impact of Deng's Southern Talks political maneuver on talent allocation and, eventually, the size of firms. Because neither Deng Xiaoping nor Chen Yun was keen on promoting their heirs to the leadership position, the debate on the political economy of reform transcended dynastic politics and was consistent with a social guardian position.Footnote 36 Notice that the entry criteria, Ā, is made exogenous for being a political elite in the prior discussion. This policy variable is controllable through the Organization Department of the CPC apparatus, which makes choices about personnel policies and selection criteria. Therefore, this is no wonder, viewed from the proposed framework, that the most crucial organizational policy is to find persons with a combination of high ability Ai and high motivation pi, who are well known as “red and technical” (you hong you zhuan) individuals capable of being technically competent as well as loyal to the party leadership. Now, the debate on the political economy of reform was to decide whether to impose a cage on the socialist market economy. This is modeled as setting a policy handle, $ \,\bar {\!h} $, on the maximum size of the private firm such that equilibrium labor hiring from the entrepreneurial side cannot exceed, $ h^{\ast} \le \ \bar {\!h} $. Comparing the size of gross domestic product (GDP) with and without such imposition on the size of private firms, the immediate and long-term impact of Deng's political moves can be formalized in the following theorem.

Theorem 2 (Comparison of blueprints) GDPcage < GDPmarket

The proof of this proposition is straightforward from the setup of the model. Chen Yun's vision requires the imposition of a cage, $ \,\bar {\!h} $, over labor hirings. For those entrepreneurs such that their labor demand $ D> \,\bar {\!h} $, they are thus prevented from hiring labors beyond the cage limit. The private sector, viewed from the entrepreneurial surplus, will be smaller than what could be achieved efficiently. With a fixed s relating back to the public sector, the total compensation for public workers and political elites will be smaller. Unless h is so high as to be irrelevant, this implies that GDPcage < GDPmarket.

An intuition of this result can be provided. Chen Yun's blueprint requires the imposition of a cage, $ \,\bar {\!h} $, on maximum labor hirings. For those high-ability entrepreneurs with greater labor demand above this cage limit, there is a surplus to be gained, but they are prevented from being able to do so. The size of the private sector measured in terms of the entrepreneurial surplus will therefore be smaller. Consequently, it would translate into a smaller pie for public sector workers and political elites unless $ \,\bar {\!h} $ is so high that there is no policy difference between Chen Yun and Deng Xiaoping.

However ad hoc this political economy model is, the formal presentation offers two testable predictions from the credible removal of political as well as ideological barriers and consolidation of Deng's blueprint for the empirical work. Thus, switching from Deng and Chen's political impasse to Deng's victory allowed an expansion of the private economy measured by the number and the size of private businesses. This is listed as hypothesis H1.

H1: The private sector expands in both the number and size of firms.

In addition, the formal model predicts that around the impacting time point, noticeable entry into entrepreneurship shall be observed as political uncertainty gave away to business opportunities. In other words, the empirical data should witness the presence of a 1992 cohort of entrepreneurship, and this is listed as hypothesis H2.

H2: High-ability people are leaving the public sector (especially around the kink) and starting to become entrepreneurs. This fact shall be detected by the fact that the social composition of the entrepreneurs (especially around the kink) begin to change.

Empirical framework

Two stylized facts

The development of China's private sector was initiated in 1978 when the Cultural Revolution ended. Figure 1 plots two curves presenting the changing numbers of private firms and small owner firms (getihu) during China's reform era, as documented by the National Bureau of Statistics. While both curves witnessed an upward trend, the growth rate of private firms was more significant and accelerated after Deng's Southern Talks. This piece of evidence offers some support for H1.

Figure 1. The number of private firms and small owner firms (getihu). The red curve represents the evolution of the number of small owner firms (getihu), and the blue curve represents the evolution of the number of private firms.

Source: National Bureau of Statistics.

Regarding the size of the private firms, a proxy measure from the wealth of the super-rich persons is considered. Building on the Hurun China Rich List (HCRL), a British publication, Lu, Fan, and Fu described the construction of the CSRP as a four-step process.Footnote 37 First, they defined the super-rich as those who had ever ranked higher than 100 on the HCRL. Second, they collected basic personal information and the rankings on the on list for each year from 2000 and 2018. Third, they constructed a list of questions regarding the families of the super-rich and asked their research assistants to fill in those items using corporate websites, media reports, and other official datasets. Finally, the final dataset was formed with cross-checking, cleaning, and integration.

Figure 2 offers a picture of the wealth dispersions from the fifty super-rich Chinese persons from 2000 to 2018. Initially, the gap among the wealthiest persons was negligible before 2007, and that dispersion rose to a situation where a few superstar billionaires outpaced other super-rich persons. This documentation demonstrates increasing wealth from these super-rich persons and growing divergence of wealth dispersions.

Figure 2. Wealth distribution of super-rich Chinese persons. This plot graphs the evolution of wealth distribution of super-rich persons in China from 2000 to 2018. For each boxplot, the dispersion is shown for a particular year.

Source: CSRP (Lu et al. Reference Lu, Fan, Han and Xiao2019).

Taking these two stylized facts together, the evolution of critical macro statistics on China's private sector development confirms that Deng's Southern Talks victory reaffirmed the public's confidence in the party's continuing development commitments. In addition, given the deaths of Chen Yun and Li Xiannian, the policy return to a political impasse seen in the 1980s became less likely.

The empirical part of the article concentrates on the second point of the prediction. Using Deng Xiaoping's Southern Talks as an exogenous political shock with credible commitment impacts, the effect on the changing social composition of the super-rich persons in China can be estimated. This novel approach has a number of benefits. First, the regression discontinuity kink design exploits a nationwide shock to gauge evidence for any likely structural changes. This research design contrasts with studies using local variation from specific policy experiments. Second, the regression discontinuity kink design offers some insights into the prediction of the models and addresses the role of generation shifts in changing the composition of super-rich persons. The intuition is that if politically induced economic uncertainty has been removed, the chance of becoming superstar wealth creators would have a time dimension associated with large entry into entrepreneurship around that period. In the absence of the event of the Southern Talks (i.e., with cage continuously being imposed or political and ideological debate unresolved), the effects from mechanical generation shifts could be much smaller than what can be captured from the data as predicted by the proposed theory. Third, this does not imply that generation turnover does not matter. Indeed, the entry into entrepreneurship induced by Deng's Southern Talks could facilitate the subsequent generation turnover.

A regression kink design

The research design using an event shock like the Southern Talks suggests an empirical strategy based on a regression discontinuity kink design using semi-parametric techniques:

(1)$$y_{ipc} = {\rm \alpha } + {\rm \rho }_1T_i + {\rm \rho }_2T_i \times f( {{\rm time\ distanc}{\rm e}_i} ) + {\rm Z}^{\prime}{\rm \beta } + f( {{\rm time\ distanc}{\rm e}_i} ) + \Phi _{\,pc} + \it \$ _{ipc}$$

where yipc is the outcome of the research interest for a super-rich person i based in province p with cohort c, and Ti is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the person i entered into entrepreneurship after the Southern Talks, with zero otherwise. The company's founding year by person i, a running variable, is used to determine whether it was affected by the Southern Talks. Zi belongs to a set of socioeconomic variables (i.e., characteristics of the entrepreneur) independent of the assignment variable Ti, and f (.) is the regression discontinuity polynomial function, controlling for the shape around the neighborhood of discontinuous shock. Lastly, Φpc is a set of interaction terms between province and cohort fixed effects. In some specifications, Φpc is simply modeled as Φpc = θp + γc.

Regression discontinuity design has been used widely in spatial models and election studies. In practice, f (.) represents a polynomial function of the gap to the year of the Southern Talks, 1992. The treatment assignment variable, Ti ≡ 1(Found Yeari > 1992), designates the post–Southern Talks binary. The treatment impacts, ρs where s ∈ {1, 2}, capture the impact of Deng Xiaoping's Southern Talks on the set of entrepreneurial composition under the assumption that the suitable window offers the right comparison. If ρ 1 = 0, then the regression discontinuity design captures the structural change induced by the Southern Talks. If ρ 1 ≠ 0, not only the outcome of interest change following the Southern Talks but also jumps at the discontinuous point.Footnote 38

The estimating framework based on sharp regression discontinuity design relies on two critical identifying assumptions.Footnote 39 One, the assignment variable, the time location to the Southern Talks, cannot be fully controlled by those choosing entrepreneurship before the Southern Talks yet affects later comers. This implies that the suitable choice of the window for the comparison between those entrepreneurs joining prior to the Southern Talks and immediately following the design approximates a good experiment. Formally speaking, let yi 1 and yi 0 denote two potential outcomes under treatment and control. The entry year of entrepreneur i determines not only the value of Ti, but also the time distancei ≡ (the year of entry into entrepreneurshipi − 1992) from the Southern Talks. This value can be used as input for f (.). The running variable in the context can thus be the time distance defined above or an entrepreneur's raw year of entry. Identification requires at the discontinuous threshold, conditional expectation functions for E[yi 1|tdi] and E[yi 0|tdi] are continuous for an approximately good random assignment.

To assess the foregoing concern, I examine the summary statistics table (see Table 1) of two groups apart from the Southern Talks with a suitable choice of windows: full sample, 1980–2000, and 1985–1995.Footnote 40 Across five target measures of social composition, none is significantly different in terms of difference-test and distributional test across the three window periods. I take this as a confidence check for a plausibly good random assignment. The case of a college degree of the person is quite interesting. Among the full sample and the window period of 20 years (1980–2000), the level of education increases significantly, indicative of substantial generational change, consistent with significant changes in distribution. Yet, column (9) of Table 1 showcases that the changes are less effective in a narrow window. This signal of evidence could support the story: Deng's Southern Talks somewhat facilitates generational changes by increasing the share of college graduates.

Table 1. Summary statistics.

Source: CSRP (Lu et al. Reference Lu, Fan, Han and Xiao2019). Columns (1)–(3) represent the whole sample. Columns (4)–(6) represent the subsample in which entry into entrepreneurship was made between 1980 and 2000. Columns (7)–(9) represent the subsample in which entry into entrepreneurship was made between 1985 and 1995. Columns (3), (6), and (9) give the t-test in parentheses and the distributional test in square brackets.

In addition, the continuity of the running variable at the kink needs to be ensured against manipulation. To assess the validity of the assumptions underlying the regression discontinuity and regression kink design, Figure 3 offers a histogram and kernel density for the year of entering the first job (Panel A) and becoming an entrepreneur (Panel B). Most of the super-rich persons in our database were employed far earlier than the time of the Southern Talks. In contrast, the timing of becoming an entrepreneur was rather balanced across the two sides of the Southern Talks. Notably, the entry years of the super-rich persons seem to be concentrated around the timing of the Southern Talks and gradually fade out, suggesting that the high chances of becoming super-rich are somewhat associated with a small window period around the Southern Talks. Combining a potentially ample market space or opportunities and removing political as well as ideological barriers worked to the advantage of future billionaires.

Figure 3. Histogram and kernel density: Entering year of first job and becoming an entrepreneur. Panel A depicts the histogram and kernel density of the entering year of the first job. Panel B displays the histogram and kernel density of the entering year as an entrepreneur. The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.

Source: CSRP (Lu et al. Reference Lu, Fan, Han and Xiao2019).

Manipulation testing for falsification of regression discontinuity design requires that those entrepreneurs could preempt their investment projects knowing that Deng Xiaoping would do something to overturn the gloomy mood after Tiananmen. Or, potential entrepreneurs could set up their businesses before the political uncertainties were removed. This possibility was rather unlikely because it would have required knowledge of the timing of the collapse of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union and Deng's rather unconventional response via the Southern Talks. To address this concern, I falsify the continuity assumption of the running variable around the cutoff.Footnote 41 Appendix Figure A.2 presents a density continuity test near the cutoff.Footnote 42 A local polynomial density estimator turns out a robust T value of 1.3304 with an associated p-value of .1834, suggesting that manipulation of entry was rather unlikely.Footnote 43

Graphical evidence

In this section, I estimate the impact of the Southern Talks on the changing social composition of entrepreneurs using several measures. In short, the aim is to look for plausible structure turning points and immediate impacts induced by Deng's political moves. While generational shifts might threaten the identification strategies, this lurking factor coevolves with rather than causes the composition change in the space of super-rich persons. In other words, Deng's Southern Talks facilitated the differences in these variables. In all graphical and regression evidence that follows, cohort fixed effects are included to minimize the unobservable generational shifting factors.

I begin my discussion by plotting three outcome variables for the CSRP against the running variable, as shown in Figure 4. These are binned scatterplots, a nonparametric method of plotting the conditional expectation function by absorbing unobservable provincial and cohort-level fixed effects. Among CSRP, Panel A documents evidence that the share of college degree holders increases until the Southern Talks. This kink significantly confirms that Deng's political victory marked promising entry opportunities for those entrepreneurs. Consistent with Panel C, where those well-educated persons with state sector jobs leave their careers around that window of opportunity, this supports a case in which high-ability, highly educated former state employees are changing their career paths and venturing into entrepreneurship, eventually making it to the top. In both cases, the highest share is reached at or around the time of the Southern Talks. However, Panel B documents that the percentage of party members does not change drastically before and after the Southern Talks.

Figure 4. Graphical evidence: The impact on the person's attributes. This plot provides the regression discontinuity plot based on binned scatterplots after absorbing provincial and cohort fixed effects. The outcome variable of interests from Panels A–C: the share of a college degree, the share of party membership, and the share of state sector experience by the entrepreneurs. The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.

Source: CSRP (Lu et al. Reference Lu, Fan, Han and Xiao2019).

Suppose market opportunities were correlated with political connections and family backgrounds, then similar changes might have happened to the attributes of the parental father of these super-rich persons. Accordingly, I plot these three measures for the parental father of the CSRP in Figure 5. The picture does not support a strong correlation between market opportunities and social position. The share of party membership does not change significantly before and after the Southern Talks (Panel E). Interestingly, the parental father's share of a college degree reaches a low point as the corresponding share for the person reaches the highest point (Panel D). In Panel F, the trend of a declining share of state sector experience for the parental father of the CSRP continues to drop after the Southern Talks. In short, these graphical results indicate that the pro-market political reform initiated by Deng benefits entrepreneurs with actual market abilities in contrast with sons or daughters of elite officials.

Figure 5. Graphical evidence: The impact on father's attributes. This plot provides the regression discontinuity plot based on scatterbins, absorbing provincial and cohort fixed effects. The outcome variable of interests from Panels D–F: the share of a college degree, the share of party membership, and the share of state sector experience by the entrepreneurs by the entrepreneur's father. The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.

Source: CSRP (Lu et al. Reference Lu, Fan, Han and Xiao2019).

Additionally, Deng's Southern Talks might have inadvertently facilitated generational shifts in the space of super-rich persons. Binned scatterplots are provided by Figure 6 on the age structure (Panel A) and gender composition (Panel B) of the entrepreneurs. Panel A documents a slight change in the age structure of entering CSRP: the cohort, on average, becomes younger following the Southern Talks, with a flatter slope. By contrast, the share of female entrepreneurs in the CSRP reversed from a growing trend and experienced a decline. These observations reveal a general trend that the billionaires in the dataset are driven by market success as opposed to parental connections.

Figure 6. Graphical evidence: Other covariates. Panel A and panel B provide binned scatterplots of the age of the entrepreneur and gender composition (male = 1). The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.

Source: CSRP (Lu et al. Reference Lu, Fan, Han and Xiao2019).

These patterns are informative in at least two aspects. First, there is a structural kink in the space of super-rich persons induced by the flow of events generated primarily by Deng's Southern Talks. Second, given ongoing political debates and the probability of a policy reversal, this window of business opportunity does not privilege too much those with political connections in general, which suggests that the policy impact of forthcoming pro-market reform does not particularly favor children of political elites or other privileged circles, as divided as they were during Deng's political maneuvers. In other words, this implies that Deng's message was transmitted in a leveled national information platform instead of targeted segments of society.

Regression estimates

Table 2 reports the regression kink estimates for the changing social composition of super-rich persons following the Southern Talks, with standard errors clustered at the provincial and cohort levels. Across all specifications, the estimated coefficients for the jump (ρ 1) cannot significantly reject zero. Three specifications using second-order polynomials—columns (2), (5), and (8)—do not increase explanatory power, giving credence to an underlying linear trend. The kink effect (ρ 2) on the share of college degrees—columns (1), (2), and (3)—offers an estimate between –0.027 and –0.037, confirming the graphical evidence of Panel A of Figure 4. This evidence shows that the share of college degree holders among CSRP dropped by about 10 percent within three years of the South Talks, without other changes.

Table 2. The impact of the Southern Talks on the social composition of super-rich persons.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the provincial and cohort levels. T stands for the incidence of the Southern Talks in 1992. TD refers to the time distance to the Southern Talks. An unreported constant is included in each specification. Columns (1)–(3) use the person's college degrees as a binary dependent variable. Columns (4)–(6) use the person's party membership employment as a binary dependent variable. Columns (7)–(9) use the person's state employment as a binary dependent variable.

A large number of higher education persons joining entrepreneurs, among whom quite a few stand out, suggests a window opportunity around the Southern Talks. The fact that these highly educated people flocked into founding their own businesses around that period is coupled with another fact that quite a few of these career switchers previously worked in the state sector. Based on specifications (7) and (9), the estimated kink effect is around –6 percent. Both values reach close to the top of their values at or nearby the Southern Talks. In the absence of Deng's political maneuver and the dampening effect of the Tiananmen tragedy, the sudden flocking into entrepreneurship driven mainly by good-quality talents within the party apparatus needs to be properly explained. Therefore, this is a telling sign of a 1992 cohort of entrepreneurs.

The kink effect on the share of party membership is somewhat less effective, a point confirmed by Panel B of Figure 4. The kink effect is estimated to be nonsignificant, failing to indicate that this value peaked during the event of the Southern Talks. In other words, this statistic, in particular, is less strongly related to the share of college degree holders and that of state sector experience among the CSRP sample. These estimates indicate that the presence of party membership is strongly associated with neither market abilities nor political background.

Table 3 reports the estimated kink effects for the parental father of these super-rich persons following the Southern Talks using the same outcome variables as for the persons themselves. Following results from columns (2), (5), and (8), the estimated effects on the second-order polynomial, as in the previous case, fail to generate meaningful results. Across all specifications, the estimated jump effects and the kink effects cannot significantly reject the zero thresholds. It meant that during the window of money-making opportunity around the Southern Talks, parental characteristics among CSRP were only marginally related to the core story. Those who flocked into entrepreneurship with a college degree and prior state sector experience had all sorts of parental fathers, making detectable changes in these attributes less visible. In contrast with the story of targeted information and political connection, the window of opportunities around the Southern Talks can be viewed as a relatively fair race open to all children of family backgrounds.

Table 3. The impact of the Southern Talks on the social composition of parental father of the super-rich persons.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the provincial and cohort levels. T stands for the incidence of the Southern Talks in 1992. TD refers to the time distance to the Southern Talks. An unreported constant is included in each specification. Columns (1)–(3) use the parental father's college degrees as binary dependent variables. Columns (4)–(6) use the parental father's party membership employment as a binary dependent variable. Columns (7)–(9) use the parental father's state employment as a binary dependent variable.

Holding constant the main specifications, The following exercise tests whether the main results are robust to different window periods against control variables. Table 4 deals with issues of multiple windows since regression kink designs seek to capture local effects. In the restricted sample for the 1980–2000 window—columns (1) and (3)—the estimated kink effects remain robust to the magnitude of a college degree share and the percentage of state employment at −3 percent and −6 percent, respectively. Further shrinking the sample size to a window period of 1985–1995—columns (2) and (4)—seems to coincide with the window of opportunity unleashed by the Southern Talks. None of the estimated kink effects can significantly reject zero at 5 percent, indicative of a period of sea jumping during which state employees switched their jobs and became entrepreneurs as their expectations over return prospects (adjusted for risk preference) began to shift among ideological as well as political debates over planned economy versus market economy.Footnote 44 One could raise a concern that Deng's Southern Talks merely confirm underlying trends from the 1980s. If this were the case, it would be difficult to reconcile with a changing composition of entering entrepreneurs, as high-quality talents might wish to stay in their careers had political uncertainties not been resolved.

Table 4. Robustness checks: Multiple windows.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the provincial and cohort levels. The standard errors in the brackets are based on the Huber-White robust errors. T stands for the incidence of the Southern Talks in 1992, and TD refers to the time distance to the Southern Talks. An unreported constant is included in each specification. Columns (1)–(2) use the person's college degrees as a binary dependent variable. Columns (3)–(4) use the person's state employment as a binary dependent variable.

Table 5 examines this consistent relationship against two control variables: gender and ethnicity. Using the complete sample, the kink effect for the share of college degrees stands at 3.7 percent in the negative for both variables—columns (1) and (2). Similarly, under this complete sample, the kink effect for the share of state employment is estimated at 6.7 percent in the negative for these two controls—columns (3) and (4)—showing the variability of ethnicity and gender is small compared with the main effect.

Table 5. Robustness checks: Control variables.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the provincial and cohort levels. The standard errors in the brackets are based on the Huber-White robust errors. T stands for the incidence of the Southern Talks in 1992, and TD refers to the time distance to the Southern Talks. An unreported constant is included in each specification. Columns (1)–(2) use the person's college degrees as a binary dependent variable. Columns (3)–(4) use the person's state employment as a binary dependent variable.

One might argue that the year of the Southern Talks might not be the “correct” shock year for a regression kink design. Table 6 tests the timing of the kink effects using four alternative timing indicators. Looking at Panels A and B as the timing of the event “moves” one or two years ahead, respectively, the kink effects on the share of college degree holders remain at similar magnitudes but with greater standard errors. On the other hand, the extent of the kink effect becomes more considerable. One explanation is that the share of college degree holders reaches its peak earlier than state employment. In addition, following the Southern Talks, those with state employment jobs continue to flow into the private marketplace, thus delaying the highest point for that particular value. As a result, the kink estimates become larger in absolute values. This explanation is consistent with the estimated coefficient at Panels C and D when the event's timing “moves” backward at one and two years, respectively. The kink effects on the share of college degree holders go up in absolute terms from the original 3.7 percent (column [3], Table 2) to 4 percent (Panel D, Table 6). The estimated coefficient on the share of state employment remains roughly the same at around 6 percent in absolute values. Combining this finding with the political context, one interpretation is that the cohort of 1992 entrepreneurs might not be limited to 1992. The overall picture could be broadly conceived as those talents leaving their bureaucratic careers between 1992 and 1994.

Table 6. Further examination of the kink.

Notes: Standard errors are clustered at the cohort level. All regressions use interacted fixed effects. The kink effect refers to the estimated coefficient ρ 2 in equation (1). An unreported constant is included in each specification. Columns (1)–(3) use the person's college degrees as a binary dependent variable. Columns (4)–(6) use the person's state employment as a binary dependent variable.

Taken as a whole, the regression estimates show that the timing of 1992 is an unusual impacting time point consolidating Deng's political vision. Not only did the paramount leader talk the talk, but also he made it true that his victory was institutionalized through formal party documents. Although the window of opportunity might have already opened before 1992, perhaps going back to 1985–1988, the flocking into the private economy with an energized entrepreneurial spirit could not have had such a substantial impact on China's political and economic landscape had Deng failed his epic maneuvers. That is why those individuals eventually become super wealthy by utilizing that window period of opportunity, confirming the concentration of entrepreneurial entries in Panel B of Figure 3. Viewed from the sample of CSRP, Deng's Southern Talks facilitated and consolidated the trends that had already been lurking in the late 80s had it not been abruptly interrupted by the Tiananmen tragedy. Accompanied by Chen Yun's death and the failure of the party conservatives to come up with a competing alternative, the ideological and political fight between the cage theory and the full-fledged market theory of socialism reached the end of its life cycle. Knowing that a policy reversal was unlikely, entrepreneurs and the private businesses understood that Deng's preferred version of market socialism was consolidated.

Conclusion

Deng Xiaoping's Southern Talks precipitated the end of China's grand debate about competing versions of market socialism with profound changes in the underlying policy regime. The significance of his political maneuver provides a unique opportunity to examine how the consolidation of a political as well as ideological victory in a socialist context affected incentives for entrepreneurial entry and wealth creation. In this analysis, this article utilized a regression kink design on the set of China's super-rich persons and documented a noticeable structural break consistent with the timeline of Deng's last battle.

Through influencing the allocation of talents, this paper proposes the importance role played by political resolution of economic commitment problems solutions as an alternative and plausible channel underpinning China's economic success. The analysis reports that some of the brightest and most highly educated former state employees immediately understood Deng's message and captured that window of opportunity following, if not around the period of the Southern Talks, eventually becoming super rich persons in China. The regression kink estimates suggest a 3 percent decline in the share of a college degree and 6 percent decline in the percentage of state employment history among the sample of super-rich Chinese persons, revealing the composition of that set of persons was experiencing trend changes induced by Deng's Southern Talks.

Linking these findings to entrepreneurship theory and current policy discussions might offer a direction for future research. Indeed, the theoretical model advanced here might represent a preliminary attempt in this direction. Aside from elite competition over fundamental ideological positions, could bureaucratic turnover in connection with regional policy experiments generate cyclical patterns of entrepreneurial entry and exit? Given these political impacts on business expectations and formation, what could be the implications of designing appropriate entrepreneurship policies? How did the consolidation of Xi Jinping's preferred policy program contribute to China's further development in business environments? These critical questions must be answered in various papers and have to be left for future research.

Improving talent allocation through political commitments has been a successful state strategy for China based on her past economic performance. The continual success of the Chinese political economy, however, depends on the regime's continued ability to instrumentalize the bourgeois component of the society (“serving the people's note”) into socialist ends (“serving the people”) such that under the red flag serving the people's note is but another side of serving the people.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/bap.2023.11.

Competing interests

The author declares none other than that this manuscript was a revision of a chapter of his PhD thesis at LSE.

Footnotes

1 Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012); Bell and Feng (Reference Bell and Feng2013); Gorodnichenko and Roland (Reference Gorodnichenko and Roland2017).

6 Lu, Fan, and Fu (Reference Lu, Fan and Fu2021).

8 One of the reviewers of this article has pointed out that this research design cannot properly distinguish entrepreneurial intentions from capabilities. In this context, it is difficult to decompose the effect of genuine business opportunities from entrepreneurial capabilities.

9 He, Lu, and Qian (Reference He, Lu and Qian2019).

11 Guo, He, and Li (Reference Guo, He and Li2016).

12 Jia, Lan, and Padró i Miquel (Reference Jia, Lan and Miquel2021).

14 Lu, Fan, and Fu (Reference Lu, Fan and Fu2021).

15 Batjargal (Reference Batjargal2007).

20 Lardy (Reference Lardy2014); Brandt and Rawski (Reference Brandt and Rawski2008).

21 Mattozzi and Merlo (Reference Mattozzi and Merlo2008)

22 Caselli and Morelli (Reference Caselli and Morelli2004).

24 Murphy, Shleifer, and Wishny (Reference Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny1991); Bö hm and Watzinger (Reference Böhm and Watzinger2015).

25 Fairbank (Reference Fairbank1986).

26 Bachman (Reference Bachman1985, 152).

27 Goldman and MacFarquhar (Reference Goldman and MacFarquhar1999); Fewsmith (Reference Fewsmith2001).

28 Li Xiannian died half a year following the Southern Talks. Chen Yun was invited to join Deng Xiaoping for the Southern Talks as a signal of party unity, yet he failed to show up for health reasons (see Vogel Reference Vogel2011, ch. 23).

29 A detailed timeline of Deng's Southern Talks is provided in Appendix A.1.

30 This quote can be found in The Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping, vol. 3, in the original version in Chinese (The People's Publisher, 1993/2009.11 version). The specific paragraph was excerpted from an article titled “Major Points over Talks from Places Like Wuchang, Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Shanghai, and others” [Zai Wuchang, Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Shanghai dengdi de tanhua yaodian] (18 January–21 February 1992). The English translation was provided by the author of this article. For the English version, the translated text can be found in Deng (Reference Xiaoping1993).

31 Quoted from Vogel (Reference Vogel2011, ch. 23).

32 Baum (Reference Baum1996, 341).

33 While Deng's Southern Talks spurred a massive wave of privatization and further marketization of the economy, the state sector responded with quite a few strategic policy packages, known as “grabbing big and letting go of small” (Hsieh and Song Reference Hsieh and Song2016).

34 Lucas (Reference Lucas1978); Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (Reference Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny1991).

35 The entry bar to share state rents to political elites can be set by the CPC apparatus.

36 Krueger (Reference Krueger2002).

37 Lu, Fan, and Fu (Reference Lu, Fan and Fu2021).

38 To ensure against treating regression discontinuities as kinks, both specifications are considered.

40 In the present exercise, the optimal selection of bandwidth is replaced by these three window periods.

41 McCrary (Reference McCrary2008).

42 Cattaneo, Jansson, and Ma (Reference Cattaneo, Jansson and Ma2018).

43 See Appendix Figure A.2 and Cattaneo, Jansson, and Ma (Reference Cattaneo, Jansson and Ma2020).

44 Consistent with reduced-form estimates, Appendix Table A.1 considers a nonparametric and data-driven estimation method based on Calonico, Cattaneo, and Titiunik (Reference Calonico, Cattaneo and Titiunik2014). Across three ways (conventional, bias-corrected, and robust), the share of state employment declined significantly by 6 percent per year for the super-rich persons after the Southern Talks.

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. New York: Crown Business.Google Scholar
Bachman, M. David. 1985. Chen Yun and the Chinese Political System. Berkeley, CA: Center for Chinese Studies.Google Scholar
Batjargal, Bat. 2007. “Internet Entrepreneurship: Social Capital, Human Capital, and Performance of Internet Ventures in China.” Research Policy 36 (5): 605–18.10.1016/j.respol.2006.09.029CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baum, Richard. 1996. Burying Mao: Chinese Politics in the Age of Deng Xiaoping. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bell, Stephen, and Feng, Hui. 2013. The Rise of the People's Bank of China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.10.4159/harvard.9780674073593CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Böhm, Michael, and Watzinger, Martin. 2015. “The Allocation of Talent over the Business Cycle and Its Long-Term Effect on Sectoral Productivity.” Economica 82 (328): 892911.10.1111/ecca.12143CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandt, Loren, and Rawski, Thomas G.. 2008. China's Great Economic Transformation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511754234CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calonico, Sebastian, Cattaneo, Matias D., and Titiunik, Rocio. 2014. “Robust Data-Driven Inference in the Regression-Discontinuity Design.” The Stata Journal 14 (4): 909–46.10.1177/1536867X1401400413CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, David, Lee, David S., Pei, Zhuan, and Weber, Andrea. 2015. “Inference on Causal Effects in a Generalized Regression Kink Design.” Econometrica 83 (6): 2453–83.10.3982/ECTA11224CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caselli, Francesco, and Morelli, Massimo. 2004. “Bad Politicians.” Journal of Public Economics 88 (3–4): 759–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cattaneo, Matias D., Jansson, Michael, and Ma, Xinwei. 2018. “Manipulation Testing Based on Density Discontinuity.” The Stata Journal 18 (1): 234–61.10.1177/1536867X1801800115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cattaneo, Matias D., Jansson, Michael, and Ma, Xinwei. 2020. “Simple Local Polynomial Density Estimators.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 115 (531): 1449–55.10.1080/01621459.2019.1635480CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xiaoping, Deng. 1993. Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping, vol. 3. Beijing: People's Publishing House.Google Scholar
Djankov, Simeon, Qian, Yingyi, Roland, Gérard, and Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina. 2006. “Who Are China's Entrepreneurs?” American Economic Review 96 (2): 348–52.10.1257/000282806777212387CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fairbank, John King. 1986. The Great Chinese Revolution, 1800–1985. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Xiaoguang, Fan and Peng, Lu. 2017. “The Social Composition of China's Private Entrepreneurs: Class and Cohort Differences.” [In Chinese.] Chinese Academy of Social Science 4: 7087.Google Scholar
Fewsmith, Joseph. 2001. China since Tiananmen: The Politics of Transition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511790959CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldman, Merle, and MacFarquhar, Roderick. 1999. The Paradox of China's Post-Mao Reforms. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gorodnichenko, Yuriy, and Roland, Gérard. 2017. “Culture, Institutions, and the Wealth of Nations.” Review of Economics and Statistics 99 (3): 402–16.10.1162/REST_a_00599CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guo, Qi, He, Canfei, and Li, Deyu. 2016. “Entrepreneurship in China: The Role of Localisation and Urbanisation Economies.” Urban Studies 53 (12): 25842606.10.1177/0042098015595598CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, Canfei, Lu, Jiangyong, and Qian, Haifeng. 2019. “Entrepreneurship in China.” Small Business Economics 52: 563–72.10.1007/s11187-017-9972-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Song, Zheng Michael. 2016. “Grasp the Large, Let Go of the Small: The Transformation of the State Sector in China.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2015 (1): 295366.10.1353/eca.2016.0005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Yasheng. 2008. Capitalism with Chinese Characteristics: Entrepreneurship and the State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jia, Ruixue, Lan, Xiaohuan, and Miquel, Gerard Padró i. 2021. “Doing Business in China: Parental Background and Government Intervention Determine Who Owns Busines[s].” Journal of Development Economics 151: 102670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klingler-Vidra, Robyn, Hai, Steven Jiawei, Liu, Ye, and Chalmers, Adam William. 2022. “Is the Jack Ma Trajectory Unique? Assessing the Place-Based Hypothesis on Entrepreneurial Success.” Journal of Small Business & Entrepreneurship 34 (4): 419–42.10.1080/08276331.2021.1974236CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Anne. 2002. Political Economy of Policy Reform in Developing Countries. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Landais, Camille. 2015. “Assessing the Welfare Effects of Unemployment Benefits Using the Regression Kink Design.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7 (4): 243–78.Google Scholar
Lardy, Nicholas R. 2014. Markets over Mao: The Rise of Private Business in China. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Lee, David S. 2008. “Randomized Experiments from Non-random Selection in US House Elections.” Journal of Econometrics 142 (2): 675–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Hongbin, Yang, Zheyu, Yao, Xianguo, Zhang, Haifeng, and Zhang, Junsen. 2012. “Entrepreneurship, Private Economy and Growth: Evidence from China.” China Economic Review 23 (4): 948–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, Peng, Fan, Xiaoguang, and Fu, Fan. 2021. “Profile of the Super Rich in China: A Social Space Analysis.” British Journal of Sociology 72 (3): 543–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, Peng, Fan, Xiaoguang, Han, Donglin, and Xiao, Kezhou. 2019. “China's Super Rich Persons (CSRP): A New Dataset on Emerging Private Wealth.”Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. 1978. “On the Size Distribution of Business Firms.” Bell Journal of Economics 9 (2): 508523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattozzi, Andrea, and Merlo, Antonio. 2008. “Political Careers or Career Politicians?Journal of Public Economics 92 (3–4): 597608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCrary, Justin. 2008. “Manipulation of the Running Variable in the Regression Discontinuity Design: A Density Test.” Journal of Econometrics 142 (2): 698714.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, Kevin M., Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert W.. 1991. “The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2): 503–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pang, C., and Li, Y.. 2011. “Chinese Entrepreneurship in the Context of Institution Transformation.” [In Chinese.] Chinese Journal of Management 8 (10): 1438–43.Google Scholar
Tian, Xiaowen. 2001. “Deng Xiaoping's Nanxun: Impact on China's Regional Development.” In The Nanxun Legacy and China's Development in the Post-Deng Era, edited by Wong, John and Yongnian, Zheng, 7592. Singapore: Singapore University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tse, Edward. 2016. “The Rise of Entrepreneurship in China.” Forbes, 5 April. Accessed 2 May 2023, https://www.forbes.com/sites/tseedward/2016/04/05/the-rise-of-entrepreneurship-in-china/.Google Scholar
Vogel, Ezra F. 2011. Deng Xiaoping and the Transformation of China. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wong, John, and Yongnian, Zheng, eds. 2001. The Nanxun Legacy and China's Development in the Post-Deng Era. Singapore: Singapore University Press.Google Scholar
Wu, Xiaogang. 2006. “Communist Cadres and Market Opportunities: Entry into Self-Employment in China, 1978–1996.” Social Forces 85 (1): 389411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yueh, Linda. 2009. “China's Entrepreneurs.” World Development 37 (4): 778–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhao, Suisheng. 1993. “Deng Xiaoping's Southern Tour: Elite Politics in Post-Tiananmen China.” Asian Survey 33 (8): 739–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, Wubiao. 2014. “Regional Institutional Development, Political Connections, and Entrepreneurial Performance in China's Transition Economy.” Small Business Economics 43 (1): 161–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The number of private firms and small owner firms (getihu). The red curve represents the evolution of the number of small owner firms (getihu), and the blue curve represents the evolution of the number of private firms.Source: National Bureau of Statistics.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Wealth distribution of super-rich Chinese persons. This plot graphs the evolution of wealth distribution of super-rich persons in China from 2000 to 2018. For each boxplot, the dispersion is shown for a particular year.Source: CSRP (Lu et al. 2019).

Figure 2

Table 1. Summary statistics.

Figure 3

Figure 3. Histogram and kernel density: Entering year of first job and becoming an entrepreneur. Panel A depicts the histogram and kernel density of the entering year of the first job. Panel B displays the histogram and kernel density of the entering year as an entrepreneur. The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.Source: CSRP (Lu et al. 2019).

Figure 4

Figure 4. Graphical evidence: The impact on the person's attributes. This plot provides the regression discontinuity plot based on binned scatterplots after absorbing provincial and cohort fixed effects. The outcome variable of interests from Panels A–C: the share of a college degree, the share of party membership, and the share of state sector experience by the entrepreneurs. The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.Source: CSRP (Lu et al. 2019).

Figure 5

Figure 5. Graphical evidence: The impact on father's attributes. This plot provides the regression discontinuity plot based on scatterbins, absorbing provincial and cohort fixed effects. The outcome variable of interests from Panels D–F: the share of a college degree, the share of party membership, and the share of state sector experience by the entrepreneurs by the entrepreneur's father. The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.Source: CSRP (Lu et al. 2019).

Figure 6

Figure 6. Graphical evidence: Other covariates. Panel A and panel B provide binned scatterplots of the age of the entrepreneur and gender composition (male = 1). The red vertical line denotes the year 1992, when Deng Xiaoping made his Southern Talks.Source: CSRP (Lu et al. 2019).

Figure 7

Table 2. The impact of the Southern Talks on the social composition of super-rich persons.

Figure 8

Table 3. The impact of the Southern Talks on the social composition of parental father of the super-rich persons.

Figure 9

Table 4. Robustness checks: Multiple windows.

Figure 10

Table 5. Robustness checks: Control variables.

Figure 11

Table 6. Further examination of the kink.

Supplementary material: PDF

Xiao et al. supplementary material

Xiao et al. supplementary material

Download Xiao et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 980.7 KB