Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T17:43:41.876Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Firms' Choice of Regulatory Instruments to Reduce Pollution: A Transaction Cost Approach

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2017

Magali Delmas
Affiliation:
University of California, Santa Barbara
Alfred Marcus
Affiliation:
University of Minnesota Carlson School of Management

Abstract

This paper compares the economic efficiency of firm-agency governance structures for pollution reduction using transaction costs economics. Two governance structures are analyzed with the transaction costs approach: command and control regulation (CCR) and negotiated agreements (NAs). We propose that the choice of governance structure depends on the strategies firms pursue given the attributes of their transactions and their market opportunities. The application of transaction cost economics analysis leads to different choices of regulatory instruments. Firms in more mature, stable industries are likely to choose command and control, while firms in new, dynamic sectors are more likely to opt for negotiated agreements. Frequency of transactions is a key factor in firm choice.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © V.K. Aggarwal 2004 and published under exclusive license to Cambridge University Press 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anderson, C. L. and Kagan, R. A. 2000. Adversarial legalism and transaction costs: The industrial-flight hypothesis revisited. International Review of Law & Economics 20(1): 119.Google Scholar
Barth, R., and Dette, B. 2001. The integration of Voluntary Agreements into existing legal systems. In Higley, C. J., and Lévêque, F. (Eds.), Environmental Voluntary Approaches: Research insights for policy-makers: 1431. Milan, Italy: Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei.Google Scholar
Börkey, P., and Lévêque, F. 1998. Voluntary approaches for environmental protection in the European Union, OECD, ENV/EPOC/GEEI(98)29/FINAL: 133. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development.Google Scholar
Boyd, J., Krupnik, A. J., and Mazurek, J. 1998. Intel's XL permit: a framework for evaluation, Discussion Paper 98–11. Washington: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Coase, R. 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3 (October): 144.Google Scholar
Delmas, M., and Heiman, B. 2001. Government credible commitment in the French and American nuclear industry. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 20(3): 433456.Google Scholar
Delmas, M., and Mazurek, J. 2004. A transaction cost perspective on Negotiated Agreements: The case of the U.S. EPA XL Program. In Baranzini, A., Thalmann, and P. (Eds.), Voluntary approaches to climate protection. An Economic assessment of private-public partnerships. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar publishing.Google Scholar
Delmas, M., and Terlaak, A. 2002. Regulatory commitment to Negotiated Agreements: evidence from the United States, Germany, the Netherlands and France. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis, 4: 529.Google Scholar
EEA. 1997. Environmental Agreements, Environmental Issues Series, 3. Copenhagen: European Environmental Agency.Google Scholar
Fiorino, D. J. 1995. Making environmental policy. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Gunningham, N., Grabosky, P., and Sinclair, D. 1998. Smart regulation: designing environmental policy. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Henisz, W. J. 2000. The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics and Politics, 12(1): 131.Google Scholar
Higley, C. J., Convery, F., and Lévêque, F. 2001. Voluntary Approaches: an introduction. In Higley, C. J., and Lévêque, F. (Eds.), Environmental Voluntary Approaches: Research Insights for Policy-Makers: 312. Milan, Italy: Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei.Google Scholar
Jaffe, A. B., Peterson, S. R., Portney, P. R., and Stavins, R. N. 1995. Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing: What does the evidence tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 33(1): 132163.Google Scholar
Levy, B., and Spiller, P. 1994. The institutional foundations of regulatory commitment: a comparative analysis of telecommunications regulation. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 10(2): 201246.Google Scholar
Lyon, T. P. and Maxwell, J. W. 2002. Self-regulation, taxation and public voluntary agreements. Journal of Public Economics. Google Scholar
Marcus, A. A. 1980. Promise and performance: choosing and implementing an environmental policy. Westport, Ct: Greenwood Press.Google Scholar
Marcus, A. A. 1984. The adversary economy: business responses to changing government requirements. Westport, Ct: Quorum Books.Google Scholar
Marcus, A. A., Geffen, D. A., and Sexton, K. 2002. Reinventing environmental regulation: lessons from Project XL. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Merck. 1995. Initial XL proposal: http://www.epa.gov/projectxl/merck/.Google Scholar
Michelman, F. I. 1967. Property utility, and fairness: comments on the ethical foundations of “just compensation” law. Harvard Law Review, 80(6): 11651258.Google Scholar
Mitnick, B. (ed.) 1993 Corporate Political Agency. (Sage) Newbury Park, Ca.Google Scholar
OECD. 1995. Netherlands. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.Google Scholar
Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. (Harvard and Shocken Press) New York.Google Scholar
Portney, P. R., and Stavins, R. N. (Eds.). 2000. Public Policies for Environmental Protection. (Vol. Resources for the Future). Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
Rutledge, G. L. and Vogan, C. R. 1994. Pollution abatement and control expenditures, 1972–1992. Survey of Current Business. May. 74. 3649.Google Scholar
Schultze, C. 1977. The public use of private interest. Washington D.C.: Brookings.Google Scholar
Stavins, R. 1995. Transaction costs and tradeable permits. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 29: 133148.Google Scholar
Vogel, D. 1993. Representing Diffuse Interests in Environmental Policy Making. In Weaver, R. K., Rockman, and B. A. (Eds.), Do institutions matter?: government capabilities in the United States and abroad. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Wallace, D. 1995. Environmental Policy and Industrial Innovation, Strategies in Europe, the US and Japan. London: Earthscan Publications Ltd.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. 1995. The economic role of political institutions: market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11(1): 132.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1970. Administrative decision-making and pricing: Externality and compensation analysis applied. In Margolis, J. (Ed.), The Analysis of Public Output: 115135.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1984. Credible commitment: further remarks. The American Economic Review, 74: 488490.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1985. Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2): 269296.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1999. Public and private bureaucracies: a transaction cost economics perspective. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15(1): 306342.Google Scholar
Wilson, J. Q. (1989). Bureaucracy: what government agencies do and why they do it. New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar