Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T08:19:58.404Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Theoretical and Empirical Issues in the Comparative Measurement of Union Power and Corporatism

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Extract

What aspects of national trade-union movements systematically affect national policy making and economic performance? While there is general agreement that union density, the proportion of the workforce organized in unions, is an important element of union strength, social scientists are only beginning to identify the other critical elements. That union density is not the whole story can quickly be appreciated by comparing the influence of unions in Britain and Germany. For much of the post-war period, union density has been higher in Britain than Germany, although German unions have sustained at least as important a political and economic role as British unions. An influential theory of group-government relations directed our attention to the degree of hierarchy and monopoly present in an interest structure and to the degree of institutionalized access to policy-making circles, wrapping these characteristics together in the concept of corporatism. Yet there is a developing interest, particularly in the analysis of labour movements, in disaggregating corporatism as part of an effort to understand the specific characteristics that produce political and economic influence.

Type
Notes and Comments
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1996

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Cameron, David R., ‘Social Democracy, Corporatism, Labour Quiescence and the Representation of Economic Interests in Advanced Capitalist Society’, in Goldthorpe, John, ed., Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1984).Google Scholar

2 Golden, Miriam, ‘The Dynamics of Trade Unionism and National Economic Performance’, American Political Science Review, 87 (1993), 439–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Golden, , ‘The Dynamics of Trade Unionism’, p. 451.Google Scholar

4 See, for example, Goldfield, Michael, The Decline of Organized Labor in the United States (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1987)Google Scholar, and Olson, Mancur Jr, The Rise and Decline of Nations (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1982).Google Scholar

5 Galbraith, John K., ‘Countervailing Power’, American Economic Review, No. 2, 44 (1954), 16 at p. 1.Google Scholar

6 Under the ‘remiss’ procedure the Swedish government collects submissions from relevant interests prior to drafting legislation.

7 Cameron, , ‘Social Democracy’, p. 164.Google Scholar

8 Cameron, , ‘Social Democracy’, p. 170.Google Scholar

9 See, in particular, her discussion of ‘coordination problems’ (Golden, , ‘The Dynamics of Trade Unionism’, p. 440).Google Scholar

10 Olson, Mancur Jr, The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971), p. 143Google Scholar; See also Golden, , ‘The Dynamics of Trade Unionism’, p. 440.Google Scholar

11 Note that while Golden re-labels Cameron's index, Cameron refers to it as the ‘organizational unity of labour’, not ‘monopoly’ or ‘concentration’.

12 Cameron, , ‘Social Democracy’, p. 165.Google Scholar

13 Golden, , ‘The Dynamics of Trade Unionism’, p. 443.Google Scholar

14 Europa Year Book 1981, Vol. I (London: Europa Publications Ltd., 1981), p. 661.Google Scholar

15 See Schmitter, Philippe C., ‘Interest Intermediation and Regime Governability in Contemporary Western Europe and North America’, in Berger, Suzanne D., ed., Organizing Interests in Western Europe and North America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981)Google Scholar; and Golden, , ‘The Dynamics of Trade Unionism’.Google Scholar

16 See Golden, , ‘The Dynamics of Trade Unionism’, p. 447, Table 2.Google Scholar

17 Golden says that Switzerland was a consistent outlier in her analyses, and so reports results both for the fourteen cases and with Switzerland omitted: ‘Omitting the Swiss outlier again improves results for monopoly’, p. 447.Google Scholar In replicating the regression analyses of unemployment, inflation and misery on Cameron's measures, Switzerland is most clearly an outlier in the analysis of misery. When omitted, the adjusted r2 for misery improves from 0.31 to 0.54. With the simplified measure, examination of the partial regression plots suggests a linear specification is appropriate, but that the United States is an outlier in the analysis of inflation. Omitting this case, the positive relationship between inflation and number of unions increases in significance, and the adjusted r2 improves to 0.82. Log transformations of the variables also strengthen the positive and significant relationship between inflation and the simplified measure.

18 See Jackman, Robert W., ‘The Politics of Economic Growth in the Industrial Democracies, 1974–1980: Leftist Strength or North Sea Oil?Journal of Politics, 49 (1987), 242–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jackman, , ‘The Politics of Economic Growth, Once Again’, Journal of Politics, 51 (1989), 646–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lange, Peter and Garrett, Geoffrey, ‘The Politics of Growth: Strategic Interaction and Economic Performance in the Advanced Industrial Democracies, 1974–1980’, Journal of Politics, 47 (1985), 792827.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

19 Bain, George S. and Elsheikh, Farouk, Union Growth and the Business Cycle (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1976), p. 85.Google Scholar

20 Goldfield, Michael, The Decline of Organized Labor in the United States (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1987), p. 27.Google Scholar

21 Esping-Andersen, Gosta, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Cambridge: Polity Press, 1990), p. 47.Google Scholar

22 Lewis-Beck, Michael, Applied Regression (Newbury Park, Calif.: Sage, 1980).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 As the decommodification scores are for 1980 I have used Cameron's figures for average density (1965–80) and, as welfare policy is measured at the national level, number of national–not local or provincial–unions for these countries in 1980, using the Europa Year Book 1981. New Zealand is not included in the analysis, since Cameron does not include it.

24 In the analysis of decommodification the relationship appears to be linear, but Australia is an outlier in Model II. Dropping this case from the analysis improves the adjusted r2 from 0.76 to 0.81. Analysing log transformations of the variables produces broadly similar results. Both the number of unions and density variables remain significantly associated with decommodification, the number of unions is still the more important of the two, and the r2 = 0.53.