No CrossRef data available.
Article contents
Myths and fitness interdependence: Beyond coalitional longevity
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 02 January 2025
Abstract
This comment seeks to extend the authors' argument by considering how perceived fitness interdependence is generated in different settings. Based primarily on research from political science, it argues that strategic agents may seek to design myths that emphasize not only the longevity of their coalitions, but also internal features such as material and status equality and institutional impartiality.
- Type
- Open Peer Commentary
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press
References
Barclay, P. (2020). Reciprocity creates a stake in one's partner, or why you should cooperate even when anonymous. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 287, 1–6.Google ScholarPubMed
Bonomi, G., Gennaioli, N., & Tabellini, G. (2021). Identity, beliefs, and political conflict. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 136(4), 2371–2411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, B. (2020). Reciprocity without compliance. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 48(4), 382–421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchak, L. (2017). Taking risks behind the veil of ignorance. Ethics, 127(3), 610–644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Y., & Xin Li, S. (2009). Group identity and social preferences. American Economic Review, 99(1), 431–457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cronk, L., & Atkipis, A. (2018). Identity fusion and fitness interdependence. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 41, e199.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (1998). Reciprocity and economics: The economic implications of Homo Reciprocans. European Economic Review, 42, 845–859.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleurbaey, M. (2010). Assessing risky social situations. Journal of Political Economy, 118(4), 649–680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freitag, M., & Bühlmann, M. (2009). Crafting trust: The role of political institutions in a comparative perspective. Comparative Political Studies, 42(12), 1537–1566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodin, R. E. (2002). Structures of mutual obligation. Journal of Social Policy, 31(4), 579–596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jost, J. T., Baldassarri, D., & Druckman, J. N. (2022). Cognitive-motivational mechanisms of political polarization in social-communicative contexts. Nature Reviews Psychology, 1, 560–576.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kahan, D. M. (2003). The logic of reciprocity: Trust, collective action, and law. Michigan Law Review, 102, 71–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-C. (2008). Reciprocity: An economics of social relations. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, L. (2015). I disrespectfully agree: The differential effects of partisan sorting on social and issue polarization. American Journal of Political Science, 59(1), 128–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mau, S. (2004). Welfare regimes and the norms of social exchange. Current Sociology, 52(1), 53–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mosse, G. L. (1990). Fallen soldiers: Reshaping the memory of the world wars. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2003). Toward a behavioral theory linking trust, reciprocity, and reputation. In Ostrom, E. & Walker, J. (Eds.), Trust and reciprocity: Interdisciplinary lessons from experimental research (pp. 19–79). Russell Sage.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1999). A theory of justice (Rev. ed.). The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, B. (2017). Solidarity, diversity, and the quality of government. In Banting, K. & Kymlicka, W. (Eds.), The strains of commitment: The political sources of solidarity in diverse societies (pp. 300–326). Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, B., & Stolle, D. (2003). Social capital, impartiality, and the welfare state: An institutional approach. In Hooghe, M. & Stolle, D. (Eds.), Generating social capital: Civil society and institutions in comparative perspective (pp. 191–209). Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shayo, M. (2009). A model of social identity with an application to political economy: Nation, class, and redistribution. American Political Science Review, 103(2), 147–174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, P. (2015). How solidarity works for welfare: Subnationalism and social development in India. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, R. M. (2003b). Stories of peoplehood: The politics and morals of political membership. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svallfors, S. (2013). Government quality, egalitarianism, and attitudes to taxes and social spending: A European comparison. European Political Science Review, 5(3), 363–380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tajfel, H., & Turner, J. (1979). An integrative theory of intergroup conflict. In Austin, W. G. & Worchel, S. (Eds.), The social psychology of intergroup relations (pp. 33–47). Brooks Cole.Google Scholar
Target article
“Our roots run deep”: Historical myths as culturally evolved technologies for coalitional recruitment
Related commentaries (25)
A terror management theory perspective on the appeal of historical myths
Adaptive lags, illusions and common interest
Beyond our “ancient roots”: Toward a broader understanding of the motivational power of societal meta-narratives
Collective selfhood as a psychically necessary illusion
Group myths can create shared understanding even if they don't act as superstimuli
Historical myths are believed because audiences are socially motivated
Historical myths as commitment devices
Historical myths define group boundaries: A mathematical sketch and evidence from Ukraine
Historical myths promote cooperation through affective states
Homo historicus: History as psychological science
Limited evidence that fitness interdependence produces historical origin myths
Myth as model: Group-level interpretive frameworks
Mythos in the light of evolution
Myths and fitness interdependence: Beyond coalitional longevity
Myths and prestige in Hindu nationalist politics
Myths of trauma and myths of cooperation: Diverse consequences of history for societal cohesion
Past glories feel good but creative minorities push us forward
The influence of stories including myths of origin
The social cognitive evolution of myths: Collective narratives of shared pasts as markers for coalitions' communicative and cooperative prowess
The social identity approach offers a more parsimonious and complete explanation of historical myths’ function and characteristics
The Trojan horse of historical myths: Emotion-driven narratives as a strategy for coalitional recruitment
Uncertainty reduction as an alternative explanation of historical myths
What about language?
Why some coalitions benefit from historical myths more than others
“We are one people”: Group myths also draw cues from self-concept formation
Author response
Coalitional psychology and the evolution of nationalistic cultures