Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T00:57:55.802Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE VALUE OF COMMUNICATION AND COOPERATION WHEN SERVERS ARE STRATEGIC

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2020

M. FACKRELL
Affiliation:
School of Mathematics and Statistics, The University of Melbourne, Victoria3010, Australia email [email protected], [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]
C. LI
Affiliation:
School of Mathematics and Statistics, The University of Melbourne, Victoria3010, Australia email [email protected], [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]
P. G. TAYLOR
Affiliation:
School of Mathematics and Statistics, The University of Melbourne, Victoria3010, Australia email [email protected], [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]
J. WANG*
Affiliation:
School of Mathematics and Statistics, The University of Melbourne, Victoria3010, Australia email [email protected], [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

In 2015, Guglielmi and Badia discussed optimal strategies in a particular type of service system with two strategic servers. In their setup, each server can be either active or inactive and an active server can be requested to transmit a sequence of packets. The servers have varying probabilities of successfully transmitting when they are active, and both servers receive a unit reward if the sequence of packets is transmitted successfully. Guglielmi and Badia provided an analysis of optimal strategies in four scenarios: where each server does not know the other’s successful transmission probability; one of the two servers is always inactive; each server knows the other’s successful transmission probability and they are willing to cooperate.

Unfortunately, the analysis by Guglielmi and Badia contained some errors. In this paper we correct these errors. We discuss three cases where both servers (I) communicate and cooperate; (II) neither communicate nor cooperate; (III) communicate but do not cooperate. In particular, we obtain the unique Nash equilibrium strategy in Case II through a Bayesian game formulation, and demonstrate that there is a region in the parameter space where there are multiple Nash equilibria in Case III. We also quantify the value of communication or cooperation by comparing the social welfare in the three cases, and propose possible regulations to make the Nash equilibrium strategy the socially optimal strategy for both Cases II and III.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© 2020 Australian Mathematical Society

Footnotes

*

This is a contribution to the series of invited papers by past ANZIAM medallists (Editorial, Issue 52(1)). P. G. Taylor was awarded the 2019 ANZIAM medal

References

Bühler, J. and Wunder, G., “Traffic-aware optimization of heterogeneous access management”, IEEE Trans. Commun. 58 (2010) 17371747; doi:10.1109/tcomm.2010.06.090182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guglielmi, A. V. and Badia, L., “Bayesian game analysis of a queueing system with multiple candidate servers”, in: IEEE 20th Int. Workshop Computer Aided Modelling and Design of Communication Links and Networks (CAMAD) (IEEE, Guildford, UK, 2015) 8590; doi:10.1109/camad.2015.7390486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Han, Z., Niyato, D., Saad, W., Başar, T. and Hjørungnes, A., Game theory in wireless and communication networks: theory, models, and applications (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2012); doi:10.1017/CBO9780511895043.Google Scholar
Hassin, R. and Haviv, M., To queue or not to queue: equilibrium behaviour in queueing systems, Volume 59, Int. Ser. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. (Springer Science & Business Media, New York, 2003); doi:10.1007/978-1-4615-0359-0.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, C., “Bayesian game theory with application to a service industry problem”, Master Thesis, School of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Melbourne, Victoria 3010, Australia, 2017.Google Scholar
Michelusi, N., Michelus, N. and Zorzi, M., “On optimal transmission policies for energy harvesting devices”, in: Information theory and applications workshop (IEEE, San Diego, CA, 2012) 249254; doi:10.1109/ita.2012.6181793.Google Scholar
Naor, P., “The regulation of queue size by levying tolls”, Econometrica 37 (1969) 1524; doi:10.2307/1909200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, M. J. and Rubinstein, A., A course in game theory (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1994); doi:10.2307/136062.Google Scholar
Zorzi, M. and Rao, R. R., “Geographic random forwarding (GeRaF) for ad hoc and sensor networks: energy and latency performance”, IEEE Trans. Mobile Comput. 2 (2003) 349365; doi:10.1109/tmc.2003.1255650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar