Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T08:01:28.818Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Théorie des Jeux et Analyse Historique des Institutions. Les institutions économiques du Moyen Age

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 July 2017

Avner Greif*
Affiliation:
Stanford University

Extract

Les institutions interviennent sur l'efficacité d'une économie puisqu'elles modifient la répartition des ressources et les relations d'échange que les agents ont entre eux. De ce fait, pour examiner leur nature et leurs effets, il n'est pas de meilleur moyen que de tirer parti de la diversité des environnements apparus dans l'histoire.

Une première façon d'étudier les institutions hors-marché (non marketinstitutions) qui ont régi l'échange au cours du temps s'inspire de la théorie néo-classique qui les identifient avec les arrangements contractuels validés par le droit et les considèrent comme des substituts du marché. Une seconde — celle de l'histoire économique néo-institutionnaliste (neo-institutionaléconomie history [NIEH]) — les identifient avec les droits de propriété et les règlements qui ordonnent l'échange. Un point commun à ces deux courants est leur insistance sur le rôle de l'État et de son appareil juridique.

Summary

Summary

Recent development of game theory has enabled expanding the analysis of historical institutions to examine self-enforcing, non-market institutions. This paper provides a brief methodological discussion of Historical Institutional Analysis that utilizes game theory for the study of such institutions. To illustrate the methodology, contributions, and potential benefit of this approach, the paper briefly discusses recent works applying this methodology to the study of institutions during the late medieval period. Particular attention is given to these studies' implications regarding institutional efficiency and path dependence.

Type
L'Historiographie Économique Américaine
Copyright
Copyright © Les Éditions de l’EHESS 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Références Bibliographiques

(Gino), Arias, 1901, I Trattati commerciali délia Repubblica fiorentina, vol. I (Secolo XIII), Florence, Successori le Monnier.Google Scholar
(Paul), Bairoch, (Jean), Batou, (Pierre), Chèvre éds, 1988, The Population of European Cities from 800 to 1850, Genève.Google Scholar
(Sandeep), Baliga, (Polak), Ben, 1995. Banks versus Bonds: A Simple Theory of Comparative Financial Institutions. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper no. 1100. Yale University.Google Scholar
Banerjee, (V. Abhijit), (Timothy), Besley, Guinnane, (Timothy W.), 1994, « Thy Neighbor's Keeper: The Design of a Crédit Coopérative with Theory and a Test », Quarterly Journal of Economies, mai, CIX 491-515.Google Scholar
(Enrico), Bensa, 1925, The Early History of Bills of Lading, Gênes, Stabilimento D'arti Grafiche.Google Scholar
Benson, (Bruce L.), 1989, « The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law », Southern Economie Journal, 55, 3, janvier, pp. 644661.Google Scholar
(B. D.), Bernheim, 1984, « Rationalizable Strategic Behavior », Econometrica, vol. 52, pp. 10071028.Google Scholar
Byrne, (Eugène H.), 1917, « Commercial Contracts of the Genoese in the Syrian Trade of the Twelfth Century », The Quarterly Journal of Economies, 31, pp. 128170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Claude), Cahen, 1990, « Economy, Society, Institutions », The Cambridge History of Islam, Holt, P. M., Lambton, Ann K. S., Lewis, Bernard éds, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
(Rondo), Cameron, 1989, A Concise Economie History of the World, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Cipolla, (Carlo. M.), 1980, Before the Industrial Révolution, New York, Norton.Google Scholar
Coase, (Ronald H.), 1937, « The Nature of the Firm », Economica 4 (n. s.), pp. 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
David, (Paul A.), 1988, « Path-Dependence: Putting the Past into the Future of Economies », Technical report number 533. IMSSS. California, Stanford University.Google Scholar
David, (Paul A.), 1993, « Path Dependence and the Predictability in Dynamic Systems with Local Network Externalities: A Paradigm for Historical Economies », Technology and the Wealth of Nations, Freeman, C., Foray, D. éds, Londres, Pinter Publishers.Google Scholar
David, (Paul A.), 1994, « Why Are Institutions the “ Carriers of History ” ? Path-Dependence and the Evolution of Conventions, Organizations and Institutions », Structural Change and Economie Dynamics, vol. 5, n° 2, pp. 205220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Lance Edwin), Davis, (Cecil North), Douglass, 1971, Institutional Change and American Economie Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Day, (Gerald W), 1988, Genoa's Response to Byzantium, 1154-1204, Urbana, Ill., University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
De Roover, (R.), 1965, The Organization of Trade. The Cambridge Economie History of Europe, vol. 3, Postan, M. M., Rick, E. E., Miltey, M., Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
(Philippe), Dollinge, 1970, The German Hansa, Stanford, Ca., Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
(Glenn), Ellison, 1993, « Learning, Local Interaction, and Coordination », Econometrica, vol. 61, n° 5, pp. 10471108.Google Scholar
English Historical Documents, 1189-1327, vol. 3, 1975, Harry ROTHWELL éd., Londres, Eyre and Spottiswoode.Google Scholar
Face, (Richard D.), 1958, « Techniques of Business in the Trade Between the Fairs of Champagne and the South of Europe in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries », The Economie History Review, 10, pp. 427438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Drew), Fudenberg, David, (K. Levine), 1991, Self-Confirming Equilibrium. The Department of Economies Working Paper No. 581, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
(David), Galenson, 1981, White Servitude in Colonial America, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gil, (M.), 1983a, « The Jews in Sicily Under the Muslim Rule in the Light of the Geniza Documents », MS Tel Aviv University. Publié en italien, Italia judaica, Rome, Istituto Poligrafico e Zecca dello Stato.Google Scholar
Gil, (M.), 1983b, Palestine During the First Muslim Period (634-1099), vol. 3 (en hébreu et arabe), Tel Aviv, The Ministry of Defence Press and Tel Aviv University Press Google Scholar
Giovanni Scriba, Cartulary di. 1154-1164, Chiaudano, Mario, Moresco, Mattia éds, 1935, S., Turin, Lattes, & Editori, C..Google Scholar
Giovanni di Guiberto, 1200-1211 (Documenti, XVII-XVIII), Hall, M. W., Cole, et Reinert, R. G. éds, Turin : 1939-1940 (GG).Google Scholar
Goitein, (S. D.), 1967, Economie Foundations. A Mediterranean Society, vol. 1, Los Angeles, University of California Press.Google Scholar
Goitein, (S. D.), 1970, « Mediterranean Trade in the Eleventh Century: Some Facts and Problems », dans Cook, M. A. éd., Studies in the Economie History of the Middle East, Londres.Google Scholar
Goitein, (S. D.), 1973, Letters of Médiéval Jewish Traders, Princeton, N. J., Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1989, « Réputation and Coalitions in Médiéval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders », Journal of Economie History, 49, pp. 857882.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1993, « Contract Enforceability and Economie Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition », American Economie Review, vol. 83, n° 3, juin, pp. 525548.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1994a, « Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies », The Journal ofPolitical Economy, vol. 102, n° 5, octobre, pp. 912950.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1994b, « On the Political Foundations of the Late Médiéval Commercial Révolution: Genoa during the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries », The Journal of Economie History, vol. 54, 4, juin, pp. 271287.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1995a, The Institutional Foundations of Genoa's Economie Growth: Selfenforcing Political Relations, Organizational Innovations, and Economie Growth during the Commercial Révolution, Manuscript, Stanford University.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1995b. Markets and Légal Systems: The Development of Markets in Late Médiéval Europe and the Transition From Community Responsibility to an Individual Responsibility Légal Doctrine, Manuscript, Stanford University.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1996a. « Micro Theory and Récent Developments in the Study of Economie Institutions Through Economie History », Advances in Economie Theory, Kreps, David M., Wallis, Kenneth F. éds, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
(Avner), Greif, 1996b, « On the Study of Organizations and Evolving Organizational Forms Through History: Reflection from the Late Médiéval Family Firm », Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 5, n° 2.Google Scholar
(Farley), Grubb, 1994, « The End of European Immigrant Servitude in the United States: An Economie Analysis of Market Collapse, 1772-1835 », Journal of Economie History, 54, décembre, n° 4, pp. 794-824.Google Scholar
Guinnane, (Timothy W.), 1994, « A Failed Institutional Transplant: Raiffeisen's Crédit Coopératives in Ireland, 1894-1914 », Explorations in Economie History, 31, janvier, n° 1, pp. 3861.Google Scholar
Guinnane, (Timothy W.), et. Miller, (Robert I.), 1996, « Bonds without Bondsmen: Tenant- Right in Nineteenth Century Ireland », Journal of Economie History, 56, mars, pp. 113 142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Jacques), Heers, 1977, Parties and Political Life in the Médiéval West, traduit par David Nicholas, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Hoffman, (Philip T.), (Gilles), Postel-Vinay, (Jean-Laurent), Rosenthal, 1994, What do Notariés do ? Overcoming Asymmetric Information in Financial Markets: The Case of 1751 Paris, manuscrit, Center for Advance Studies in the Behavioral Sciences, Stanford.Google Scholar
Houtsma, (M. T.) éd., 1978, Encyclopedia of Islam, 2e édition, Leyde, Netherlands, Brill.Google Scholar
(Diane Owen), Hughes, 1974, « Toward Historical Ethnography: Notarial Records and Family History in The Middle Ages », Historical Methods Newsletter, 7, n° 2, mars, pp. 6171.Google Scholar
Kedar, (Benjamin Z.), 1976, Marchands in Crisis, New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Krueger, (Hilmar C), 1957, « Genoese Marchands, Their Partnerships and Investments, 1155 To 1164 », dans Studi in Onore di Armando Sapori, Milan, Istituto Editoriale Cisalpino.Google Scholar
Krueger, (Hilmar C), 1962, « Genoese Marchands, Their Associations and Investments 1155 to 1230», dans Studi in Onore di Amintore Fanfani, vol. 1, Graffre, D. A. éd., Milan, Multa Paucis.Google Scholar
Lane, (Fredric C), 1973, Venice: A Maritime Republic, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lanfranco, 1202-1226. Cartulary di, Krueger, H. G., Reynolds, R. L., 1952-4 (en latin et italien), Notari Liguri del secolo XII e del XIII, I-III, Gênes.Google Scholar
(Alessandro), Lattes, 1939, Il Diritto Marittimo Privato nelle Carte Liguri dei Scoli XII e XIII, Cité du Vatican.Google Scholar
(Bernard), Lewis, 1991, The Political Language of Islam, Chicago-Londres, The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Lieber, (A. E.), 1968, « Eastern Business Practices and Médiéval Europe Commerce », Economie History Review, 21, pp. 230243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lloyd, (T. H.), 1991, England and the German Hansa, 1157-1611, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Robert Sabatino), Lopez, 1943, « European Marchands in the Médiéval Indies: The Evidence of Commercial Documents », Journal of Economie History, vol. 3, pp. 164184.Google Scholar
(Robert Sabatino), Lopez, 1976, The Commercial Révolution of the Middle Ages, 950-1350, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
(Robert Sabatino), Lopez, Raymond, (I. W.), 1955, Médiéval Trade in the Mediterranean World, New York, Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Mccloskey, (Donald. N.), 1989, « The Open Field of England: Rent, Risk, and the Rate of Interest, 1300-1815 », dans Markets in History, Galenson, David W. éd., Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
(Murad), Michael, 1965, The Archives of Naharay ben Nissim, Businessman and Public Figure in Eleventh-Century Egypt (en hébreu et arabe), Ph. D. dissertation, The Hebrew University, Jérusalem.Google Scholar
Milgrom, (Paul. R.), North, (Douglass C), Weingast, (Barry R.), 1990, « The Rôle of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs », Economies & Politics, vol. 2, pp. 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Ellen Wedemeyer), Moore, 1985, The Fairs of Médiéval England, Toronto, Pontifical Institute of Mediaeval Study.Google Scholar
North, (Douglass C), 1981, Structure and Change in Economie History, New York, Norton.Google Scholar
North, (Douglass C), 1990, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economie Performance, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, (Douglass C), 1991, « Institutions », Journal of Economie Perspectives, 5, pp. 97 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, (Douglass C), Thomas, (R.), 1973, The Rise of the Western World, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearce, (David G.), 1992, « Repeated Games: Coopération and Rationality », Advances in Economie Theory, vol. 1, Laffont, Jean-Jacques éd., Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Postan, (M. M.), 1973, Médiéval Trade and Finance, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Stanley), Reiter, Hughes, (Jonathan), 1981, « A préface on Modeling the Regulated United State Economy », Hofstra Law Review, vol. 9, n° 5.Google Scholar
Reynolds, (Robert L.), 1929, « The Market for Northern Textiles in Genoa 1179-1200 », Revue belge de Philologie et d'Histoire, 8, pp. 831851.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, (Robert L.), 1931, « Genoese Trade in the Late Twelfth Century, Particularly in Cloth from the Fair of Champagne », Journal of Economie and Business History, 3, pp. 362381.Google Scholar
Reynolds, (Robert L.), 1952, « Origins of Modem Business Enterprise », Journal of Economie and Business History, 12, pp. 350365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(Nathan), Rosenberg, Birdzell, (L. E.) Jr., 1986, How the West Grew Rich, New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar
(Jean-Laurent), Rosenthal, 1992, The Fruits of Révolution, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sombart, (W.), 1953, « Médiéval and Modem Commercial Enterprise », dans Enterprise and Secular Change,Lane, F. C. et Riemersa, J. C. éds, Homewood, Ill., Irwin.Google Scholar
Stillman, (N. A.), 1970, East-West Relations in the Islamic Mediterranean in the Early Eleventh Century, Ph. D. diss. The University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
(Giovanni), Tabacco, 1989, The Struggle for Power in Médiéval Italy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
(Vito), Vitale, 1951, Il Comune del Podestà a Genova, Milan, Ricciardi.Google Scholar
Vitale, (V.), 1955, Breviario délia Storia di Genova, Genève, Società Ligure di Storia Patria.Google Scholar
(Cornélius), Walford, 1883, Fairs. Past and Présent, 1968, reprint, New York, Augustus M. Kelley Publishers.Google Scholar
Weiner, (A.), 1932, « The Hansa », The Cambridge Médiéval History, vol. VII, Tanner, J. R., Previté-orton, C. W., et Brooke, Z. N. éds, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp. 216269.Google Scholar
Weingast, (R. Barry), 1995, Rational Choice Perspectives on Institutions. Working Paper. The Hoover Institute. Stanford.Google Scholar