Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T22:59:32.693Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Was Weber Right? The Role of Urban Autonomy in Europe's Rise

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2014

DAVID STASAVAGE*
Affiliation:
New York University
*
David Stasavage is Professor at New York University, Department of Politics, 19 W. 4th Street, New York, NY 10012 ([email protected])

Abstract

Do strong property rights institutions always help, or might they sometimes actually hinder development? Since Max Weber and before, scholars have claimed that the presence of politically autonomous cities, controlled by merchant oligarchies guaranteeing property rights, helped lead to Europe's rise. Yet others suggest that autonomous cities were a hindrance to growth because rule by merchant guilds resulted in restrictions that stifled innovation and trade. I present new evidence and a new interpretation that reconcile the two views of city autonomy. I show that politically autonomous cities initially had higher population growth rates than nonautonomous cities, but over time this situation reversed itself. My evidence also suggests why autonomous cities eventually disappeared as a form of political organization. Instead of military weakness, it may have been their political institutions that condemned them to become obsolete.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramson, Scott, and Boix, Carles. 2012. “The Roots of the Industrial Revolution: Political Institutions or (Socially Embedded) Know-How?” Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron. 2008. “Oligarchic Versus Democratic Societies.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6: 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James. 2005. “The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth.” American Economic Review 95: 547–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angrist, Joshua, and Pischke, Jorn-Steffen. 2009. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist's Companion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth. 1962. “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention.” In The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Bairoch, Paul, Batou, Jean, and Chevre, Pierre. 1988. Cities and Economic Development: From the Dawn of History to the Present. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bairoch, Paul, Batou, Jean, and Chevre, Pierre. 1988. La Population des Villes Européennes, 800–1850. Geneva: Droz.Google Scholar
Bean, Richard. 1973. “War and the Birth of the Nation State.” Journal of Economic History 33: 203–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blockmans, Wim. 1976. “Le régime représentatif en Flandre dans le Cadre Européen au bas Moyen Age avec un Projet d’Application des Ordinateurs.” In Album Elémer Malyusz, Bruxelles: Editions de la Librairie Encyclepedique.Google Scholar
Blockmans, Wim. 1994. “Voracious States and Obstructing Cities: An Aspect of State Formation in Preindustrial Europe.” In Cities and the Rise of States in Europe: A.D. 1000 to 1800, eds. Tilly, Charles and Blockamns, Wim, Westview Press, Boulder.Google Scholar
Blockmans, Wim. 2010. “Constructing a Sense of Community in Rapidly Growing European Cities in the Eleventh to Thirteenth Centuries.” Historical Research 83: 575–87.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blockmans, Wim, and ’t Hart, Marjolein. 2013. “Power” In The Oxford Handbook of Cities in World History, ed. Clark, Peter. New York: Oxford University Press, 421–37.Google Scholar
Bosker, Maarten, Buringh, Eltjo, and van Zanden, Jan Luiten. 2013. “From Baghdad to London: Unraveling Urban Development in Europe and the Arab World, 800–1800.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, October 2013 95 (4): 1418–37.Google Scholar
Bowsky, William. 1981. A Medieval Commune: Siena Under the Nine, 1287–1355. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cantoni, Davide, and Yuchtman, Noam. 2010. “Medieval Universities, Legal Institutions, and the Commercial Revolution.” Mimeo, Harvard University.Google Scholar
de Lagarde, Georges. 1937. “Individualisme et Corporatisme au Moyen Âge.” In L’Organisation corporative du Moyen Age à la fin de l’Ancien Régime. Louvain: Bibliothèque de l’Université.Google Scholar
DeLong, J. Bradford, and Shleifer, Andre. 1993. “Princes and Merchants: European City Growth Before the Industrial Revolution.” Journal of Law and Economics 36: 671702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Moor, Tine. 2008. “The Silent Revolution: A New Perspective on the Emergence of Commons, Guilds, and Other Forms of Corporate Collective Action in Western Europe.” International Review of Social History 53 (supplement): 179212.Google Scholar
de Vries, Jan. 1984. European Urbanization 1500–1800. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Dincecco, Mark. 2011. Political Transformations and Public Finances: Europe, 1650–1913. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dittmar, Jeremiah. 2011. “Cities, Markets, and Growth: The Emergence of Zipf's Law.” Institute for Advanced Study.Google Scholar
Djankov, Simeon, La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2002. “The Regulation of Entry.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 137.Google Scholar
Elvin, Mark. 1978. “Chinese Cities Since the Sung Dynasty” In Towns in Societies: Essays in Economic History and Historical Sociology, eds. Abrams, P. and Wrigley, E. A. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Stephan. 2000. Freedom and Growth: The Rise of States and Markets in Europe 1300–1750. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Epstein, Stephan. 2008. “Craft Guilds, Apprenticeship and Technological Change in Pre-Industrial Europe” In Guilds, Innovation, and the European Economy, 1400–1800, eds. Epstein, Stephan and Prak, Maarten. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Stephan, and Prak, Maarten. 2008. Guilds, Innovation, and the European Economy, 1400–1800. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gennaioli, Nicola, and Voth, Hans-Joachim. 2012. “State Capacity and Military Conflict.” Bocconi University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, Luigi, Sapienza, Paola, and Zingales, Luigi. 2009. “Long-Term Persistence”, unpublished paper, University of Chicago.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, Luigi, Sapienza, Paola, and Zingales, Luigi. 2013. “Long-Term Persistence.” University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Hicks, John. 1969. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Holmes, Thomas, Levine, David, and Schmitz, James 2012. “Monopoly and the Incentive to Innovate: Wehn Adoption Involves Switchover Disruptions.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 4: 133.Google Scholar
Jacob, Marcus, 2010. “Long Term Persistence: The Free and Imperial City Experience in Germany.”Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2010. The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lexikon des Mittelalters Online. Turnhout, Belgium: Brepols, 2009. Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 1994. “Cardwell's Law and the Political Economy of Technological Progress.” Research Policy 23: 561–74.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 1995. “Urbanization, Technological Progress, and Economic History.”Google Scholar
Nicholas, David. 1971. Town and Countryside: Social, Economic, and Political Tensions in Fourteenth-Century Flanders. Bruges: De Tempel.Google Scholar
North, Douglass, and Thomas, Robert Paul. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass, Wallis, John, and Weingast, Barry. 2009. Violence and Social Orders. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” The Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. 2011. Institutions and European Trade: Merchant Guilds, 1000–1800. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Pesaran, M. H. 2004. “General Diagnostic Tests for Cross Section Dependence in Panels.” Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, 0435, University of Cambridge.Google Scholar
Petit-Dutaillis, Ch. 1947. Les Communes Françaises: Caractères et Évolution des Origines au XVIIIe siècle. Paris: Albin Michel.Google Scholar
Pirenne, Henri. 1915. Belgian Democracy, Its Early History. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Pirenne, Henri. 1925. Medieval Cities: Their Origins and the Revival of Trade. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert. 1993. Making Democracy Work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rokkan, Stein. 1973. “Cities, States, and Nations: A Dimensional Model for the Study of Contrasts in Development.” In Building States and Nations: Models and Data Resources. ed. Stein Rokkan. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Rokkan, Stein. 1975. “Dimensions of State Formation and Nation Building: A Possible Paradigm for Research on Variations Within Europe.” In The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed. Tilly, Charles. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Skinner, Quentin. 1987. “Ambrogio Lorenzetti: The Artist as Political Philosopher.” Proceedings of the British Academy 72: 156.Google Scholar
Société, Jean Bodin. 1954. La Ville: Première Partie Institutions Administratives et Judiciaires. Recueils de la Société Jean Bodin. Brussels: Éditions de la Librairie Encyclo ṕedique.Google Scholar
Société, Jean Bodin. 1955. La Ville: Deuxième Partie: Institutions Economiques et Sociales. Recueils de la Soci été Jean Bodin. Brussels: Éditions de la Librairie Encycloṕ edique.Google Scholar
Spruyt, Hendryk. 1996. The Sovereign States and its Competitors. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2003. Public Debt and the Birth of the Democratic State: France and Great Britain, 1688–1789. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2011. States of Credit: Size, Power, and the Development of European Polities. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1992. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1990. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
van Werveke, Hans. 1963. “The Rise of the Towns.” In The Cambridge Economic History of Europe: Volume III Economic Organization and Policies in the Middle Ages, eds. Postan, E. E. R. M. M. and Miller, Edward. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Verhulst, Adriaan. 1999. The Rise of Cities in North-West Europe. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Weber, Max. [1921] 1958. The City. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.