Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T20:39:40.346Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Pluralism and Social Choice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Nicholas R. Miller*
Affiliation:
University of Maryland, Baltimore County

Abstract

Pluralist political theory identifies certain patterns of political preferences as promoting the “stability” of democratic political systems and others as threatening to such stability. Social choice theory likewise identifies certain patterns of political preferences as leading to “stability” in social choice under majority rule and related collective decision rules, and other patterns as leading to “unstable” social choice. But the preference patterns identified by pluralist theory as promoting stability are essentially those identified by social choice theory as entailing instability. Thus the notions of stability and the implicit normative criteria associated with the two theories are very close to being logically incompatible. This incompatibility suggests that the social choice ideal of collective rationality may not be one that we should endorse. Indeed, the generic instability of the pluralist political process and its consequent collective irrationality may contribute to the stability of pluralist political systems.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1983

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abrams, R. Social homogeneity and political viability. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Public Choice Society, Chicago, 04, 1975.Google Scholar
Abrams, R. The voter's paradox and the homogeneity of individual preference orders. Public Choice, 1976, 26, 1927.Google Scholar
Abrams, R. Foundations of political analysis: An introduction to the theory of collective choice. New York: Columbia University Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. Social choice and individual values. New York: John Wiley, 1951.Google Scholar
Bailey, F. G. Strategems and spoils: A social anthropology of politics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1970.Google Scholar
Balbus, I. D. The concept of interest in pluralist and Marxian analysis. Politics and Society, 1971, 1, 151177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, B. Is democracy special? In Laslett, P. & Fishkin, J. (Eds.), Philosophy, politics, and society, 5th series. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1979, pp. 155196.Google Scholar
Batra, R. N., & Pattanaik, P. K. On some suggestions for having non-binary social choice functions. Theory and Decision, 1972, 3, 111.Google Scholar
Bell, C. E. What happens when majority rule breaks down? Some probability calculations. Public Choice, 1978, 33, 121126.Google Scholar
Bentley, A. F. The process of government. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1908.Google Scholar
Bjurulf, B. H., & Niemi, R. G. Order-of-voting effects. In Holler, M. J. (Ed.), Power, voting, and voting power. Würzburg, West Germany: Physica-Verlag, 1982, pp. 151178.Google Scholar
Black, D. The theory of commmittees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1958.Google Scholar
Brams, S. J. Paradoxes in politics: An introduction to the non-obvious in political science. New York: Free Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Brams, S. J., & Lake, M. Power and satisfaction in a representative democracy. In Ordeshook, P. C. (Ed.), Came theory and political science. New York: New York University Press, 1978.Google Scholar
Burke, E. Reflections on the revolution in France. New York: Library of Liberal Arts, 1955. (Originally published, 1790.)Google Scholar
Burnham, W. D. Critical elections and the mainsprings of American politics. New York: W. W. Norton, 1970.Google Scholar
Chamberlin, J. R. A collective goods model of pluralist political systems. Public Choice, 1978, 33, 97113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, L. Cyclic sets in multidimensional voting models. Journal of Economic Theory, 1979, 20, 112.Google Scholar
Coser, L. The functions of social conflict. New York: Free Press, 1956.Google Scholar
Dahl, R. A. A preface to democratic theory. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956.Google Scholar
Dahl, R. A. Democracy in the United States: Promise and performance (3rd ed.). Chicago: Rand McNally, 1976.Google Scholar
Dahrendorf, R. Class and class conflict in industrial society. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1959.Google Scholar
Downs, A. An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row, 1957.Google Scholar
Easton, D. The political system. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1953.Google Scholar
Farquharson, R. Theory of voting. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. A., McKelvey, R. D., & Packel, E. W. Limiting distributions for continuous state Markov voting models. Social Science Working Paper No. 394, California Institute of Technology, 07, 1981.Google Scholar
Fiorina, M. P., & Plott, C. R. Committee decisions under majority rule: An experimental study. American Political Science Review, 1978, 72, 575598.Google Scholar
Fishburn, P. C. Voter concordance, simple majorities, and group decision methods. Behavioral Science, 1973, 18, 364376.Google Scholar
Fishburn, P. C., & Gehrlein, W. V. Social homogeneity and Condorcet's paradox. Public Choice, 1980, 35, 403419.Google Scholar
Foxcroft, H. C. A character of the trimmer: Being a short life of the first Marquis of Halifax. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1946.Google Scholar
Frohlich, N., & Oppenheimer, J. A. Modern political economy. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1978.Google Scholar
Gorman, M., & Kamien, M. The paradox of voting: Probability calculations. Behavioral Science, 1968, 13, 306316.Google Scholar
Hamada, K. A simple majority rule on the distribution of income. Journal of Economic Theory, 1973, 6, 243264.Google Scholar
Hardin, R. Collective action. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Jamison, D., & Luce, E. Social homogeneity and the probability of intransitive majority rule. Journal of Economic Theory, 1972, 5, 7987.Google Scholar
Kadane, J. B. On division of the question. Public Choice, 1972, 13, 4754.Google Scholar
Kent, F. R. The great game of politics. Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1923.Google Scholar
Key, V. O. Jr. A theory of critical elections. Journal of Politics, 1955, 17, 318.Google Scholar
Koehler, D. H. Vote trading and the voting paradox: A proof of logical equivalence. American Political Science Review, 1975, 69, 954960.Google Scholar
Kornhauser, W. The politics of mass society. New York: Free Press, 1959.Google Scholar
Kramer, G. A. On a class of equilibrium conditions for majority rule. Econometrica, 1973, 41, 285297.Google Scholar
Kramer, G. A. A dynamical model of political equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory, 1977, 16, 310334.Google Scholar
Kuga, K., & Nagatani, H. Voter antagonism and the paradox of voting. Econometrica, 1974, 42, 10451067.Google Scholar
Latham, E. The group basis of politics: Notes for a theory. American Political Science Review, 1952, 46, 376397.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. Consociational democracy. World Politics, 1969, 21, 207225.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. Democracy in plural societies. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Lindblom, C. E. Politics and markets. New York: Basic Books, 1977.Google Scholar
Lipset, S. M. Political man: The social bases of politics. Garden City, N.Y.: Anchor Books, 1963.Google Scholar
Madison, J. Federalist Paper No. 10, 1787.Google Scholar
McConnell, G. Private power and American democracy. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1966.Google Scholar
McFarland, A. S. Power and leadership in pluralist systems. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
MacKay, A. F. Arrow's theorem and the paradox of social choice. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1980.Google Scholar
MacKay, A. F., & Wong, E. Preference anarchy. Theory and Decision, 1979, 11, 457463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory, 1976, 12, 472482.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models. Econometrica, 1979, 47, 10851112.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. Symmetric spatial games without majority rule equilibria. American Political Science Review, 1976, 70, 11721184.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., Ordeshook, P. C, & Winer, M. The competitive solution for n-person games without transferable utility, with an application to committee games. American Political Science Review, 1978, 72, 599615.Google Scholar
Miller, N. R. Logrolling and the Arrow paradox: A note. Public Choice, 1975, 21, 107110.Google Scholar
Miller, N. R. Social preference and game theory: A comment on “The dilemma of a Paretian liberal.” Public Choice, 1977a, 30, 2328.Google Scholar
Miller, N. R. Logrolling, vote trading, and the paradox of voting: A game-theoretical overview. Public Choice, 1977b, 30, 5175.Google Scholar
Miller, N. R. Graph-theoretical approaches to the theory of voting. American Journal of Political Science, 1977c, 21, 769803.Google Scholar
Miller, N. R. A new solution set for tournaments and majority voting: Further graph-theoretical approaches to the theory of voting. American Journal of Political Science, 1980, 24, 6896.Google Scholar
Miller, N. R. Power in game forms. In Holler, M. J. (Ed.), Power, voting, and voting power. Würzburg, West Germany: Physica-Verlag, 1982a, 3351.Google Scholar
Miller, N. R. The complete structure of majority rule on distributive politics. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Public Choice Society, San Antonio, Texas, 03, 1982.Google Scholar
Nelson, W. N. On justifying democracy. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1980.Google Scholar
Niemi, R. G. Majority decision-making with partial unidimensionality. American Political Science Review, 1969, 63, 488497.Google Scholar
Niemi, R. G., & Weisberg, H. F. A mathematical solution for the probability of the paradox of voting. Behavioral Science, 1968, 13, 317323.Google Scholar
Oliver, F. S. The endless adventure. London: Mac-millan, 1930.Google Scholar
Jr.Olson, M. The logic of collective action. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Oppenheimer, J. A. Relating coalitions of minorities to the voters' paradox or putting the fly in the democratic pie. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Southwest Political Science Association, San Antonio, Texas, 0304 1972.Google Scholar
Oppenheimer, J. A. Some implications of “Vote trading and the voting paradox: A proof of logical equivalence”: A comment. American Political Science Review, 1975, 69, 963966.Google Scholar
Ordeshook, P. C. The spatial theory of elections: A review and a critique. In Budge, I., Crewe, I., & Farlie, D. (Eds.), Party identification and beyond: Representations of voting and party competition. London: Wiley, 1976.Google Scholar
Plott, C. R. A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. American Economic Review, 1967, 57, 787806.Google Scholar
Plott, C. R. Path independence, rationality, and social choice. Econometrica, 1973, 41, 10751091.Google Scholar
Plumb, J. H. The origins of political stability: England, 1675–1725. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1967.Google Scholar
Rae, D. An altimeter for Mr. Escher's stairway: A comment on William H. Riker's “Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions.” American Political Science Review, 1980, 74, 451455.Google Scholar
Rae, D., & Taylor, M. The analysts of political cleavages. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1970.Google Scholar
Riker, W. H. Voting and the summation of preferences. American Political Science Review, 1961, 55, 900911.Google Scholar
Riker, W. H. A confrontation between the theory of social choice and the theory of democracy. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York, 09, 1978.Google Scholar
Riker, W. H. Liberalism against populism: A confrontation between the theory of democracy and the theory of social choice. San Francisco: Freeman, 1982.Google Scholar
Riker, W. H., and Brams, S. J. The paradox of vote trading. American Political Science Review, 1973, 67, 12341247.Google Scholar
Riker, W. H., and Ordeshook, P. C. An introduction to positive political theory. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1973.Google Scholar
Ross, E. A. The principles of sociology. New York: Century, 1920.Google Scholar
Savile, G. (First Marquess of Halifax). The character of a trimmer. In Raleigh, W. (Ed.), The complete works of George Savile, First Marquess of Halifax. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1912. (Originally published, 1790.)Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E. E. Party government. New York: Henry Holt, 1942.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E. E. The semisovereign people. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1960.Google Scholar
Schofield, N. Generic instability of voting games. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Public Choice Society, New Orleans, 03, 1978a.Google Scholar
Schofield, N. Instability of simple dynamic games. Review of Economic Studies, 1978b, 45, 575594.Google Scholar
Schofield, N. Instability and development in the political economy. In Ordeshook, P. C. & Shepsle, K. A. (Eds.), Political equilibrium. Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff, 1982.Google Scholar
Schwartz, T. Collective choice, separation of issues and vote trading. American Political Science Review, 1977, 71, 9991010.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. A possibility theorem on majority decisions. Econometrica, 1966, 34, 491499.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. The impossibility of a Paretian liberal. Journal of Political Economy, 1970a, 78, 152157.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. Collective choice and social welfare. San Francisco: Holden-Day, 1970b.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. Social choice theory: A re-examination. Econometrica, 1977, 45, 5388.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science, 1979, 23, 2759.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A., & Weingast, B. R. Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice, 1981, 57, 503519.Google Scholar
Smith, T. V. The legislative way of life. Chicago: University of Chicago Press (Midway Reprint), 1940.Google Scholar
Stevens, D. N., & Foster, J. E. The possibility of democratic pluralism. Economica, 1978, 45, 401406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straffin, P. D., Davis, M. D., & Brams, S. J. Power and satisfaction in an ideologically divided voting body. In Holler, M. J. (Ed.), Power, voting, and voting power. Würzburg, West Germany: Physica-Verlag, 1982.Google Scholar
Trollope, A. Phineas Finn: The Irish member. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1951. (Originally published, 1869.)Google Scholar
Truman, D. B. The governmental process. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1951.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. Why so much stability? Public Choice, 1981, 37, 189202.Google Scholar
Uslaner, E. M., & Davis, J. R. The paradox of vote trading: Effects of decision rules and voting strategies on externalities. American Political Science Review, 1975, 69, 929942.Google Scholar
Vickrey, W. Utility, strategy, and social decision rules. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1960, 74, 507535.Google Scholar
Ward, B. Majority rule and allocation. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1961, 5, 379389.Google Scholar
Ward, B. Majority voting and alternative forms of public enterprise. In Margolis, J. (Ed.), The public economy of urban communities. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 112125.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.