Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T15:13:49.178Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimal Obfuscation: Democracy and Trade Policy Transparency

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 August 2006

DANIEL Y. KONO
Affiliation:
University of California at Davis

Abstract

A growing body of research shows that democracies have more liberal trade policies than do autocracies. I argue, in contrast, that democracy has contradictory effects on different types of trade policies because electoral competition generates more information about some than about others. It generates considerable information about policies whose effects on consumer welfare are easy to explain to voters, but less information about policies whose effects are more complex. By increasing the transparency of some policies relative to others, democracy induces politicians to reduce transparent trade barriers but also to replace them with less transparent ones. I test this hypothesis by examining the impact of democracy on tariffs, “core” nontariff barriers (NTBs) such as quotas, and “quality” NTBs such as product standards in 75 countries in the 1990s. I find that democracy leads to lower tariffs, higher core NTBs, and even higher quality NTBs. I conclude that democracy promotes “optimal obfuscation” that allows politicians to protect their markets while maintaining a veneer of liberalization.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2006 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adsera Alicia, and Carles Boix. 2002. “Trade, Democracy, and the Size of the Public Sector.” International Organization 56 (Spring): 22962.Google Scholar
Baba Stephen Anthony. 1997. “Democracies and Inefficiency.” Economics and Politics 9 (July): 99114.Google Scholar
Baker Andy. 2003. “Why Is Trade Reform so Popular in Latin America? A Consumption-Based Theory of Trade Policy Preferences.” World Politics 55 (April): 42355.Google Scholar
Becker Gary S. 1983. “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics XCVII (August): 371400.Google Scholar
Bliss Harry, and Bruce Russett. 1998. “Democratic Trading Partners: The Liberal Connection, 1962–1989.” The Journal of Politics 60 (November): 112647.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D. Morrow. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Budge Ian, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Judith Bara, and Eric Tanenbaum. 2001. Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945–1998. New York: Oxford University Press. 43 (October): 102850.
Cassing James, Timothy J. McKeown, and Jack Ochs. 1986. “The Political Economy of the Tariff Cycle.” American Political Science Review 80 (September): 84362.Google Scholar
Feenstra Robert C. 2000. World Trade Flows, 1980–1997. CD-ROM. Davis, CA: Institute of Governmental Affairs.
Frankel Jeffrey A., and David Romer. 1999. “Does Trade Cause Growth?American Economic Review 89 (June): 37999.Google Scholar
Frye Timothy, and Edward D. Mansfield. 2004. “Timing Is Everything: Elections and Trade Liberalization in the Postcommunist World.” Comparative Political Studies 37 (May): 37198.Google Scholar
Gawande Kishore, and Wendy L. Hansen. 1999. “Retaliation, Bargaining, and the Pursuit of ‘Free and Fair’ Trade.” International Organization 53 (Winter): 11759.Google Scholar
Gilligan Michael J. 1997. Empowering Exporters: Reciprocity, Delegation, and Collective Action in American Trade Policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Grossman Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1994. “Protection for Sale.” American Economic Review 84 (September): 83350.Google Scholar
Herrman Richard K., Philip E. Tetlock, and Matthew N. Diascro. 2001. “How Americans Think About Trade: Reconciling Conflicts Among Money, Power, and Principles.” International Studies Quarterly 45 (June): 191218.Google Scholar
2005. International Monetary Fund (IMF).Dealing with the Revenue Consequences of Trade Reform.Paper prepared by the Fiscal Affairs Department.
Keele Luke J., and Nathan J. Kelly. 2006. “Dynamic Models for Dynamic Theories: The Ins and Outs of Lagged Dependent Variables.” Political Analysis 14 (Spring): 186205.Google Scholar
Khattry Barsha, and J. Mohan Rao. 2002. “Fiscal Faux Pas?: An Analysis of the Revenue Implications of Trade Liberalization.” World Development 30 (August): 143144.Google Scholar
Lee Jong-Wha, and Phillip Swagel. 1997. “Trade Barriers and Trade Flows Across Countries and Industries.” Review of Economics and Statistics 79 (August): 37282.Google Scholar
Magee Stephen P., William A. Brock, and Leslie Young. 1989. Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory: Political Economy in General Equilibrium. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mansfield Edward D., and Marc L. Busch. 1995. “The Political Economy of Nontariff Barriers: A Cross-National Analysis.” International Organization 49 (Autumn): 72349.Google Scholar
Mansfield Edward D., Helen V. Milner, and Peter Rosendorff. 2000. “Free to Trade: Democracies, Autocracies, and International Trade.” American Political Science Review 94 (June): 30522.Google Scholar
Mansfield Edward D., Helen V. Milner, and Peter Rosendorff. 2002. “Why Democracies Cooperate More: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements.” International Organization 56 (Summer): 477514.Google Scholar
McGillivray Fiona. 1997. “Party Discipline as a Determinant of the Endogenous Formation of Tariffs.” American Journal of Political Science 41 (April): 584607.Google Scholar
Michels Robert. 1915, reprinted 1949. Political Parties: A Sociological Study of the Oligarchical Tendencies of Modern Democracy. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Milner Helen V., and Benjamin Judkins. 2004. “Partisanship, Trade Policy, and Globalization: Is There A Left-Right Divide on Trade Policy?International Studies Quarterly 48 (March): 95120.Google Scholar
Milner Helen V., and Keiko Kubota. 2005. “Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries.” International Organization 59 (Winter): 10744.Google Scholar
Nielson Daniel L. 2003. “Supplying Trade Reform: Political Institutions and Liberalization in Middle-Income Presidential Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (July): 47091.Google Scholar
Plume Janet. 1996. “Trade Pacts Leave a Bitter Taste.Journal of Commerce (February): 7A.Google Scholar
Polachek Solomon W. 1980. “Conflict and Trade.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 24 (March): 5778.Google Scholar
Ray Edward J. 1981. “The Determinants of Tariffs and Nontariff Trade Restrictions in the U.S.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (February): 10521.Google Scholar
Rodriguez Francisco, and Dani Rodrik. 2000. “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000. ed. Ben Bernanke and Kenneth Rogoff. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Rogowski Ronald. 1987. “Trade and the Variety of Democratic Institutions.” International Organization 41 (Spring): 20323.Google Scholar
Rose Andrew K. 2004. “Do WTO Members Have More Liberal Trade Policy?Journal of International Economics 63 (July): 20935.Google Scholar
Rosendorff B. Peter, and James Raymond Vreeland. 2004. “Democracy and Data Dissemination: The Effect of Political Regime on Transparency.Working Paper.
Sachs Jeffrey D., and Andrew Warner. 1995. “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995 (1): 1118.Google Scholar
Todd Chuck. 2004. “Campaign by the Numbers.” The New York Times (3 November): p. A19.Google Scholar
Trefler Daniel. 1993. “Trade Liberalization and the Theory of Endogenous Protection: An Econometric Study of U.S. Import Policy.” The Journal of Political Economy 101 (February): 13860.Google Scholar
1996. The White House. “A National Security Strategy of Engagement and Enlargement.”
Wittman Donald. 1989. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy 97 (December): 1395424.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.