Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T09:32:28.129Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Leading the Party: Coordination, Direction, and Communication

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 November 2007

TORUN DEWAN
Affiliation:
London School of Economics
DAVID P. MYATT
Affiliation:
University of Oxford

Abstract

Party activists face a coordination problem: a critical mass—a barrier to coordination—must advocate a single policy alternative if the party is to succeed. The need for direction is the degree to which the merits of the alternatives respond to the underlying fundamentals of the party's environment. An individual's ability to assess the fundamentals is his sense of direction. These three factors—the barriers to coordination, the need for direction, and an individual's sense of direction—combine to form an index of both the desirability and the feasibility of leadership. We offer insights into Michels' Iron Law: a sovereign party conference gives way to leadership by an individual or oligarchy if and only if the leadership index is sufficiently high. Leadership enhances the clarity of intraparty communication, but weakens the response of policy choices to the party's environment. Our model can also be applied to the coordination problems faced by instrumental voters in plurality-rule elections, and so relates to the psychological effect of Duverger's Law.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2007 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2000. “Why Did the West Extend the Franchise? Democracy, Inequality, and Growth in Historical Perspective.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (November): 116799.Google Scholar
Acemoglu Daron and James A. Robinson. 2001. “A Theory of Political Transitions.” American Economic Review 91 (September): 93863.Google Scholar
Angeletos George-Marios, and Alessandro Pavan. 2004. “Transparency of Information and Coordination in Economies with Investment Complementarities.” American Economic Review: AEA Papers and Proceedings 94 (May): 9198.Google Scholar
Calvert Randall L. 1995. The Rational Choice of Social Institutions: Cooperation, Coordination, and Communication. In Modern Political Economy, ed. Jeffrey S. Banks and Eric A. Hanushek. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Carlsson Hans, and Eric van Damme. 1993. “Global Games and Equilibrium Selection.” Econometrica 61 (September): 9891018.Google Scholar
Chamberlain Gary, and Michael Rothschild. 1981. “A Note on the Probability of Casting a Decisive Vote.” Journal of Economic Theory 25 (August): 15262.Google Scholar
Cox Gary W. 1994. “Strategic Voting Equilibria under the Single Nontransferable Vote.” American Political Science Review 88 (September): 60821.Google Scholar
Cox Gary W. 1997. Making Votes Count. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dewan Torun, and David P. Myatt. 2007. “The Qualities of Leadership: Direction, Communication, and Obfuscation.” Oxford University Economics Discussion Paper no. 311.
Feddersen Timothy J. 1992. “A Voting Model Implying Duverger's Law and Positive Turnout.” American Journal of Political Science 36 (November): 93862.Google Scholar
Feddersen Timothy J., and Wolfgang Pesendorfer. 1996. “The Swing Voter's Curse.” American Economic Review 86 (June): 40824.Google Scholar
Feddersen Timothy J., and Wolfgang Pesendorfer. 1997. “Voting Behavior and Information Aggregation in Elections with Private Information.” Econometrica 65 (September): 102958.Google Scholar
Feddersen Timothy J., and Wolfgang Pesendorfer. 1998. “Convicting the Innocent: The Inferiority of Unanimous Jury Verdicts under Strategic Voting.” American Political Science Review 92 (March): 2335.Google Scholar
Fiorina Morris P., and Kenneth A. Shepsle. 1989. Formal Theories of Leadership: Agents, Agenda-Setters, and Entrepeneurs. In Leadership and Politics, ed. Bryan D. Jones. Lawrence: University Press Kansas, pp. 1741.
Fisher Stephen D. 2004. “Definition and Measurement of Tactical Voting: The Role of Rational Choice.” British Journal of Political Science 34 (January): 15266.Google Scholar
Goldstein Itay, and Ady Pauzner. 2005. “Demand-Deposit Contracts and the Probability of Bank Runs.” Journal of Finance 60 (June): 1293327.Google Scholar
Hamilton Alexander, James Madison, and John Jay. 1788. he Federalist: A Collection of Essays, Written in Favour of the New Constitution, as Agreed by the Federal Convention, September 17, 1787, New York: J. and A. McLean.
Hands Gordon. 1971. “Robert Michels and the Study of Political Parties.” British Journal of Political Science 1 (April): 15572.Google Scholar
Koelble Thomas A. 1996. “Economic Theories of Organization and the Politics of Institutional Design in Political Parties.” Party Politics 2 (March): 25163.Google Scholar
Levi Margaret. 2006. “Why We Need a New Theory of Government.” Perspectives on Politics 4 (March): 519.Google Scholar
Lupia Arthur, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 2000. “Representation or Abdication? How Citizens Use Information to Help Delegation Succeed.” European Journal of Political Research 37 (May): 291307.Google Scholar
McKenzie Robert T. 1963. British Political Parties: The Distribution of Power within the Conservative and Labour Parties (1955). London: Heinemann.
Michels Robert. 1915. Political Parties: A Sociological Study of the Oligarchical Tendencies of Modern Democracy. Kitchener, Ontario: Batoche Books. 2001 edition translated by Eden and Cedar Paul and available from http://onlinebooks.library.upenn.edu/.
Morris Stephen, and Hyun S. Shin. 1998. “Unique Equilibrium in a Model of Self-Fulfilling Currency Attacks.” American Economic Review 88 (June): 58797.Google Scholar
Morris Stephen, and Hyun S. Shin. 2002. “Social Value of Public Information.” American Economic Review 92 (December): 152134.Google Scholar
Morris Stephen, and Hyun S. Shin. 2003. Global Games: Theory and Applications. In Advances in Economics and Econometrics, the Eighth World Congress, ed. M. Dewatripont, L. Hansen and S. Turnovsky. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Morris Stephen, and Hyun S. Shin. 2004. “Coordination Risk and the Price of Debt.” European Economic Review 48 (February): 13353.Google Scholar
Morris Stephen, Hyun S. Shin, and Hui Tong. 2006. “Social Value of Public Information: Morris and Shin (2002) is Actually Pro-Transparency, not Con: Reply.” American Economic Review 96 (March): 45355.Google Scholar
Myatt David P. 2007. “On the Theory of Strategic Voting.” Review of Economic Studies 74 (January): 25581.Google Scholar
Myerson Roger B. 2004. “Justice, Institutions, and Multiple Equilibria.” Chicago Journal of International Law 5 (Summer): 91107.Google Scholar
Myerson Roger B., and Robert J. Weber. 1993. “A Theory of Voting Equilibria.” American Political Science Review 87 (March): 102114.Google Scholar
Olson Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Palfrey Thomas R. 1989. A Mathematical Proof of Duverger's Law. In Models of Strategic Choice in Politics, ed. Peter C. Ordeshook. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 6992.
Schelling Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Svensson Lars E. O. 2006. “Social Value of Public Information: Comment: Morris and Shin (2002) is Actually Pro-Transparency, not Con.” American Economic Review 96 (March): 44852.Google Scholar
Weingast Barry R. 1997. “The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law.” American Political Science Review 91 (June): 24563.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.