Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-03T00:44:25.806Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

I Don’t Know

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2020

MATTHEW BACKUS*
Affiliation:
Columbia University
ANDREW T. LITTLE*
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley
*
Matthew Backus, Philip H. Geier Jr Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Columbia University, NBER, and CEPR, [email protected]
Andrew T. Little, Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, University of California, Berkeley, [email protected]

Abstract

Political decision makers make choices in a complex and uncertain world, where even the most qualified experts may not know what policies will succeed. Worse, if these experts care about their reputation for competence, they may be averse to admitting what they don’t know. We model the strategic communication of uncertainty, allowing for the salient reality that sometimes the effects of proposed policies are impossible to know. Our model highlights the challenge of getting experts to admit uncertainty, even when it is possible to check predictive success. Moreover, we identify a novel solution: checking features of the question that only good experts will infer—in particular, whether the effect of policies is knowable—can induce uninformed experts do say “I Don’t Know.”

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Thanks to Charles Angelucci, Jonathan Bendor, Sylvain Chassang, Wouter Dessein, Sean Gailmard, James Hollyer, Ryan Hübert, Navin Kartik, Greg Martin, Mallesh Pai, Matthew Mitchell Andrea Prat, Michael Raith, Daniel Rappaport, Maher Said, Jim Snyder, Joel Sobel, Philipp Strack, and audiences at MPSA 2015, EARIE 2017, The 28th International Game Theory Conference, QPEC 2017, Petralia Workshop 2017, SAET 2017, ESSET 2018, Columbia, Harvard, the Higher School of Economics, the University of Hong Kong, Peking University, and Stanford for thoughtful comments and suggestions. We thank Jett Pettus, Alphonse Simon, and Brenden Eum for their excellent research assistance. All remaining errors are our own.

References

Ashworth, Scott. 2012. “Electoral Accountability: Recent Theoretical and Empirical Work.” Annual Review of Political Science 15: 183201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, David. 1990. Information Transmission in Debate. American Journal of Political Science 34 (1): 124152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey S . 1990. “A Model of Electoral Competition with Incomplete Information.” Journal of Economic Theory 50 (2): 309325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergemann, Dirk, and Hege, Ulrich. 2005. “The Financing of Innovation: Learning and Stopping.” RAND Journal of Economics 36 (4): 719752.Google Scholar
Bergemann, Dirk, and Hörner, Johannes. 2010. “Should Auctions Be Transparent?” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhaskar, V., Mailath, George J., and Morris, Stephen. 2013. “A Foundation for Markov Equilibria in Sequential Games with Finite Social Memory.” Review of Economic Studies 80 (3): 925948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callander, Steven. 2011. “Searching for Good Policies.” American Political Science Review 105 (4): 643662.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1985. The Value of Biased Information: A Rational Choice Model of Political Advice.” The Journal of Politics 47 (2): 530555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Herron, Michael C., and Shotts, Kenneth W.. 2001. Leadership and Pandering: A theory of Executive Policymaking.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (3): 532550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cho, In-Koo, and Kreps, David M.. 1987. “Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (2): 179221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, Vincent P., and Sobel, Joel. 1982. “Strategic Information Transmission.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 50 (6): 14311451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deb, Rahul, Pai, Mallesh, and Said, Maher. 2018. “Evaluating Strategic Forecasters.” American Economic Review 8 (10): 30573103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dessein, Wouter. 2002. “Authority and Communication in Organizations.” The Review of Economic Studies 69 (4): 811838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dye, Ronald A . 1985. “Disclosure of Nonproprietary Information.” Journal of Accounting Research 23 (1): 123145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ericson, Richard, and Pakes, Ariel. 1995. “Markov-perfect Industry Dynamics: A Framework for Empirical Work.” Review of Economic Studies 62 (1): 5382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D . 1999. “Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance.” In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, eds. Przeworski, A., Stokes, S. C., and Manin, B.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 5597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehrler, Sebastian, and Janas, Moritz. 2019. Delegation to a Group. Unpublished Manuscript.Google Scholar
Fox, Justin, and Shotts, Kenneth W.. 2009. Delegates or Trustees? A Theory of Political Accountability.” The Journal of Politics 71 (4): 12251237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and Tirole, Jean. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Gailmard, Sean, and Patty, John W.. 2012. “Formal Models of Bureaucracy.” Annual Review of Political Science 15: 353377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gailmard, Sean, and Patty, John W.. 2013. “Stovepiping.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 25 (3): 388411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilligan, Thomas W ., and Krehbiel, Keith. 1987. “Collective Decisionmaking and Standing Committees: An Informational Rationale for Restrictive Amendment Procedures.” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 3 (2): 287335.Google Scholar
Hacking, Ian. 1975. The Emergence of Probability: A Philosophical Study of Early Ideas about Probability Induction and Statistical Inference. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C . 1973. “Games with Randomly Disturbed Payoffs: A New Rationale for Mixed-strategy.” International Journal of Game Theory 2 (1): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. , and Selten, Reinhard. 1988. A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Holmström, Bengt. 1999. “Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective.” The Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 169182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hübert, Ryan. 2019. “Getting Their Way: Bias and Deference to Trial Courts.” American Journal of Political Science 63 (3): 706718.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jung, Woon-Oh, and Kwon, Young K.. 1988. “Disclosure When the Market is Unsure of the Information Endowment of Managers.” Journal of Accounting Research 26 (1): 146153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kartik, Navin. 2009. “Strategic Communication with Lying Costs.” Review of Economic Studies 76: 13591395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiureghian, Armen Der , and Ditlevsen, Ove. 2009. “Aleatory or Epistemic? Does It Matter?Structural Safety 31: 105112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David M. , and Ramey, Garey. 1987. “Structural Consistency, Consistency, and Sequential Rationality.” Econometrica 55 (6): 13311348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David M. , and Wilson, Robert. 1982. “Sequential Equilibria.” Econometrica 50 (4): 863894.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydd, Andrew. 2003. “Which Side Are You On? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (4): 597611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leaver, Clare. 2009. Bureaucratic Minimal Squawk Behavior: Theory and Evidence from Regulatory Agencies.” American Economic Review 99 (3): 572607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, Andrew T . 2017. “Propaganda and Credulity.” Games and Economic Behavior 102: 224232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manski, Charles F. 2019. Communicating Uncertainty in Policy Analysis. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 116(16):76347641.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Maskin, Eric, and Tirole, Jean. 1988a. “A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly, I: Overview and Quantity Competition with Large Fixed Costs.” Econometrica 56 (3): 549569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maskin, Eric, and Tirole, Jean. 1988b. “A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly, II: Price Competition, Kinked Demand Curves, and Edgeworth Cycles.” Econometrica 56 (3): 5 71599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maskin, Eric, and Tirole, Jean. 2001. “Markov Perfect Equilibrium: 1. Observable Actions.” Journal of Economic Theory 100: 191219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, John F. 1950. “The Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 18 (2): 155162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ottaviani, Marco, and Sørensen, Peter Norman. 2006. “Reputational Cheap Talk. RAND.” Journal of Economics 37 (1).Google Scholar
Patty, John W . 2009. “The Politics of Biased Information.” The Journal of Politics 71 (2): 385397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, Canice, and Stole, Lars. 1996. “Impetuous Youngsters and Jaded Old-timers: Acquiring a Reputation for Learning.” Journal of Political Economy 104 (6): 11051134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rappaport, Daniel. 2015. “Humility in Experts and the Revelation of Uncertainty.” Unpublished Manuscript.Google Scholar
Schnakenberg, Keith E. 2015. “Expert Advice to a Voting Body.” Journal of Economic Theory 160:102113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schnakenberg, Keith E . 2017. “Informational Lobbying and Legislative Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 61 (1): 129145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tadelis, Steven. 2013. Game Theory: An Introduction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Backus and Little supplementary material

Backus and Little supplementary material

Download Backus and Little supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 311.5 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.