Hostname: page-component-cc8bf7c57-j4qg9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-11T22:55:28.989Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Diplomatic Calculus in Anarchy: How Communication Matters

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 May 2010

ROBERT F. TRAGER*
Affiliation:
University of California at Los Angeles
*
Robert F. Trager is Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, University of California at Los Angeles, 4289 Bunche Hall, Box 951472, Los Angeles, CA 90095-1472 ([email protected]).

Abstract

When states come to believe that other states are hostile to their interests, they often reorient their foreign policies by realigning alliance commitments, building arms, striking first, mobilizing troops, or adopting policies to drain the resources of states that menace them. This article presents a crisis bargaining model that allows threatened states a wider array of responses than the choice to back down or not. Two implications are that (1) “cheap talk” diplomatic statements by adversaries can affect perceptions of intentions, and (2) war can occur because resolved states decline to communicate their intentions, even though they could, and even though doing so would avoid a war. The model relates the content and quality of diplomatic signals to the context of prior beliefs about intentions and strategic options. In simulations, this form of diplomatic communication reduces the likelihood of conflict.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Axelrod, R. 1970. Conflict of Interest: A Theory of Divergent Goals with Applications to Politics. Chicago, Markham.Google Scholar
Banks, J. S. 1990. “Equilibrium Behavior in Crisis Bargaining Games.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (3): 599614.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bismarck, O. F. v. 1915. Gedanken und Erinnerungen. Berlin: J. G. Cotta'sche Buchhandlung Nachfolger.Google Scholar
Bratman, M. E. 1999. Intentions, Plans, and Practical Reason. New York: Center for the Study of Language and Inference.Google Scholar
Chen, Y., Kartik, N., and Sobel, J.. 2008. “Selecting Cheap-talk Equilibria.” Econometrica 76 (1): 117–36.Google Scholar
Crawford, V. P., and Sobel, J.. 1982. “Strategic Information Transmission.” Econometrica 50 (6): 1431–51.Google Scholar
Der Derian, J. 1987. On Diplomacy: A Geneology of Western Estrangement. New York: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Farrell, J., and Gibbons, R.. 1989. “Cheap Talk Can Matter in Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Theory 48 (June): 221–37.Google Scholar
Farrell, J., and Rabin, M.. 1996. “Cheap Talk.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 (3): 103–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D. 1994. “Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes.” American Political Science Review 88 (3): 577–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D. 1995. “Rationalist Explanations for War.” International Organization 49 (3): 379414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D. 1997. “Signaling Foreign Policy Interests: Tying Hands versus Sinking Costs.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 41 (1): 6890.Google Scholar
Fearon, J. D. 1998. “Bargaining, Enforcement and International Cooperation.” International Organization 52 (2): 269306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feis, H. 1950. The Road to Pearl Harbor. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Finnemore, M., and Sikkink, K.. 1998. “International Norm Dynamics and Political Change.” International Organization 52 (Autumn): 887917.Google Scholar
Fursenko, A. A., and Naftali, T. J.. 1999. One Hell of a Gamble: Khrushchev, Castro, Kennedy, and the Cuban Missile Crisis, 1958–1964. London: Pimlico.Google Scholar
George, A. L. 1991. Forceful Persuasion: Coercive Diplomacy as an Alternative to War. Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace Press.Google Scholar
Gilligan, T. W., and Krehbiel, K.. 1987. “Collective Decisionmaking and Standing Committees: An Informational Rationale for Restrictive Amendment Procedures.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 3 (2): 345–50.Google Scholar
Guisinger, A., and Smith, A.. 2002. “Honest Threats: The Interaction of Reputation and Political Institutions in International Crises.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (2): 175200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Healy, B., and Stein, A.. 1973. “The Balance of Power in International History: Theory and Reality.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 17 (1): 3361.Google Scholar
Ignatyev, N. 1931. “The Memoirs of Count N. Ignatyev.” Slavonic Review 10: 386407; 627–40.Google Scholar
Jervis, R. 1970. The Logic of Images in International Relations. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Jervis, R. 1976. Perception and Misperception in International Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Jervis, R. 1984. “Deterrence and Perception.” In Strategy and Nuclear Deterrence, ed. Miller, S., Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 5784.Google Scholar
Jervis, R. 2001. “Was the Cold War a Security Dilemma?Journal of Cold War Studies 3 (1): 3660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurizaki, S. 2007. “Efficient Secrecy: Public versus Private Threats in Crisis Diplomacy.” American Political Science Review 101 (3): 543–58.Google Scholar
Kydd, A. 1997. “Game theory and the Spiral Model.” World Politics 49 (3): 371400.Google Scholar
Kydd, A. 2003. “Which Side Are You on? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (4): 597611.Google Scholar
Kydd, A. 2005. Trust and Mistrust in International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
May, E. R., and Zelikow, P. D.. 2002. The Kennedy Tapes: Inside the White House during the Cuban Missile Crisis. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, J. J. 2001. The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Mercer, J. 1996. Reputation and International Politics. New York: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, P. M. 2003. Deterrence Now. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Morrow, J. D. 1989. “Capabilities, Uncertainty, and Resolve: A Limited Information Model of Crisis Bargaining.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (4): 941–72.Google Scholar
Morrow, J. D. 1994. “Alliances, Credibility, and Peacetime Costs.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 38: 270–97.Google Scholar
Mosse, W. 1958. The European Powers and the German Question: 1848–71. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
O'Neill, B. 1999. Honor, Symbols, and War. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, R. 1988. “Nuclear Brinkmanship with Two-Sided Incomplete Information.” American Political Science Review 82 (1): 155–78.Google Scholar
Powell, R. 1990. Nuclear Deterrence Theory: The Problem of Credibility. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, R. 1993. “Guns, Butter and Anarchy.” American Political Science Review 87 (1): 115–32.Google Scholar
Press, D. G. 2005. Calculating Credibility: How Leaders Assess Military Threats. New York: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Ramsay, K. W. 2004. “Politics at the Water's Edge: Crisis Bargaining and Electoral Competition.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 48 (4): 459–86.Google Scholar
Rich, N. 1965. Why the Crimean War? A Cautionary Tale. Hanover, NH: University Press for New England.Google Scholar
Ritter, J. M. 2004. “Silent Partners and Other Essays on Alliance Politics.” Ph.D. diss., Harvard University.Google Scholar
Rupp, G. H. 1941. A Wavering Friendship: Russia and Austria 1876–1878. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Russett, B. M. 1967. “Pearl Harbor: Deterrence Theory and Decision Theory.” Journal of Peace Research 4 (2): 89106.Google Scholar
Saburov, P. A. 1929. The Saburov Memoirs or Bismarck and Russia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sartori, A. E. 2002. “The Might of the Pen: A Reputational Theory of Communication in International Disputes.” International Organization 56 (1): 121–49.Google Scholar
Sartori, A. E. 2005. Deterrence by Diplomacy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. 1966. Arms and Influence. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. 1980. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schultz, K. 1998. “Domestic Opposition and Signaling in International Crises.” American Political Science Review 92 (4):829–44.Google Scholar
Schultz, K. 2001. Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schweinitz, H. L. v. 1927. Denkwuerdigeiten des Botschafters General v. Schweinitz, Vol. 1. Berlin: Reimar Hobbing.Google Scholar
Schweller, R. 1998. Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitler's Strategy of World Conquest. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Schweller, R. L. 1994. “Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State back in.” International Security 19 (1): 72107.Google Scholar
Slanchev, B. L. 2005. “Military Coercion in Interstate Crises.” American Political Science Review 99 (4): 533–47.Google Scholar
Slantchev, B. L. n.d. “Feigning Weakness.” International Organization. Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1998. “International Crises and Domestic Politics.” American Political Science Review 92 (3): 623–38.Google Scholar
Taylor, A. J. P. 1954. The Struggle for Mastery in Europe, 1848–1918. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Trager, R. F. 2007. Diplomatic Calculus in Anarchy: The Construction and Consequences of the Space of Intentions. Ph.D. diss., Columbia University.Google Scholar
Walt, S. M. 1987. The Origins of Alliances. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Waltz, K. N. 1979. Theory of International Politics. New York: McGraw–Hill.Google Scholar
Waltz, K. N. 2003. “Evaluating Theories.” In Realism and the Balancing of Power, eds. Elman, C. and Vasquez, J. A., Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall, 4957.Google Scholar
Wendt, A. 1999. Social Theory of International Politics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.