Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-fscjk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T18:51:16.953Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rulers and the Ruled: Patterned Inequality and the Onset of Mass Political Violence

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 September 2013

Manus I. Midlarsky
Affiliation:
University of Colorado, Boulder

Abstract

The theory of patterned inequality between rulers and ruled provides a valuable analytic approach to the relationship between inequality and political violence. Under conditions of a bifurcated pattern of inequality, the probability of political violence is likely to be greater than under a more generalized inequality typically measured by the Gini index. A strong systematic relationship between patterned inequality in Latin American landholdings and deaths from political violence was discovered using the exponential distribution as a model for the lower portion of the land distribution and the log-exponential for the upper. This degree of association was far stronger than that found between the Gini index of land inequality in Latin America and deaths from political violence. Evidence supporting the theory was also found in an analysis of Middle Eastern landholdings.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1988

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Agricultural Statistics of Ireland, with Detailed Report for the Year 1912. 1913. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office.Google Scholar
Badger, Wade W. 1980. An Entropy-Utility Model for the Size Distribution of Income. In Mathe-matical Models As a Tool for the Social Sciences, ed. West, Bruce J.. New York: Gordon & Breach.Google Scholar
Champernowne, D. G. 1953. A Model of Income Distribution. Economic Journal 63:318–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Converse, Philip E. 1969. Of Time and Partisan Stability. Comparative Political Studies 2:139–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, James C. 1962. Toward a Theory of Revolution. American Sociological Review 27:519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dix, Robert H. 1967. Colombia: The Political Dimensions of Change. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dominguez, Jorge I. 1978. Cuba: Order and Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Belknap.Google Scholar
Feierabend, Ivo K., and Feierabend, Rosalind L.. 1966. Aggressive Behaviors within Polities, 1948–62: A Cross-National Study. Journal of Conflict Resolution 10:249–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finley, Moses I. 1982. Economy and Society in Ancient Greece. Eds. Shaw, Brent D. and Sailer, Richard P.. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Food and Agriculture Organization. 19661970. Report on the 1960 World Census of Agriculture. Vol. 1. Census Results by Countries. Rome: author.Google Scholar
Food and Agriculture Organization. 1981. 1970 World Census of Agriculture: Analysis and International Comparison of the Results. Rome: author.Google Scholar
Foster, George M. 1967. Tzintzuntzan: Mexican Peasants in a Changing World. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Gibbons, Jean D. 1971. Nonparametric Statistical Inference. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Goldstone, Jack A. 1983. Capitalist Origins of the English Revolution: Chasing a Chimera. Theory and Society 12:143–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodell, Grace E. 1981. How the Shah De-Stabilized Himself. Policy Review 16:5572.Google Scholar
Gumbel, Emil J. 1958. Statistics of Extremes. New York: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurr, Ted R. 1968. A Causal Model of Civil Strife: A Comparative Analysis Using New Indices. American Political Science Review 62:1104–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurr, Ted R. 1970. Why Men Rebel. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hamby, Russell R. 1986. Coffee and Conflict in Colombia: Spatial Temporal, and Class Patterns of La Violencia. In Inequality and Contemporary Revolutions, Monograph Series in World Affairs, vol. 22, bk. 2, ed. Midlarsky, Manus I.. Denver: University of Denver.Google Scholar
Hardy, Melissa A. 1979. Economic Growth, Distributional Inequality, and Political Conflict in Industrial Societies. Journal of Political and Military Sociology 7:209–27.Google Scholar
Heath, Dwight B., Erasmus, Charles J., and Buechler, Hans C.. 1969. Land Reform and Social Revolution in Bolivia. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1981. Essays in Trespassing: Economics to Politics and Beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hooglund, Eric J. 1982. Land and Revolution in Iran, 1960–1980. Austin: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, Norman L., and Kotz, Samuel. 1970. Continuous Univariate Distributions, 2 vols. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.Google Scholar
LaFeber, Walter. 1983. Inevitable Revolutions: The United States in Central America. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Lichbach, Mark I., and Gurr, Ted R.. 1981. The Conflict Process: A Formal Model. Journal of Conflict Resolution 25:329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mandelbrot, Benoit. 1960. The Pareto-Lévy Law and the Distribution of Income. International Economic Review 1:79106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mandelbrot, Benoit. 1961. Stable Paretian Random Functions and the Multiplicative Variation of Income. Econometrica 29:517–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Midlarsky, Manus I. 1982. Scarcity and Inequality: Prologue to the Onset of Mass Revolution. Journal of Conflict Resolution 26:338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Midlarsky, Manus I. 1983. The Balance of Power as a “Just” Historical System. Polity 16:181200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Midlarsky, Manus I. N.d. A Distribution of Extreme Inequality with Applications to Conflict Behavior: A Geometric Derivation of the Pareto Distribution. Mathematical Modelling. Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Midlarsky, Manus I., and Roberts, Kenneth. 1985. Class, State, and Revolution in Central America: Nicaragua and El Salvador Compared. Journal of Conflict Resolution 29:163–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muller, Edward N. 1985. Income Inequality, Regime Repressiveness, and Political Violence. American Sociological Review 50:4761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muller, Edward N. 1986. Comment: Income Inequality and Political Violence: The Effect of Individual Cases. American Sociological Review 51:441–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muller, Edward N., and Seligson, Mitchell A.. 1987. Inequality and Insurgency. American Political Science Review 81:425–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, Jack H. 1974. Inequality and Discontent: A Nonlinear Hypothesis. World Politics 26:453–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, Jack H. 1976. Erratum. World Politics 28:315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nejad, Hassan M. 1986. Inequality in an Urban Revolution: The Case of Iran. In Inequality and Contemporary Revolutions, Monograph Series in World Affairs, vol. 22, bk. 2, ed. Midlarsky, Manus I.. Denver: University of Denver.Google Scholar
Oquist, Paul H. 1980. Violence, Conflict, and Politics in Colombia. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Pagels, Heinz R. 1982. The Cosmic Code. New York: Bantam Books.Google Scholar
Parvin, Manoucher. 1973. Economic Determinants of Political Unrest: An Econometric Approach. Journal of Conflict Resolution 17:271–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Returns of Agricultural Produce of Ireland in the Year 1853. 1854. Dublin: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.Google Scholar
Russett, Bruce M. 1964. Inequality and Instability: The Relation of Land Tenure to Politics. World Politics 16:442–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sigelman, Lee, and Simpson, Miles. 1977. A Cross-National Test of the Linkage between Economic Inequality and Political Violence. Journal of Conflict Resolution 21:105–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tanter, Raymond, and Midlarsky, Manus I.. 1967. A Theory of Revolution. Journal of Conflict Resolution 11:264–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, Charles L., and Hudson, Michael C.. 1972. World Handbook of Political and Social Indicators. 2d ed. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, Charles L., and Jodice, David A.. 1983. World Handbook of Political and Social Indicators. 3d ed. 2 vols. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1978. From Mobilization to Revolution. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Tuma, Elias H. 1965. Twenty-Six Centuries of Agrarian Reform: A Comparative Analysis. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weede, Erich. 1981. Income Inequality, Average Income, and Domestic Violence. Journal of Conflict Resolution 25:639–54.Google Scholar
Weede, Erich. 1986. Comment: Income Inequality and Political Violence Reconsidered. American Sociological Review 51:438–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weede, Erich. 1987. Some New Evidence on Correlates of Political Violence: Income Inequality, Regime Repressiveness, and Economic Development. European Sociological Review 3:97108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wesson, Robert G. 1967. The Imperial Order. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, Bruce J. 1985. An Essay on the Importance of Being Nonlinear. New York: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilkie, James W., and Perkal, Adam, eds. 1986. Statistical Abstract of Latin America. Vol. 24 (for 1985). Los Angeles: University of California.Google Scholar
Zaborowski, Wojciech. 1986. Dichotomous Class Images and Worker Radicalism. In Social Stratification in Poland: Eight Empirical Studies, ed. Slomczynski, Kazimierz M. and Krauze, Tadeusz K.. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.