Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-29T21:22:29.387Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Human Capital, Income, and Environmental Quality: A State-Level Analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 September 2016

Stephan J. Goetz
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Kentucky
David L. Debertin
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Kentucky
Angelos Pagoulatos
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Kentucky
Get access

Abstract

An empirical analysis reveals that states with more highly educated populations have better environmental conditions, after controlling for income, population density, and industrial composition. The strategy of raising human capital stocks to maintain or improve environmental quality is proposed as a complement, if not an alternative, to direct government intervention, which consists of command and control, market incentives, and moral suasion. Under this approach, general education becomes the control variable that guides economic behavior in a manner consistent with long-term environmental sustainability.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 1998 Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Becker, Gary S. 1968. “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach.” Journal of Political Economy 76: 109217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1993. “Nobel Lecture: The Economic Way of Looking at Behavior.” Journal of Political Economy 101: 385409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1996. Accounting for Tastes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S., Murphy, Kevin M., and Tamura, Robert. 1990. “Human Capital, Fertility and Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 98: S12S37.Google Scholar
Cameron, S.V., and Heckman, J.J. 1993. “Comment on Trends in College Entry among Whites, Blacks and Hispanics.” In Studies of Supply and Demand in Higher Education, ed. Clotfelter, C.T. and Rothschild, M. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Clark, D.E., and Cosgrove, J.C. 1991. “Amenities Versus Labor Market Opportunities: Choosing the Optimal Distance to Move.” Journal of Regional Science 31(3): 311–28.Google Scholar
Cohn, E., and Hughes, W.W. 1994. “A Benefit-Cost Analysis of Investment in College Education in the United States: 1969–1985.” Economics of Education Review 13: 109–23.Google Scholar
Comes, Richard, and Sandler, Todd. 1980. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fischel, William A. 1979. “Determinants of Voting on Environmental Quality: A Study of New Hampshire Pulp Mill Referendum.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 6(2): 107–18.Google Scholar
Goetz, Stephan J., and Hu, Dayuan. 1996. “Economic Growth and Human Capital Accumulation: Simultaneity and Expanded Convergence Tests.” Economics Letters 5: 355–62.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene, and Krueger, Alan. 1995. “Economic Growth and the Environment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(2): 353–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, Robert W. 1989. “Economic Prescriptions for Environmental Problems: How the Patient Followed the Doctor's Orders.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3: 95114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Bob, and Lee Kerr, Mary. 1991. 1991–1992 Green Index: A State-by-State Guide to the Nation's Environmental Health. Washington, D.C.: Island Press.Google Scholar
Katz, L. 1992. “Recent Developments in Labor Economics.” American Economic Association lecture series entitled Recent Developments in Economics. Presented at the annual American Economic Association meetings. New Orleans, La.Google Scholar
Kenkel, Donald S. 1991. “Health Behavior, Health Knowledge, and Schooling.” Journal of Political Economy 99: 287305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knapp, T.A., and Graves, P.E. 1989. “On the Role of Amenities in Models of Migration and Regional Development.” Journal of Regional Science 29: 7187.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. 1955. “Economic Growth and Income Inequality.” American Economic Review 45: 128.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. 1979. Growth, Population and Income Distribution: Selected Essays. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. 1993. “Making a Miracle.” Econometrica 61: 251–72.Google Scholar
Mincer, Jacob. 1974. Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R., and Phelps, Edmund S. 1966. “Investment in Humans, Technological Diffusion, and Economic Growth.” American Economic Review 56: 6975.Google Scholar
Nerlove, M., Razin, A., Sadka, E., and von Weizsäcker, R.K. 1993. “Comprehensive Income Taxation, Investments in Human and Physical Capital, and Production.” Journal of Public Economics 50: 397–106.Google Scholar
Pigou, Arthur Cecil. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Polachek, Solomon W., and Stanley Siebert, W. 1993. The Economics of Earnings. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98: S71S102.Google Scholar
Rosenzweig, M.R., and Wolpin, K.L. 1988. “Migration Selectivity and the Effects of Public Programs.” Journal of Public Economics 37: 265–89.Google Scholar
Schultz, T.P. 1988. “Heterogeneous Preferences and Migration: Self-Selection, Regional Prices and Programs, and the Behavior of Migrants in Columbia.” Research in Population Economics 6: 163–81.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1964. Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Selden, T.M., and Song, D. 1994. “Environmental Quality and Development: Is There a Kuznets Curve for Air Pollution Emissions?Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 27: 147–62.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., and Becker, Gary S. 1977. “De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum.” American Economic Review 67: 7690.Google Scholar
Tiebout, Charles. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Public Expenditure.” Journal of Political Economy 64: 416–24.Google Scholar