Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T07:15:56.230Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economic Analysis of Supplemental Deductible Coverage as Recommended in the USDA's 2007 Farm Bill Proposal

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 September 2016

Paul D. Mitchell
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics at the University of Wisconsin-Madison in Madison, Wisconsin
Thomas O. Knight
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics at Texas Tech University in Lubbock, Texas

Abstract

A primary change to crop insurance contained in the USDA's Farm Bill proposal is supplemental deductible coverage (SDC). SDC would allow farmers who purchase individual crop insurance coverage to purchase area-wide coverage in the amount of the individual policy deductible. This supplemental area-wide coverage would be similar to the existing Group Risk Plan policy, but with an accelerated indemnity schedule. Analysis indicates that SDC increases farmer certainty equivalents. The largest benefits are realized by farmers with high yield potential in counties with greater systemic risk. In general, optimal individual policy coverage levels modestly decrease when SDC is taken.

Type
Contributed Papers
Copyright
Copyright © 2008 Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Atwood, J., Baquet, A., and Watts, M. 1996. “Income Protection.” Technical report, Montana State University. Submitted to the U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Commercial Agricultural Division (February 16). Available at http://www.rma.usda.gov/pilots/mis[-]cproj/techsum.pdf.Google Scholar
Babcock, B., Hart, C., and Hayes, D. 2004. “Actuarial Fairness of Crop Insurance with Constant Rate Relativities.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(3): 563575.Google Scholar
Babcock, B., and Hennessy, D. 1996. “Input Demand under Yield and Revenue Insurance.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78(2): 416427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carriquiry, M., Babcock, B., and Hart, C. 2005. “Using a Farmer's Beta for Improved Estimation of Actual Production History (APH) Yields.” Working Paper No. 05-WP-387, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, IA. Available at http://www.card.iastate.edu/publications/DBS/PDFFiles/05wp387.pdf.Google Scholar
Chambers, R.G. 1989. “Insurability and Moral Hazard in Agricultural Insurance Markets.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71(3): 604616.Google Scholar
Chavas, J.P. 2004. Risk Analysis in Theory and Practice. New York: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Chavas, J.P., and Holt, M.T. 1996. “Economic Behavior under Uncertainty: A Joint Analysis of Risk Preferences and Technology.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 78(2): 329335.Google Scholar
Coble, K., Heifner, R., and Zuniga, M. 2000. “Implications of Crop Yield and Revenue Insurance for Producer Hedging.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 25(2): 432452.Google Scholar
Coble, K.H., and Knight, T.O. 2002. Crop Insurance as a Tool for Price and Yield Risk Management.” In Just, R.E. and Pope, R.D., eds., A Comprehensive Assessment of the Role of Risk in U.S. Agriculture. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Press.Google Scholar
Coble, K.H., Zuniga, M., and Heifner, R. 2003. “Evaluation of the Interaction of Risk Management Tools for Cotton and Soybeans.” Agricultural Systems 75(2/3): 323340.Google Scholar
Cohen, A., and Einav, L. 2007. “Estimating Risk Preferences from Deductible Choices.” The American Economic Review 97(3): 745788.Google Scholar
Deng, X., Barnett, B., and Vedenov, D. 2007. “Is There a Viable Market for Area-Based Crop Insurance?American Journal of Agricultural Economics 89(2): 508519.Google Scholar
Fackler, P. 1991. “Modeling Interdependence: An Approach to Simulation and Elicitation.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(4): 10911097.Google Scholar
Gollier, C. 2001. The Economics of Risk and Time. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Goodwin, B.K. 1993. “An Empirical Analysis of the Demand for Crop Insurance.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75(2): 425434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodwin, B.K., and Ker, A.P. 2002. “Modeling Price and Yield Risk.” In Just, R.E. and Pope, R.D., eds., A Comprehensive Assessment of the Role of Risk in U.S. Agriculture. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Press.Google Scholar
Greene, W. 2003. Econometric Analysis (5th edition). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Hennessy, D., Babcock, B., and Hayes, D. 1997. “Budgetary and Producer Welfare Effects of Revenue Insurance.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79(3): 10241034.Google Scholar
Hurley, T.M., Mitchell, P.D., and Rice, M.E. 2004. “Risk and the Value of Bt Corn.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(2): 345358.Google Scholar
Just, R., Calvin, L., and Quiggin, J. 1999. “Adverse Selection in U.S. Crop Insurance: Actuarial and Asymmetric Information Incentives.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81(4): 834849.Google Scholar
Martin, S., Barnett, B.J., and Coble, K.H. 2001. “Developing and Pricing a Rainfall Contingent Claims Contract.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 26(1): 261274.Google Scholar
Miranda, M. 1991. “Area-Yield Crop Insurance Reconsidered.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(2): 233242.Google Scholar
Mitchell, P., Gray, M., and Steffey, K. 2004. “A Composed Error Model for Estimating Pest-Damage Functions and the Impact of the Western Corn Rootworm Soybean Variant in Illinois.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(2): 332344.Google Scholar
Ramaswami, B., and Roe, T. 2004. “Aggregation in Area-Yield Crop Insurance: The Linear Additive Model.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(2): 420431.Google Scholar
Richardson, J., and Condra, G. 1981. “Farm Size Evaluation in the El Paso Valley: A Survival/Success Approach.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63(3): 430437.Google Scholar
Schechter, L. 2007. “Risk Aversion and Expected-Utility Theory: A Calibration Exercise.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 35(1): 6776.Google Scholar
Sherrick, B.J., Zanini, F.C., Schnitkey, G.D., and Irwin, S.H. 2004. “Crop Insurance Evaluation under Alternative Yield Distributions.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(2): 406419.Google Scholar
Skees, J.R., Black, J.R., and Barnett, B.J. 1997. “Designing and Rating an Area Yield Crop Insurance Contract.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79(2): 430438.Google Scholar
Turvey, C.G., Weersink, A., and Chiang, S.-H.C. 2006. “Pricing Weather Insurance with a Random Strike Price: The Ontario Ice-Wine Harvest.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88(3): 696709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vedenov, D.V., Epperson, J.E., and Barnett, B.J. 2006. “Designing Catastrophe Bonds to Securitize Systemic Risks in Agriculture: The Case of Georgia Cotton.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 31(2): 318338.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture. 2007a. “USDA 2007 Farm Bill Proposals by Title.” Available at http://www.usda.gov/wps/portal/usdahome?contentidonly=true&contentid=view_proposals.xml (accessed February 14, 2007).Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture. 2007b. “USDA 2007 Farm Bill Proposal: Title X Miscellaneous: Summary of Miscellaneous Title Reform.” Available at http://www.usda.gov/documents/07title10.pdf (accessed February 14, 2007).Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture. 2007c. Risk Management Agency's actuarial documents browser. Available at http://www.rma.usda.gov/tools/adb.html.Google Scholar