Land conservation organizations differ in their priorities, but all are focused on selecting land to preserve for the future. This would be challenging with complete information about land availability, conservation value, and costs, because difficult choices would have to be made regarding which piece of land is more important than another, leaving land not chosen open to development and degradation. The land selection problem is additionally complicated because conservation organizations are often faced with not only this type of informed tradeoff but also a lack of complete information. Imperfect information is especially prevalent in the face of climate change, the effects of which are already being seen and are virtually certain to continue and worsen in the coming decades (IPCC Reference Stocker, Qin, Plattner, Tignor, Allen, Boschung, Nauels, Xia, Bex and Midgley2013). In this paper we study one aspect of the uncertainty faced by conservation organizations, the impact of rising sea-levels.
The Arctic ice sheet is melting, storms are increasing in intensity, and dangerous heat waves are increasing in frequency (Holdren Reference Holdren2010). Some coastal roads will become impassable during storm surges, creating a dangerous emergency response scenario (MMM 2013), property values will be affected (Yohe et al. Reference Yohe, Neumann, Marshall and Ameden1996), and land cover will change (Ando and Mallory Reference Ando and Mallory2012). These and other potential effects add an element of both risk and uncertainty to conservation decisions, with the potential for sea-level rise being especially problematic for conservation organizations focused on coastal conservation.
At the same time, in the past few years there have been multiple attempts to leave climate-change-based decision making out of the policy process. Perhaps the most widely known examples come from North Carolina, where the State Legislature passed a bill limiting the Coastal Resources Commission to the use of linear historical data and restricted use of scenarios with accelerated rates of sea-level rise (Krakauer Reference Krakauer2012, Lee Reference Lee2012). More recent efforts by the current Federal government to reduce funding for climate change and direct research away from climate change furthers this trend of decoupling climate-change-based predictions from the policy process.
This study aims to answer two questions: First, using simulated data and the knapsack optimization method, we show that there are expected benefits from anticipating sea-level rise, and that these benefits are sensitive to changes in budget, risk level, and range of uncertainty. We also show that ignoring likely sea-level rise due to climate change in policy planning can lead to suboptimal outcomes. Second, we look at what an accessible and useful method to incorporate uncertainty over sea-level rise is when deciding which land parcels to conserve. We use a case study with real data on marsh migration from Phippsburg, Maine to develop a decision-making approach that uses readily available software. This method is an inexpensive and relatively simple way to guide decision-makers’ choices. We start the paper with an extensive literature review discussing land conservation under climate change and the current literature related to coastal conservation and sea-level rise.
Motivation and Literature Review
What Does a Conservation Organization Need to Do?
A conservation organization looking toward the future needs to know three basic things: land suitability, land availability, and a land selection strategy. Land suitability must be valued depending on the group's goals, i.e., a group concerned about marsh habitat will be interested in different pieces of land than a group concerned about a specific species that does not use marshes. Climate change directly influences land suitability by altering the habitat through its impacts; for example, in the case of sea-level rise, land may become submerged.
Land availability is simply whether or not the organization can own and use (in a way that is meaningful to them) the land. This is a question of both whether the land is for sale (either outright or via a land trust or similar arrangement) or not, and whether or not the land will be suitable for an acceptable period of time. The land selection process must identify those properties that are suitable and available, and then create a method to determine which ones are actually purchased based on their budget. We focus on this aspect in this study; specifically we discuss site selection methods (also called reserve design or systematic conservation methods) and then discuss the importance of accounting for the uncertainty from climate change.
Land Conservation Methods
Optimal site selection methods or systematic conservation methods focus on identifying optimal conservation areas given ecological criteria and conservation resource constraints (Haight and Snyder Reference Haight, Snyder, Moilanen, Wilson and Possingham2009, Moilanen and Ball Reference Moilanen, Ball, Moilanen, Wilson and Possingham2009). The fundamental models, the set covering and maximal covering formulations introduced by Toregas and ReVelle (Reference Toregas and Revelle1973) and Church and ReVelle (Reference Church and Charles1974), focused purely on the conservation outcomes; Kirkpatrick (Reference Kirkpatrick1983), Underhill (Reference Underhill1994), Camm et al. (Reference Camm, Polasky, Solow and Csuti1996), Possingham, Ball, and Andelman (Reference Possingham, Ball and Andelman2000), Rodrigues and Gaston (Reference Rodrigues and Gaston2002), and Önal (Reference Önal2004) present some of the early examples. Subsequently, multiple studies have shown that there are conservation gains from taking more economically minded approaches to designing reserves and land selection (Ando et al. Reference Ando, Camm, Polasky and Solow1998, Naidoo et al. Reference Naidoo, Balmford, Ferraro, Polasky, Ricketts and Rouget2006, Nelson et al. Reference Nelson, Mendoza, Regetz, Polasky, Tallis, Cameron, Chan, Daily, Goldstein and Kareiva2009, Strange et al. Reference Strange, Thorsen and Bladt2007). More recent studies extended the basic formulations to incorporate various spatial criteria in site selection such as boundary length minimization, clustering, connectedness, compactness, and contiguity (e.g. Williams and ReVelle Reference Williams and ReVelle1996, Reference Williams and ReVelle1998, Cova and Church Reference Cova and Church2000, Williams Reference Williams2002, Fischer and Church Reference Fischer and Church2003, Önal, and Briers Reference Önal and Briers2003, Reference Önal and Briers2006, Cerdeira, Gaston, and Pinto Reference Cerdeira, Gaston and Pinto2005, Önal and Wang Reference Önal and Wang2008, Dissanayake, Önal, and Westervelt Reference Dissanayake, Onal and Westervelt2011, Dissnayake et al. Reference Dissanayake, Önal, Westervelt and Balbach2012, Onal et al. Reference Önal, Wang, Dissanayake and Westervelt2016; see Williams, Revelle, and Levin Reference Williams, ReVelle and Levin2005 and Boyd et al. Reference Boyd, Epanchin-Niell and Siikamäki2015 for an extensive review).
Much of this work assumed a static framework and did not incorporate dynamic aspects such as changing land prices and availability, change in species distributions and land suitability and these dynamic aspects can impact the efficiency of outcomes (Costello and Polasky Reference Costello and Polasky2004, Armsworth et al. Reference Armsworth, Daily, Kareiva and Sanchirico2006). Some recent work has tackled the dynamic land conservation using stochastic dynamic programming (Costello and Polasky Reference Costello and Polasky2004, Strange et al. Reference Strange, Thorsen and Bladt2006, Sabbadin, Spring, and Rabier Reference Sabbadin, Spring and Rabier2007) and integer programming (Snyder, Robert, and ReVelle Reference Snyder, Robert and ReVelle2005, Dissanayake and Onal Reference Dissanayake and Önal2011), constrained Markov decision processes (Newburn, Berck, and Merenlender Reference Newburn, Berck and Merenlender2006), meta-population modeling (Moilanen Reference Moilanen and Cabeza2002). At the same time, these methods do not explicitly model the uncertainty and risk due to climate change.
To deal with the uncertainty of climate change in the land conservation setting, scientists have suggested increasing the number of reserves and the connectivity between them (Ando and Hannah Reference Ando and Hannah2011). Decision makers may also choose to include the possibility of swapping or buying and selling parcels over time rather than being cemented in the choice they make today. Inclusion of the swapping decision has been shown to increase benefits (Strange, Jellesmark Thorsen, and Bladt Reference Strange, Thorsen and Bladt2006) but may not be realistic for all organizations, as many land trusts are set up in perpetuity.
Over the last few years, environmental economists working on conservation have also turned to modern portfolio theory, which is concerned with “how to allocate wealth among alternative assets” to model the conservation under uncertainty (Elton and Gruber Reference Elton and Gruber1997, 1743). Ando and Mallory (Reference Ando and Mallory2012) illustrate how to use modern portfolio theory to handle conservation under the threat of climate change using the case study of conservation in the United States Prairie Pothole Region. According to their results, this uncertainty could be greatly reduced for a small sacrifice in expected returns, when the expected returns are high, highlighting that maximizing returns is not always the best approach when faced with uncertainty. Shah and Ando (Reference Shah and Ando2015) extend this framework to account for downside risk using a case study on bird conservation in the Eastern U.S. In summary, there are growing numbers of studies either using purely mathematical models, simulation studies, or actual data with complex models to identify optimal conservation areas.
Unfortunately, as Prendergast et al. (Reference Prendergast, Quinn and Lawton1999) point out, conservation theorists and practical conservationists are working in different worlds. Very few of the theoretical models being developed in the literature are actually being used in real life, with Australia (whose conservation agencies are developing their own techniques) and California being possible exceptions. There are varieties of reasons for this, from the inability of the algorithms being used to incorporate factors such as translocation and restoration considerations, the sporadic nature of land availability, ownership issues, or impact of climate change (Prendergast, Quinn, and Lawton Reference Prendergast, Quinn and Lawton1999). While these are all issues theoretical models may be able to overcome in the future, another issue may still prevent even the best algorithms from being implemented. In many cases, conservation agents are faced with a difficult judgment call, whether they should spend money on data collection and modeling or on land purchasing. This may be confounded by a lack of knowledge or understanding on the part of the decision maker about the value of systematic conservation models, or the decision maker may simply not have access to the hardware or software necessary to run the algorithms, even where data are available Prendergast, Quinn, and Lawton Reference Prendergast, Quinn and Lawton1999).
Climate Change and Sea Level Rise
By the end of this century, 95 percent of ocean area is expected to be at a higher level than it is today, with approximately 70 percent of global coastlines within 20 percent of the global mean rise (IPCC Reference Stocker, Qin, Plattner, Tignor, Allen, Boschung, Nauels, Xia, Bex and Midgley2013). This means almost no one can expect to gain land from changes in sea level, even if the level of loss is uncertain. However, local variations are expected (Jones Reference Jones2013), a factor that must be kept in mind by local decision makers.
Nicholls, Hoozemans, and Marchand (Reference Nicholls, Hoozemans and Marchand1999) suggested that relative to a scenario without sea-level rise, the numbers of people who will be flooded during storm surges in an average year will be five times higher by the 2080s. In the short term, both lives and material wealth can be protected by moving away from the coast and avoiding areas below current sea-level, and through actions such as building levees. Acting now to limit greenhouse gas emissions may not be enough to prevent the necessity of these changes but would benefit future generations by limiting the level of sea-level rise seen during their lifetimes.
Though there is wide acceptance of climate change, there is uncertainty with regard to the outcomes, especially with regard to rising sea levels (IPCC Reference Stocker, Qin, Plattner, Tignor, Allen, Boschung, Nauels, Xia, Bex and Midgley2013). Part of the uncertainty in sea-level rise predictions arises from the number of factors that influence sea-level rise. According to the IPCC (IPCC Reference Stocker, Qin, Plattner, Tignor, Allen, Boschung, Nauels, Xia, Bex and Midgley2013), glacier mass loss and ocean thermal expansion from warming explain 75 percent of the observed global mean sea level rise since the early 1970s, but the future rate of glacier melt is itself uncertain. Changes in water temperatures and salinity will change currents, which may change water levels as well as affect storm systems, again changing the effects felt from sea-level rise (IPCC Reference Stocker, Qin, Plattner, Tignor, Allen, Boschung, Nauels, Xia, Bex and Midgley2013).
Despite the potential benefits of adaptation steps taken today, it seems as though many individuals are only slowly taking these steps, if at all. The uncertainty inherent in the modeling of sea-level rise and the variability in effects may be part of why agents are not incorporating predictions into their decision-making. Global changes do not give much of an idea how much sea levels will rise in local areas, and the large range of predictions being published is likely to confuse the lay person. As climate change involves “highly unknown and to some extent, inherently random, long-term behavior” (Lontzek and Narita Reference Lontzek and Narita2011), uncertainty and risk become a key component in understanding and formulating responses to rising sea levels. In this study we focus on land conservation, specifically coastal land conservation, and how sea level rise will impact coastal conservation decisions.
We first present a straightforward simulation example to highlight that incorporating climate-change-based sea-level predictions is important and that ignoring the predictions can lead to suboptimal outcomes for conservation organizations. We then follow with a case study from Phippsburg, Maine to highlight how the methods can be applied to guide conservation decision making.
In general, for all conservation site selection applications, organizations must decide how to calculate benefits, depending on what the organization's goals are. A conservation group could consider habitat type or expected species conserved (Polasky et al. Reference Polasky, Camm, Solow, Csuti, White and Ding2000), focus on protecting endangered species (Arthur et al. Reference Arthur, Camm, Haight, Montgomery and Polasky2004), or find an optimal protection level above which gains come from an excessive cost (Strange et al. Reference Strange, Jacobsen, Thorsen and Tarp2007). Depending on risk aversion, the organization may want to maximize the expected benefits, or they may want to aim for the highest likely benefit. These decisions are specific to individual groups and will be strongly influenced by the stakeholders. For example, a progressive private conservation group is expected to make different decisions than a government agency held accountable by a public holding the full spectrum of opinions on conservation. For the purposes of simulation work and the case study presented in this paper, we assume that benefits are directly correlated to the size of the protected land and therefore maximize the amount of conserved land as the objective function.
Simulated Data: The Knapsack Problem
We simulate the decision-making context of two different conservation organizations, one that incorporates predictions of sea-level rise into their decision-making process and one that does not. The simulation demonstrates that expectations of sea-level rise can be effectively incorporated into existing optimization methods and that failure to do so results in suboptimal outcomes. This then motivates the application to Marsh Migration presented in Section 4.
Problem Description
In order to compare the future benefits realized by two different conservation organizations using different selection methods (one that anticipates sea-level rise, the other does not), we use a basic optimization method, the knapsack algorithm, to compare the realized benefit of acquired land, given predicted sea-level rise and the cost of the land. While values of benefits, land costs, and predicted sea-level rise were randomly generated for simulation purposes, the proposed method can be directly applied to real data.
For this simulation and the application (next section), we use the size of the protected wetland area as the benefit or value from conservation. This is a proxy for the ecosystem value of the conserved land and is a simplification, as it ignores multiple benefits that can result from wetlands or the spatial arrangement of wetlands. At the same time, we use the simplest possible approach here to illustrate the conceptual model. If an organization wanted to focus on specific wetland types or locations or ecosystem-based benefits, the decision-making framework can easily be adopted to do so by replacing the size of the land by the desired benefits.
Simulation
We simulate the knapsack method using 50 properties. For each property, land cost and land value were randomly generated using a uniform distribution between 0 and 10. The size or area of the property in the “current” period was generated to be between 1 and 100, and the per-unit value of the property was calculated based on the size and land value. The predicted sea-level rise was between 0 and 100, meaning anywhere between zero to more than complete inundation for any given property could occur. The predicted land value at N years was determined by taking the area of each property remaining after N periods and multiplying by the per-unit value for that property. It is important to note that the definition of value will be specific to the needs of the conservation organization, but for this simulation may be thought of as an ordinal index of usefulness, meaning the higher the number the more advantageous the land. See Table 1 for a complete description of variables used.
For each comparison of expected outcomes for these two conservation organizations, their choices were determined using the following model:
Because one group (Group 1) incorporated expected sea-level rise in the decision-making process, their purchasing decision was based on the expected value for each property after N periods. The other organization (Group 2) did not incorporate expected sea-level rise in the decision-making process, instead choosing to purchase land based on the value in the current time period.
We examine four separate scenarios, as presented in Table 2. The first scenario compares the difference in realized benefits and costs in each of 30 different simulations, in which the values were randomly generated according to Table 2 for each simulation. For the second scenario, the budgets were varied over a range of $25 to $230, all with a sea-level severity between 0 percent and 100 percent. The third scenario compares variations in the mean expected level of severity. The lowest mean was 10 percent, and the highest mean was 90 percent, all with a range of 20 percent and a budget of $150. Fourth, a range of predicted sea-level rise from 10 percent to 50 percent, with mean severity of 50 percent and a budget of $150 was used to explore increasing uncertainty. In all scenarios we compare the total benefits obtained by the myopic agent that ignores sea-level rise and the forward-looking agent that accounts for sea-level rise and the difference between the two outcomes.
The analysis we conduct does not account for the uncertainty of land type change as the value per unit of land remains constant through time. The value of the land may be calculated a number of ways in reality, but here we take it as a given. Finally, we assume a linear landscape that is one unit wide and given that we are considering the size of plots of land as our objective we do not incorporate discounting, rather we compare the available land N periods in the future.Footnote 1 Despite these limitations, the exercise clearly and simply demonstrates the importance of incorporating expectations of sea-level rise while building a decision framework to analyze optimal coastal land conservation.
Comparing Models in Fixed Scenarios
As expected, incorporating the predictions of sea-level rise into the decision-making process resulted in higher realized benefits at a lower cost, on average. Realized benefits when incorporating expectations of sea-level rise were greater than realized benefits when ignoring expectations of sea-level rise in every scenario. With the range in total realized benefits between a maximum of 97 and minimum of 23 between each model, the average difference was 7 (SD 3.79) land units over the thirty scenarios (maximum difference was 15, minimum difference was 1). A one-tail mean sample comparison test indicates the benefits of incorporating sea-level rise are statistical significant at the 10-percent level (p-value = 0.061). This translates to an approximately 11-percent increase in benefits compared to a myopic decision maker that ignores sea-level rise.
The total cost when incorporating expectations of sea-level rise were less than or equal to the total costs when ignoring expectations of sea-level rise in 29 of the 30 simulations. With a maximum cost of 150 (the set budget), and a minimum cost of 90 between the two models, the average difference (calculated as the cost for the model incorporating expectations minus the cost for the model ignoring them) was 26 (SD 17.33) over the 30 scenarios (the maximum difference was 60 and the minimum difference was -8). A one tail, mean sample comparison test indicates savings from incorporating sea-level rise are statistically significant statistical significant at any reasonable level (p-value<0.0000). This translates to an approximately 20-percent decrease in costs compared to a myopic decision maker that ignores sea-level rise.
We then conduct robustness tests of these results by varying the budget constraint, varying the severity of sea-level rise, and varying the risk (the range of possible sea-level rise). The details and the results from these robustness tests are presented in Appendix 1 and summarized in Table 3. The main conclusion from this analysis shows that incorporating sea-level rise into the decision-making framework provides a higher return/benefits compared to a myopic decision maker.
This highlights the inefficiencies (and the dangers) of ignoring sea-level rise predictions as has been proposed by for example by North Carolina. We next present a case study, based on data from Phippsburg, Maine, that demonstrates how to incorporate sea-level rise into coastal conservation planning and also the importance of doing so with regard to maximizing returns.
Application: Wetlands in Phippsburg, Maine
This section uses real data on potential wetland migration and property prices in Phippsburg, Maine to determine the optimal properties to purchase now in order to conserve wetlands in the future. While the specific results may only be useful to those working in Phippsburg, the process used to find the results is easily transferable to other locations and data sets and will be useful for conservation agents in multiple settings.
Why Maine, and Why Wetlands?
Wetlands have recently been recognized as an incredibly valuable biome, both environmentally and economically. Their services include flood protection, maintenance of water quality (which can then be used for drinking water supplies), biodiversity support (which in turn provides recreational fishing and hunting opportunities), and carbon sequestration, making them one of Earth's most productive ecosystems (Heimlich et al. Reference Heimlich, Wiebe, Claassen, Gadsby and House1998, Birol, Karousakis, and Koundouri Reference Birol, Karousakis and Koundouri2006). A study by Moore, Gunn and Troy (Reference Moore, Gunn and Troy2012) placed a value of $1,399/acre/year (a total estimated value of $26,330,579) for wetlands in Maine, excluding nonuse values. Unfortunately, their importance was not always understood, and wetlands have historically been drained or otherwise degraded on a national level (Barbier, Acreman, and Knowler Reference Barbier, Acreman and Knowler1997), making protection of those wetlands remaining especially important.
Recognizing this importance, multiple countries signed on to the Ramsar Convention in 1975, agreeing to include wetland conservation in national planning, among other requirements (Turner Reference Turner1991). As of March 2016 there are 2,231 Ramsar wetland sites covering 2.1 million square kilometers globally. In the United States, the permits to dredge or fill in wetlands required by the Clean Water Act often require “compensatory wetland replacement,” meaning wetlands elsewhere must be restored (Robertson Reference Robertson2006). While wetland conversion is an option to fulfil the requirement, protection and restoration has become the focus of federal wetland policy in an effort to balance the competing public and private interests arising from the public good quality wetlands poses (Heimlich et al. Reference Heimlich, Wiebe, Claassen, Gadsby and House1998). In addition to the national level efforts to protect wetlands coastal states, counties and cities also engage in wetland protection and management.
Maine has a substantial coastal community in terms of population, culture, and livelihoods. Compounding this, Maine is in a region expected to see sea levels rise higher than the global mean (Jones Reference Jones2013), which has been predicted to increase by 0.5 to 1.4 meters above the 1990 level by 2100 (Rahmstorf Reference Rahmstorf2007). The Sea Level Adaptation Working Group has predicted a 2 foot increase by 2100, a level now accepted by the Saco Bay, Maine region in their municipal planning (Sea Level Rise Adaptation Working Group Reference Survey and Commission2011). Given these predictions and as a peninsular, open ocean town, Phippsburg, Maine has a particular need to understand the predictions and act accordingly. However, town meeting minutes show they have only recently begun to purposefully incorporate expectations of sea-level rise into their municipal planning process (Young Reference Young.2012).
4.2. Introduction to the Marsh Migration Project
In line with this focus on protection, in an effort to assist adaptation efforts by coastal communities in Maine, a collaborative effort between the Maine Coastal Program, Maine Department of Inland Fisheries and Wildlife, Maine Geological Survey, Wells National Estuarine Research Reserve, and Maine Coast heritage Trust, with support from a National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) Project of Special Merit grant, was formed and named the Marsh Migration Team .
Six communities in Maine, namely Scarborough, Bath, Topsham, Phippsburg, Georgetown, and Bowdoinham, were selected for the project, which determined where current wetlands could potentially migrate to in each town under 1 foot, 2 foot, 3.3 foot, or 6 foot sea-level rise scenarios. A bathtub model, i.e., using elevation contours, was used to identify suitable areas (MMM 2013).Footnote 2
We use the results of the Marsh Migration Team analysis for Phippsburg (Maine Geological Survey, Department of Agriculture, Conservation and Forestry 2014) for this work. The Phippsburg tax assessor supplied a GIS layer including all of the properties in Phippsburg as of 2011 and a text file including the total assessed value (including land and buildings) and acreage for each parcel for 2011 (Wilson-Hennessey, IFA, CMA, personal communication). Details of the data set up and merging are provided in Appendix 2.
Data
There are currently 35 non-island properties coded as conservation, land trust, or state property, with a total assessed value of $11,013,500, protecting 1,858,969 square meters (approximately 460 acres) of wetlands. These values are used as benchmarks for land area and budget. Property values for lots currently defined as conservation were set to zero, so they were automatically selected by the optimization method if they provided benefit in the future. This means the framework models the decision making of a conservation organization looking to protect additional land, given what is currently protected.
Aggregating the area of potential wetlands by map-lot type provides insights to the type of property these wetlands do or may lay on. The intersection found 3,424,802 square meters (approximately 846 acres) of wetlands currently existing in Phippsburg. Of this area, 54 percent is under conservation, defined as a parcel coded as conservation, land trust, or state land. Future scenarios have significantly fewer potential wetlands, especially under two-foot or three-foot sea-rise levels. Of these areas for potential wetlands, about 1/5th are already under conservation, requiring no further action to protect them. Under the 1 foot sea-level rise scenario 32 percent is “not for sale,” meaning it is on a current cemetery, a private or public road, is currently water, or is coded as unknown. The last type is of some concern for this analysis, as it may be land available for purchase or not (Juanita C. Wilson-Hennessey, IFA, CMA, personal communication). See Figure 1 and Table 4 for further details.
The spatial distribution of property values in Phippsburg is important to understand. As seen in Figure 2, property values tend to be higher on the western and southern sides of the peninsula, as properties are on the open coast. On the eastern side is the Kennebec River, which creates wetlands as well but does not tend to cause property values to increase by as great a degree. This pattern likely explains the results seen in the set-coverage optimizations.
Most of the current conservation land (Conservation, Land Trust, or State Land) has either a current or potential wetland. Figure 3 provides a spatial distribution of these properties.
Simulation Scenarios
Because there may be fewer wetlands in the future, it will be impossible to achieve the same level of protection at any cost. Therefore, in the first model we target conserving approximately 5–20 percent of current coverage under each sea-level-rise scenario. Specifically we find the minimum cost to cover the stated land area. This is the canonical set-covering problem as defined in the reserve design/systematic conservation literature.
In the second model, we find the maximum potential area of wetlands conserved under a range of budgets. This is the canonical maximal-covering problem as defined in the reserve design/systematic conservation literature. For this scenario, following Ando and Mallory (Reference Ando and Mallory2012), we account for different climate scenarios by multiplying the potential area of wetlands by a probability distribution for the four sea-level-rise scenarios analyzed. The probability distributions used were an even distribution (0.25/0.25/0.25/0.25), a .7/.1/.1/.1 distribution, a .1/.1/.7/.1 distribution, and a .4/.4/.1/.1 distribution, where the probabilities correspond to 1-foot, 2-foot, 3.3-foot, and 6-foot rises, respectively.
In both optimization models, the assessed value for each map-lot was used as a proxy for purchasing cost. These values could change with sea-level rise, either positively or negatively, but as the decision framework is intended for an organization making purchases today the analysis does not incorporate changes in future prices of the land. Also for both optimization models, we use the size of the potential wetland area as the benefit of conservation. This is a simplification, and if an organization wanted to focus on specific wetland types or locations or ecosystem based benefits the decision-making framework can easily be adopted to do so by replacing the size by the desired benefits.
Model 1: Set Covering
As is typical in conservation site selection models we see that under every sea-level-rise scenario the costs increase as a function of the conserved area (see Figure 4). In this application the cost increase is exponential, and this may be explained by the limited area of wetlands available and the distribution of property values in Phippsburg. For example, to go from conserving 400,000 square meters (98.8 acres) to 500,000 square meters (123.5 acres) under the 3.3-foot sea-level-rise scenario, the cost increases from $12,470,300 to $47,490,900, while the number of properties selected increases from 109 to 202 (including the 35 properties currently conserved). To allow for the possibility of using the current conservation land to fund the purchase of future conservation land, we include the current value of conservation land in Figure 4. This shows that conservation of more than 500,000 m2 (123.5 acres) in the future is unlikely, with conservation under the 6-foot scenario being the only possible exception.
To explore the hypothesis that the distribution of land prices is driving the exponential cost increases seen in Figure 4, we examine the potentially extreme case of moving from 400,000 square meters of wetlands conserved to 500,000 square meters of wetlands conserved under the 3.3-foot sea-level rise scenario. To do this, the map-lots selected by the optimization algorithm in both cases were mapped using ArcMap and compared. As illustrated in Figure 5, many of the properties selected when covering 500,000 square meters are on the eastern, western, and southern portions of Phippsburg, while the properties selected when covering 400,000 square meters are mainly confined to the eastern portion of Phippsburg. Recall the properties on the southern and western portions of Phippsburg are the most expensive, supporting the hypothesis that this is a driving force in the cost structure seen. Essentially, as the conservation organization increases amount of land being protected, the conservation organization reaches a point where it is being forced to buy almost any property with benefits, regardless of the cost.
Finally, as seen in Figure 6, there are some properties which would be selected for a set level of coverage under both the minimum and maximum levels of sea-level rise. These colors are shown in beige, while parcels selected for only a 1-foot rise or only a 6-foot rise are shown according to the legend. The properties which are selected under more than one scenario may be of increased value to conservation organizations, considering the uncertainty involved in predicting what sea-level-rise scenario to expect, since they are expected to provide coverage no matter what sea-level-rise scenario actually occurs.
Model 2: Maximal Covering
Maximizing the total area conserved, given various probability distributions for the four sea-level-rise scenarios examined, showed decreasing marginal returns to the budget in all cases (Figure 7), as is the standard result for maximal covering problems. This corresponds to the results found in the set-coverage optimization method, which also show decreasing marginal returns. The maximal covering problem highlights that the greatest expected benefits are when the smallest sea-level-rise levels were the most likely, although the differences between each distribution is fairly small.
We map the properties selected by the maximal covering selection under all four of the probability distributions. We use a budget of $250,000 in the presented results. First, in Figure 8, the sites selected under an even distribution (.25/.25/.25/.25) are shown in pink, the sites selected under the .7/.1/.1/.1 distribution are shown in yellow, and the sites selected under both distributions are shown in orange. Second, in Figure 9, the sites selected under the .1/.1/.7/.1 distribution are shown in pink, the .4/.4/.1/.1 distribution is shown in light blue, and the sites selected in both are shown in a deep blue color. By comparing these two maps, it can also be seen that several properties are selected under more than one distribution, again indicating that they may be especially beneficial for conservation organizations to conserve. It is also interesting to note that very few properties were selected along the open coast under any of the scenarios. This supports the hypothesis that the high cost of these properties outweighs any benefits they have.
In summary, we use set covering and maximal covering models to identify the best land to purchase for future wetlands in Phippsburg, Maine, given a range of probabilities of climate outcomes. We then generate specific maps from these results to highlight how conservation organizations can incorporate climate-change-based land-use changes into coastal conservation planning.
Discussion and Conclusion
Current climate models generally predict rising sea levels, although the specific level of the increase in any given location is uncertain (IPCC Reference Stocker, Qin, Plattner, Tignor, Allen, Boschung, Nauels, Xia, Bex and Midgley2013). Not only will sea-level rise continue to occur, it is expected to increase at an increasing rate as we move further into this century. Given this, it seems intuitive that incorporating expectations of sea-level rise into decision making would result in increased benefits; this is evident from the results using simulated data with the knapsack method. Our results highlight the importance of incorporating sea-level rise information in decision making vs. the myopic approach of ignoring predictions, as has been evident in some cases, including with the legislation in North Carolina.
In our simulation analysis, we find conservation agencies are able to increase benefits between 11 percent to almost 30 percent by incorporating sea-level rise into their decision making. The benefits from anticipating sea-level rise are actually greatest with a mid-range budget, when conditions are uncertain, and when the risk is greatest. Arguably, these conditions are the same as those being faced by conservation organizations today. We then present a case study and highlight methods that can be adopted by coastal conservation agencies.
Using Phippsburg, Maine as a case study to select the optimal properties given either a budget and probability distributions of sea-level rise, or a set coverage goal under each sea-level-rise scenario generated results that can help the town and conservation agencies plan their future land purchases. In general, Phippsburg is faced with decreasing marginal returns relative to the size of the conservation budget, a result that is common in many site-selection studies. The properties in Phippsburg, Maine have a positive correlation between property prices and coastal acreage, and this correlation also means fewer wetlands may be conserved if the goal is storm surge protection, necessitating purchasing properties along the open coast.
The method used to analyze Phippsburg highlights one approach that conservation organizations may be able to use to explore what parcels would be optimal to purchase (given their respective goals). With fewer computational requirements than some of the methods currently in the literature, the approach we present is especially appealing, as it can be replicated using free or inexpensive versions of ArcMap or QGIS for the GIS component, and Excel, a standard program that organizations are likely to already have, for the optimization work.
However, the method we used for this study requires detailed data which may be difficult to obtain in some cases. Phippsburg already had tax maps as GIS layers, something many Maine towns have not yet done. The Marsh Migration Team also put considerable work into ground truthing and conducting their analysis of potential wetland migration, supported by grant money. The method used here also partially takes into account the issue of land availability, in that public and private roads, as well as current water bodies, were identified and left out of the analysis. On the other hand, our analysis not only considered all other properties as “for sale,” it considered them as for sale at the assessed value, an unrealistic assumption given some individuals’ reluctance to part with their home, even if they would be compensated above market price. This issue of land availability is something that should be appropriately accounted for in future work.
Overall, our study presents a potential decision-making method for conservation organizations, which may be less computationally demanding and therefore may be more useful for decision makers than methods used in the literature. Sites selected under multiple selection criteria may be of particular interest to conservation organizations. Educational efforts could be streamlined using this method, up to the optimization step, to identify who owns properties that could be converted to wetlands in the future. Finally, the method was successful in generating useful results using real data, showing that it could be used to inform a real decision in a similar setting.
Appendix A – Detailed Simulation Results
Variations in Budget Constraints
The forward-looking model that accounts for sea level rise achieves higher benefits across various amounts of budget. As seen in Appendix Figure 1a, given a budget range between $25 and $230, a model that incorporates expectations of sea-level rise into the decision-making process always results in higher realized benefits. A one-tail, two-sample mean comparison test indicates the benefit of expecting sea-level rise is statistically significant at a less than 1-percent level (p-value = 0.0092).
The exercise also shows where the difference between the two models is greatest. It appears there may be a range of budgets where the benefit of incorporating sea-level rise expectations is greatest, around $100 given the parameters of this model. It also shows a convergence at either end of the budget spectrum where the differences between the two models is small (see Appendix Figure 1b). The decrease of the differences between the two models at low and high budgets is to be expected; when the budget is small, only a small number of parcels can be bought, limiting the difference, and when the budget is large, most of the landscape is purchased again, limiting the differences between the selections.
Variations in Severity of Sea-Level Rise
In Scenario 3 we fix the budget, and vary the mean severity of sea-level rise. We use a budget of $150 and model nine mean severity levels ranging from 10 percent to 90 percent, each with a range of 20 percent as indicated in Appendix Table 1. We find that both organizations have the highest benefits when mean sea-level rise is the smallest (Appendix Figure 2a), an intuitive result, and also that the advantage of the forward looking (over the myopic model) decreases as the severity of sea-level rise approaches complete (100 percent) inundation; see Appendix Figure 2b. A possible reason for this is that at very high levels of sea-level rise, a significant part of the landscape is inundated, accounting for climate change when planning does not result in additional benefits.
The average difference (calculated as the realized benefits for the model incorporating expectations minus the realized benefits for the model ignoring them for each simulation) is nine units (SD 5.89). A one-tail, mean sample comparison test indicates that the additional benefits of incorporating sea-level rise are statistically significant at the 1-percent level (p-value = 0.0015).
Variations in Risk
In the final scenario we vary the range of the severity of sea-level rise (i.e., the risk) around a mean of 50 percent of the land being inundated. At lower ranges, and therefore lower uncertainty, both agents see lower benefits than at higher ranges of uncertainty. This may be because of where the mean level of rise was set; at lower levels of uncertainty, more parcels experience higher levels of flooding because lower severities are not possible. At higher levels of uncertainty, catastrophic levels of flooding are possible, but so is minimal flooding. See Appendix Table 2 for a summary of the results.
At all levels of uncertainty, given a mean severity of 50-percent loss, the agent who expects sea-level rise to occur has a higher level of benefits after N years than the agent who does not. The difference in realized benefits between the two agents increases as the range of sea-level-rise severity increases, so with more uncertainty it becomes advantageous to have incorporated the expectation of sea-level rise into your decision-making process. The average difference (calculated as the realized benefits for the model incorporating expectations minus the realized benefits for the model ignoring them for each simulation) is 15 units (SD 2.64). A one-tail mean sample comparison test indicates that the additional benefits from incorporating sea-level rise are statistically significant at the 1-percent level (p-value = 0.0001).
Appendix B – Setting up the Data
To use assessed property value as a proxy for the purchasing price conservation organizations would be faced with, the area of potential wetlands under each sea-level-rise scenario needed to be associated with a tax-map. To do this, the Google Earth file was first converted to a shapefile using the ArcMap Conversion tool, resulting in a Wetland layer showing where current wetlands are, as well as areas of potential wetlands under the 1-foot, 2-foot, 3.3-foot, and 6-foot scenarios analyzed by the Marsh Migration Team. The ArcMap Projection tool was then used to project both the Wetland and Tax Map layers into NAD1983 UTM19N from their original (mismatched) projections. This projection insured both layers used the same geographical coordinates and were accurately aligned spatially.
Next, the Intersect tool in ArcMap was used to produce a new layer, including only those locations that included both a map-lot and an area of either current or potential wetlands. Unfortunately, due to the scale at which the tax maps were drawn, the two layers did not always intersect as they should have. As the island lots were purposefully drawn closer to the mainland than they should have been for printing purposes (J.C. Wilson-Hennessey, IFA, CMA, personal communication), these lots were excluded from the optimization analysis.
Having obtained the output layer including only the areas of intersection between the wetland area and tax-maps, the data included multiple rows for each map-lot, one for each separate wetland polygon with which the map-lot intersected. Excel was used to organize the data so that each row had one map-lot and one area, and each column had only areas belonging to that columns sea-level-rise scenario. This was then collapsed using Stata, resulting in a data set with a unique row for each unique map-lot, with the sum of potential wetland area under each scenario. Excel's match and index functions were then used to associate the correct assessed value for that map-lot and the map-lot type (parcel, town, conservation) as had been coded by the town's mapper.