Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T23:10:52.706Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

More is Less

Why Parties May Deliberately Write Incomplete Contracts

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 April 2024

Maija Halonen-Akatwijuka
Affiliation:
University of Bristol
Oliver Hart
Affiliation:
Harvard University

Summary

Why are contracts incomplete? Transaction costs and bounded rationality cannot be a total explanation since states of the world are often describable, foreseeable, and yet are not mentioned in a contract. Asymmetric information theories also have limitations. We offer an explanation based on 'contracts as reference points'. Including a contingency of the form, 'The buyer will require a good in event E', has a benefit and a cost. The benefit is that if E occurs there is less to argue about; the cost is that the additional reference point provided by the outcome in E can hinder (re)negotiation in states outside E. We show that if parties agree about a reasonable division of surplus, an incomplete contract is strictly superior to a contingent contract. If parties have different views about the division of surplus, an incomplete contract can be superior if including a contingency would lead to divergent reference points.
Get access
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781009396059
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 23 May 2024

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Philippe, Aghion and Bolton, Patrick. 1987. “Contracts as a Barrier to Entry.” American Economic Review 77(3): 388401.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe and Hermalin, Benjamin. 1990. “Legal Restrictions on Private Contracts Can Enhance Efficiency.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organizations 6(2): 381409.Google Scholar
Al-Najjar, Nabil I., Anderlini, Luca and Felli, Leonardo. 2006. “Undescribable Events.” Review of Economic Studies 73(4): 849868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderlini, Luca and Leonardo, Felli. 1994. “Incomplete Written Contracts: Undescribable States of Nature.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(4): 10851124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Ian and Gertner, Robert. 1989. “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules.” Yale Law Journal 99(1): 87130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Ian and Gertner, Robert. 1992. “Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules.” Yale Law Journal 101(4): 729773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bajari, Patrick and Tadelis, Steven. 2001. “Incentives versus Transaction Costs: A Theory of Procurement Contracts.” Rand Journal of Economics 32(3): 387407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
George, Baker, Gibbons, Robert and Murphy, Kevin J.. 1994. “Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(4): 11251156.Google Scholar
Benabou, Roland and Tirole, Jean. 2003. “Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation.” Review of Economic Studies 70(3): 489520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benabou, Roland and Tirole, Jean. 2006. “Incentives and Prosocial Behavior.” American Economic Review 96(5): 16521678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Michael, D. Whinston. 1998. “Incomplete Contracts and Strategic Ambiguity.” American Economic Review 88(4): 902932.Google Scholar
Bolton, Patrick and Faure-Grimaud, Antoine. 2010. “Satisficing Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 77(3): 937971.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin. 2003. Behavioral Game Theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Card, David. 1986. “An Empirical Model of Wage Indexation Provisions in Union Contracts.” Journal of Political Economy 94(3): S144S175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakravarty, Surajeet and Bentley MacLeod, W.. 2009. “Contracting in the Shadow of the Law.” Rand Journal of Economics 40(3): 533557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Che, Yeon-Koo and Hausch, Donald. 1999. “Cooperative Investments and the Value of Contracting.” American Economic Review 89(1): 125147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dye, Ronald. 1985. “Costly Contract Contingencies.” International Economic Review 26(1): 233250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, Hart, Oliver and Zehnder, Christian. 2015. “How Do Informal Agreements and Renegotiation Shape Contractual Reference Points?Journal of the European Economic Association 13(1): 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frydlinger, David, Hart, Oliver and Vitasek, Kate. 2019. “A New Approach to Contracts.” Harvard Business Review September–October.Google Scholar
Frydlinger, David and Hart, Oliver. 2024. “Overcoming Contractual Incompleteness: The Role of Guiding Principles.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halonen-Akatwijuka, Maija and Hart, Oliver. 2020. “Continuing Contracts.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 36(2): 284313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver and Moore, John. 1999. “Foundations of Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 66(1): 115–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver and Moore, John. 2008. “Contracts as Reference Points.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(1): 148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartman-Glaser, Barney and Hébert, Benjamin. 2020. “The Insurance Is the Lemon: Failing to Index Contracts.” Journal of Finance 75(1): 463506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heider, Fritz. 1958. The Psychology of Interpersonal Relations. Hillside (NJ): Erlbaum.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herold, Florian. 2010. “Contractual Incompleteness as a Signal of Trust.” Games and Economic Behavior 68: 180191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herweg, Fabian and Schmidt, Klaus M.. 2015. “Loss Aversion and Ex Post Inefficient Renegotiation.” Review of Economic Studies 82(1): 297332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelman, Herbert C. 1958. “Compliance, Identification, and Internalization: Three Processes of Attitude Change.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 2(1): 5160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kvaløy, Ola and Olsen, Trond E.. 2009. “Endogenous Verifiability and Relational Contracting.” American Economic Review 99: 21932208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malcomson, James. 2013. “Relational Incentive Contracts.” In The Handbook of Organizational Economics, edited by Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, 10141065. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Robert M. and Hunt, Shelby D.. 1994. “The Commitment-Trust Theory of Relationship Marketing.” Journal of Marketing 58(3): 2038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oyer, Paul. 2004. “Why Do Firms Use Incentives that Have No Incentive Effects?Journal of Finance 59(4): 16191649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1986. The Economic Analysis of Law. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Rothschild, Michael and Stiglitz, Joseph. 1976. “Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90(4): 629649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, Klaus M. and Schnitzer, Monika. 1995. “The Interaction of Explicit and Implicit Contracts.” Economics Letters 48(2): 193199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, Alan and Scott, Robert E.. 2010. “Contract Interpretation Redux.” Yale Law Journal 119: 926964.Google Scholar
Segal, Ilya. 1999. “Complexity and Renegotiation: A Foundation for Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 66(1): 5782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shavell, Steven. 1980. “Damage Measures for Breach of Contract.” Bell Journal of Economics 11(2): 466490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spier, Kathryn. 1992. “Incomplete Contracts and Signalling.” RAND Journal of Economics 23(3): 432443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean. 2009. “Cognition and Incomplete Contracts.” American Economic Review 99(1):265294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weitzman, Martín L. 1984. The Share Economy: Conquering Stagflation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

More is Less
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

More is Less
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

More is Less
Available formats
×