Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T02:48:41.215Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part V - Evolutionary Perspectives on Welfare and Sustainability

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 November 2018

Ulrich Witt
Affiliation:
Max Planck Institute, Jena
Andreas Chai
Affiliation:
Griffith University, Queensland
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Understanding Economic Change
Advances in Evolutionary Economics
, pp. 341 - 392
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

References

Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. 1998. Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Angner, E. 2016. A Course in Behavioral Economics. London: Palgrave/MacMillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. D. and Rangel, A. 2009. Beyond Revealed Preference: Choice-theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 51104.Google Scholar
Binder, M. 2010. Elements of an Evolutionary Theory of Welfare. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Binswanger, M. 2006. Why Does Income Growth Fail to Make Us Happier? Searching for the Treadmills behind the Paradox of Happiness. Journal of Socio-Economics, 35, 366381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2008. Can There Be a Preference-based Utilitarianism. In: Fleurbaey, M., Salles, M., and Weymark, J. (eds.) Justice, Political Liberalism and Utilitarianism: Themes from Harsanyi and Rawls. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cabanac, M. 1992. Pleasure: The Common Currency. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 155, 173200.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Camerer, C., Loewenstein, G., and Prelec, D. 2005. Neuroeconomics: How Neuroscience Can Inform Economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 43, 964.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 144.Google Scholar
DellaVigna, S. 2009. Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315372.Google Scholar
Diener, E. and Lucas, R. E. 1999. Personality and Subjective Well-Being. In: Diener, E. (ed.) The Science of Well-Being: The Collected Works of Ed Diener. Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands.Google Scholar
Diener, E., Suh, E. M., Lucas, R. E., and Smith, H. L. 1999. Subjective Well-Being: Three Decades of Progress. Psychological Bulletin, 125, 276302.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. 1988. Sources, Procedures, and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation. Journal of Economic Literature, 26, 11201171.Google Scholar
Elster, J. 1983. Sour Grapes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fernández-Dols, J.-M. and Ruiz-Belda, M.-A. 1995. Are Smiles a Sign of Happiness? Gold Medal Winners at the Olympic Games. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69, 11131119.Google Scholar
Flanagan, K., Uyarra, E., and Laranja, M. 2011. Reconceptualising the “Policy Mix” for Innovation. Research Policy, 40, 702713.Google Scholar
Frederick, S. and Loewenstein, G. F. 1999. Hedonic Adaptation. In: Kahneman, D., Diener, E., and Schwarz, N. (eds.) Well-Being: The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Stutzer, A. 2002. Happiness and Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gowdy, J. 2005. Toward a New Welfare Economics for Sustainability. Ecological Economics, 53, 211222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, C. 2010. Happiness around the World: The Paradox of Happy Peasants and Miserable Millionaires. New York/Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gustafsson, R. and Autio, E. 2011. A Failure Trichotomy in Knowledge Exploration and Exploitation. Research Policy, 40, 819831.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. M. and Mcpherson, M. S. 2006. Economic Analysis, Moral Philosophy and Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Headey, B. 2010. The Set Point Theory of Well-being Has Serious Flaws: On the Eve of a Scientific Revolution? Social Indicators Research, 97, 721.Google Scholar
Helliwell, J., Layard, R., and Sachs, J. 2015. World Happiness Report. New York: Sustainable Development Solutions Network.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1939. The Foundations of Welfare Economics. Economic Journal, 49, 696712.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Wakker, P. P., and Sarin, R. 1997. Back to Bentham? Explorations of Experienced Utility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 375405.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1939. Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility. The Economic Journal, 49, 549552.Google Scholar
Kőszegi, B. and Rabin, M. 2008. Choices, Situations, and Happiness. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 18211832.Google Scholar
Krueger, A. B. and Schkade, D. A. 2008. The Reliability of Subjective Well-Being Measures. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 18331845.Google Scholar
Kuklys, W. 2005. Amartya Sen’s Capability Approach – Theoretical Insights and Empirical Applications. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Lancaster, K. J. 1966. A New Approach to Consumer Theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74, 132157.Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G. F. 1999. Is More Choice Always Better? Social Security Brief, 7, 18.Google Scholar
Lykken, D. and Tellegen, A. 1996. Happiness Is a Stochastic Phenomenon. Psychological Science, 7, 186189.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D., and Green, J. R. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. New York; Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
McQuillin, B. and Sugden, R. 2012. Reconciling Normative and Behavioural Economics: The Problems to Be Solved. Social Choice and Welfare, 38, 553567.Google Scholar
Metcalfe, J. S. 1998. Evolutionary Economics and Creative Destruction. New York; London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. 1990. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R. 1996. The Sources of Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. 1999. Hayek’s Contribution to Understanding the Process of Economic Change. In: Vanberg, V. J. (ed.) Freiheit, Wettbewerb und Wirtschaftsordnung. Freiburg: Haufe.Google Scholar
Nozick, R. 1974. Anarchy, State and Utopia. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, M. 2003. Capabilities as Fundamental Entitlements: Sen and Social Justice. Feminist Economics, 9, 3359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parfit, D. 1984. Reasons and Persons. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Redelmeier, D. A. and Kahneman, D. 1996. Patients’ Memories of Painful Medical Treatments: Real-time and Retrospective Evaluations of Two Minimally Invasive Procedures. Pain, 66, 38.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, N. and Birdzell, L. E. 1986. How the West Grew Rich – The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Sandvik, E., Diener, E., and Seidlitz, L. 1993. Subjective Well-Being: The Convergence and Stability of Self-report and Non-Self-report Measures. Journal of Personality, 61, 317342.Google Scholar
Sartorius, C. 2003. An Evolutionary Approach to Social Welfare. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schubert, C. 2015. What Do We Mean When We Say That Innovation and Entrepreneurship (Policy) Increase “Welfare”? Journal of Economic Issues, 49, 122.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Schwartz, B. 2000. Self-determination: The Tyranny of Freedom. American Psychologist, 55, 7988.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sen, A. 1985a. Commodities and Capabilities. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1985b. Well-Being, Agency and Freedom: The Dewey Lectures 1984. The Journal of Philosophy, 82, 169221.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1987. On Ethics and Economics. New York: B. Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1992. Inequality Reexamined. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1993. Internal Consistency of Choice. Econometrica, 61, 495521.Google Scholar
Shiv, B. and Huber, J. 2000. The Impact of Anticipating Satisfaction on Consumer Choice. Journal of Consumer Research, 27, 202216.Google Scholar
Shizgal, P. 1999. On the Neural Computation of Utility: Implications from Studies of Brain Stimulation Reward. In: Kahneman, D., Diener, E., and Schwarz, N. (eds.) Well-Being: The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1993. Welfare, Resources, and Capabilities: A Review of Inequality Reexamined by Amartya Sen. Nashville, TN: American Economic Association.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2004. The Opportunity Criterion: Consumer Sovereignty without the Assumption of Coherent Preferences. The American Economic Review, 94, 10141033.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2006. What We Desire, What We Have Reason to Desire, Whatever We Might Desire: Mill and Sen on the Value of Opportunity. Utilitas, 18, 3351.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2013. The Behavioural Economist and the Social Planner: To Whom Should Behavioural Welfare Economics Be Addressed? Inquiry, 56, 519538.Google Scholar
Tenner, E. 1997. Why Things Bite Back: Technology and the Revenge of Unintended Consequences. New York: Vintage.Google Scholar
Vanberg, V. J. 2014. Evolving Preferences and Welfare Economics: The Perspective of Constitutional Political Economy. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 234, 328349.Google Scholar
von Weizsäcker, C. C. 2005. The Welfare Economics of Adaptive Preferences. In: Institute, M. P. (ed.) Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods. Bonn: Max Planck Institute.Google Scholar
Witt, U. 1996. Innovations, Externalities and the Problem of Economic Progress. Public Choice, 89, 113130.Google Scholar
Witt, U. 2009. Novelty and the Bounds of Unknowledge in Economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 16, 361375.Google Scholar
Witt, U. 2017. The Evolution of Consumption and Its Welfare Effects. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 27, 273293.Google Scholar
Witt, U. and Schubert, C. 2008. Constitutional Interests in the Face of Innovations: How Much Do We Need to Know about Risk Preferences? Constitutional Political Economy, 19, 203225.Google Scholar

References

Ackerberg, D. A. 2003. Advertising, Learning, and Consumer Choice in Experience Good Markets: An Empirical Examination. International Economic Review, 44, 10071040.Google Scholar
Aguiló, E., Alegre, J., and Sard, M. 2003. Examining the Market Structure of the German and UK Tour Operating Industries through an Analysis of Package Holiday Prices. Tourism Economics, 9, 255278.Google Scholar
Anderson, J. 2000. Learning and Memory. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Arkesteijn, K. K. and Oerlemans, L. L. a. G. 2005. The Early Adoption of Green Power by Dutch Households: An Empirical Exploration of Factors Influencing the Early Adoption of Green Electricity for Domestic Purposes. Energy Policy, 33, 183196.Google Scholar
Bandura, A. 1986. Social Foundations of Thought and Action: A Social Cognitive Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Murphy, K. M. 1988. A Theory of Rational Addiction. Journal of Political Economy, 96, 675700.Google Scholar
Bianchi, M. 2002. Novelty, Preferences, and Fashion: When Goods are Unsettling. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 47, 118.Google Scholar
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., and Welch, I. 1992. A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 9921026.Google Scholar
Binder, M. and Lades, L. K. 2015. Autonomy-Enhancing Paternalism. Kyklos, 68, 327.Google Scholar
Bishop, P. 1996. Off Road: Four-wheel Drive and the Sense of Place. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 14, 257271.Google Scholar
Bisin, A. and Verdier, T. 2001. The Economics of Cultural Transmission and the Dynamics of Preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 97, 298319.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. 1998. Endogenous Preferences: The Cultural Consequences of Markets and other Economic Institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 75111.Google Scholar
Brennan, T. J. 2006. “Green” Preferences as Regulatory Policy Instrument. Ecological Economics, 56, 144154.Google Scholar
Brenner, T. 1999. Modeling Learning in Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Brown, P. M. and Cameron, L. D. 2000. What Can Be Done to Reduce Overconsumption? Ecological Economics, 32, 2741.Google Scholar
Buenstorf, G. 2003. Designing Clunkers: Demand-side Innovation and the Early History of the Mountain Bike. In: Metcalfe, S. and Cantner, U. (eds.) Change, Transformation and Development. Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag HD.Google Scholar
Buenstorf, G. and Cordes, C. 2008. Can Sustainable Consumption Be Learned? A Model of Cultural Evolution. Ecological Economics, 67, 646657.Google Scholar
Chai, A. 2011. Consumer Specialization and the Romantic Transformation of the British Grand Tour of Europe. Journal of Bioeconomics, 13, 181203.Google Scholar
Chai, A., Bradley, G., Lo, A., and Reser, J. 2015. What Time to Adapt? The Role of Discretionary Time in Sustaining the Climate Change Value-Action Gap. Ecological Economics, 116, 95107.Google Scholar
Chai, A., Earl, P. E., and Potts, J. 2007. Fashion, Growth and Welfare: An Evolutionary Approach. Advances in Austrian Economics, 10, 187207.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Cordes, C. 2003. An Evolutionary Analysis of Long-Term Qualitative Change in Human Labor. Jena, Germany: Friedrich Schiller University Jena.Google Scholar
Cowan, R., Cowan, W., and Swann, P. 1997. A Model of Demand with Interactions among Consumers. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15, 711732.Google Scholar
DeFleur, M. L. and Ball-Rokeach, S. J. 1989. Theories of Mass Communication. New York: Longman.Google Scholar
Dietz, T., Gardner, G. T., Gilligan, J., Stern, P. C., and Vandenbergh, M. P. 2009. Household Actions Can Provide a Behavioral Wedge to Rapidly Reduce US Carbon Emissions. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 106, 1845218456.Google Scholar
Dopfer, K. and Potts, J. 2007. The General Theory of Economic Evolution. New York; London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dulleck, U. and Kerschbamer, R. 2006. On Doctors, Mechanics, and Computer Specialists: The Economics of Credence Goods. Journal of Economic Literature, 44, 542.Google Scholar
Earl, P. 1986. Lifestyle Economics: Consumer Behaviour in a Turbulent World. Sussex: Wheatsheaf Books.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. and Potts, J. 2004. The Market for Preferences. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28, 619633.Google Scholar
Farhar, B. C. 1999. Willingness to Pay for Electricity from Renewable Resources: A Review of Utility Market Research. National Renewable Energy Laboratory.Google Scholar
Farrell, J. and Saloner, G. 1985. Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation. The Rand Journal of Economics, 16, 7083.Google Scholar
Flinn, M. V. 1997. Culture and the Evolution of Social Learning. Evolution and Human Behavior, 18, 2367.Google Scholar
Foxall, G. R. 1989. Consumer Psychology in Behavioural Perspective. New York; London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. 1999. Luxury Fever: Weighing the Cost of Excess. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. 1993. Motivation as a Limit to Pricing. Journal of Economic Psychology, 14, 635664.Google Scholar
Galtung, J. 1980. The Basic Needs Approach. In: Lederer, K. (ed.) Human Needs: A Contribution to the Current Debate. Cambridge: Oelgeschlager, Gunn & Hain.Google Scholar
Gifford, R., Kormos, C., and Mcintyre, A. 2011. Behavioral Dimensions of Climate Change: Drivers, Responses, Barriers, and Interventions. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Climate Change, 2, 801827.Google Scholar
Goodson, F. E. 2003. The Evolution and Function of Cognition. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates Publishers.Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. and Soong, R. 1986. Threshold Models of Interpersonal Effects in Consumer Demand. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 7, 8399.Google Scholar
Hayak, F. A. 1937. Economics and Knowledge. Economica, 4, 3354.Google Scholar
Hergenhahn, B. R. and Olson, M. H. 1997. An Introduction to Theories of Learning. Upper Saddle River, NJ Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Higham, J. E. S. and Cohen, S. A. 2011. Canary in the Coalmine: Norwegian Attitudes towards Climate Change and Extreme Long-haul Air Travel to Aotearoa/New Zealand. Tourism Management, 32, 98105.Google Scholar
Hull, C. L. 1943. Principles of Behavior: An Introduction to Behavior Theory. Oxford: Appleton-Century.Google Scholar
Jackson, T., Jager, W., and Stagl, S. 2004. Beyond Insatiability – Needs Theory, Consumption and Sustainability. In: Reisch, L. A. and Røpke, I. (eds.) The Ecological Economics of Consumption. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Jackson, T. and Marks, N. 1999. Consumption, Sustainable Welfare and Human Needs – With Reference to UK Expenditure Patterns between 1954 and 1994. Ecological Economics, 28, 421441.Google Scholar
Jackson, T. and Papathanasopoulou, E. 2008. Luxury or “Lock-in”? An Exploration of Unsustainable Consumption in the UK: 1968 to 2000. Ecological Economics, 68, 8095.Google Scholar
Janssen, M. A. and Jager, W. 2001. Fashions, Habits and Changing Preferences: Simulation of Psychological Factors Affecting Market Dynamics. Journal of Economic Psychology, 22, 745772.Google Scholar
Jeppsen, L. and Molin, M. 2003. Consumers as Co-Developers: Learning and Innovation Outside the Firm. Working Paper Series. Copenhagen: Copenhagen Department of Industrial Economics & Strategy, Copenhagen Business School.Google Scholar
Kerstetter, D. L., Confer, J. J., and Graefe, A. R. 2001. An Exploration of the Specialization Concept within the Context of Heritage Tourism. Journal of Travel Research, 39, 267274.Google Scholar
Khalil, E. L. 2003. The Context Problematic, Behavioral Economics and the Transactional View: An Introduction to “John Dewey and Economic Theory”. Journal of Economic Methodology, 10, 107130.Google Scholar
Kleiman, M. 1992. Against Excess: Drug Policy for Results. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. 2001. Knowledge, Consumption and Endogenous Growth. In: Witt, U. (ed.) Escaping Satiation. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. and Cosgel, M. 1998. The Organization of Consumption. In: Bianchi, M. (ed.) The Active Consumer. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lindner, S. B. 1970. The Harried Leisure Class. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Lintott, J. 1998. Beyond the Economics of More: The Place of Consumption in Ecological Economics. Ecological Economics, 25, 239248.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. 1999. Knowledge, Institutions, and Evolution in Economics. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
MacCoun, R., Reuter, P., and Schelling, T. 1996. Assessing Alternative Drug Control Regimes. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 15, 330352.Google Scholar
Maréchal, K. 2010. Not Irrational but Habitual: The Importance of “Behavioural Lock-in” in Energy Consumption. Ecological Economics, 69, 11041114.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1919. Industry and Trade. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Martin, S. R. 1997. Specialization and Differences in Setting Preferences among Wildlife Viewers. Human Dimensions of Wildlife, 2, 118.Google Scholar
Max-Neef, M. A., Elizalde, A., and Hopenhayn, M. 1991. Human Scale Development: Conception, Application and Further Reflections. New York: The Apex Press.Google Scholar
McFarland, D. 1987. The Oxford Companion to Animal Behavior. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Menger, C. 1950. Principles of Economics. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Moreau, C. P., Lehmann, D. R., and Markman, A. B. 2001. Entrenched Knowledge Structures and Consumer Response to New Products. Journal of Marketing Research, 38, 1429.Google Scholar
Mueller, B. 1991. An Analysis of Information Content in Standardized vs. Specialized Multinational Advertisements. Journal of International Business Studies, 22, 2339.Google Scholar
Myers, K. M. and Davis, M. 2007. Mechanisms of Fear Extinction. Molecular Psychiatry, 12, 120150.Google Scholar
Myers, N. and Kent, J. 2003. The New Consumers: The Influence of Affluence on the Environment. London; Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R. and Consoli, D. 2010. An Evolutionary Theory of Household Consumption Behavior. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20, 665687.Google Scholar
Norton, B., Costanza, R., and Bishop, R. C. 1998. The Evolution of Preferences Why “Sovereign” Preferences May Not Lead to Sustainable Policies and What to Do about It. Ecological Economics, 24, 193211.Google Scholar
O’Hara, S. U. and Stagl, S. 2002. Endogenous Preferences and Sustainable Development. Journal of Socio-Economics, 31, 511527.Google Scholar
OECD. 2008. Promoting Sustainable Consumption: Good Practices in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Ölander, F. and Kahneman, D. 1995. Understanding of Consumer Behaviour as a Prerequisite for Environmental Protection. Journal of Consumer Policy, 18, 345385.Google Scholar
Pedersen, L. H. 2000. The Dynamics of Green Consumption: A Matter of Visibility? Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning, 2, 193210.Google Scholar
Posner, M. I. and Petersen, S. E. 1990. The Attention System of the Human Brain: 20 Years After. Annual Review of Neuroscience, 35, 7389.Google Scholar
Robson, A. J. 2001. The Biological Basis of Economic Behavior. Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 1133.Google Scholar
Rogers, E. M. 1962. Diffusion of New Innovations. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Rolls, E. T. 2005. Emotion Explained. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Røpke, I. 1999. The Dynamics of Willingness to Consume. Ecological Economics, 28, 399420.Google Scholar
Røpke, I. 2009. Theories of Practice – New Inspiration for Ecological Economic Studies on Consumption. Ecological Economics, 68, 24902497.Google Scholar
Sanne, C. 2002. Willing Consumers – or Locked-in? Policies for a Sustainable Consumption. Ecological Economics, 42, 273287.Google Scholar
Sartorius, C. 2003. An Evolutionary Approach to Social Welfare. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Saviotti, P. 2002. Variety, Growth and Demand. In: McMeekin, A., Green, K., Tomlinson, M., and Walsh, V. (eds.) Innovation by Demand. Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Schor, J. B. 1991. The Overworked American: The Unexpected Decline of Leisure. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. 1976. The Joyless Economy: An Inquiry into Human Satisfaction and Consumer Dissatisfaction. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sexton, S. E. and Sexton, A. L. 2014. Conspicuous Conservation: The Prius Halo and Willingness to Pay for Environmental Bona Fides. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 67, 303317.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. 1972. Epistemics and Economics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. and Becker, G. S. 1977. De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum. The American Economic Review, 67, 7690.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. and Sunstein, C. R. 2008. Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. 2008. Environmental Regulation of Households: An Empirical Review of Economic and Psychological Factors. Ecological Economics, 66, 559574.Google Scholar
van den Ende, J. and Dolfsma, W. 2005. Technology-push, Demand-pull and the Shaping of Technological Paradigms – Patterns in the Development of Computing Technology. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 15, 8399.Google Scholar
von Hippel, E. 2005. Democratizing Innovation. London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Wagner, J. 2006. On the Economics of Sustainability. Ecological Economics, 57, 659664.Google Scholar
Windrum, P. 2005. Heterogeneous Preferences and New Innovation Cycles in Mature Industries: The Amateur Camera Industry 1955–1974. Industrial and Corporate Change, 14, 10431074.Google Scholar
Witt, U. 2001. Learning to Consume – A Theory of Wants and the Growth of Demand. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11, 2336.Google Scholar
Witt, U. 2016. The Evolution of Consumption and Its Welfare Effects. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 27(2), 121.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×