Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T15:25:19.379Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 December 2020

Zili Yang
Affiliation:
State University of New York at Binghamton
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Environment and Externality
Theory, Algorithms and Applications
, pp. 277 - 285
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Amundsen, E. S. and Schob, R.. (1999). “Environmental taxes on exhaustible resources.” European Journal of Political Economy, 15, 311–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antweiler, W. and Trefler, D.. (2002). “Increasing returns and all that: a view from trade.” The American Economic Review, 92(1), 93119.Google Scholar
Arkolakis, C., Costinot, A., and Rodriguez-Clare, A.. (2012). “New trade models, same old gains?American Economic Review, 102(1), 94103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J. and Debreu, G.. (1954). “Existence of equilibrium for a competitive economy.” Econometrica, 22, 265–90.Google Scholar
Arthur, W. B. (1994). Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. J. (1961). “The core of a cooperative game without side payments.” Transactions of the American Mathematical Society, 98, 539–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. J. and Myerson, R.. (1988). “Endogenous formation of links between players and of coalitions: an application of the Shapley value.” In Roth, A., ed., The Shapley Value: Essays in Honor of Lloyd Shapley. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 175–91.Google Scholar
Ayres, R. U. and Kneese, A. V.. (1969). “Production, consumption, and externality.American Economic Review, 59(3), 282–97.Google Scholar
Babiker, M. (2005). “Climate change policy, market structure, and carbon leakage.” Journal of International Economics, 65, 412–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baliga, S. and Maskin, E.. (2003). “Mechanism design for the environment.” In Maler, K. and Vincent, J., eds., Vol. 1, Handbook of Environmental Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, pp. 306–23.Google Scholar
Barrett, S. (1992). “Economic growth and environmental preservation.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 23, 289300.Google Scholar
Barrett, S. (1994). “Self-enforcing international environmental agreements.” Oxford Economic Papers, 46, 111–22.Google Scholar
Barrett, S. (1997). “The strategy of trade sanctions in international environmental agreements.” Resource and Energy Economics, 19(4), 345–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bator, F. M. (1958). “The anatomy of market failures.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72, 351–79.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. (1972). “On taxation and the control of externalities.” American Economic Review, 62(3), 307–22.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. and Oates, W. E.. (1988). The Theory of Environmental Policy, 2nd ed. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beavis, B. and Dobbs, I. M., (1990). Optimization and Stability Theory for Economic Analysis. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bergstrom, T. C. (1975). “The core when strategies are restricted by law.” Review of Economic Studies, 42, 249–57.Google Scholar
Blomberg, J. (2007). “Essays on the economics of the aluminum industry.” Doctoral Thesis, Lulea University of Technology, Sweden.Google Scholar
Borah, D. and Bera., M. (2004). “Watershed-scale hydrologic and nonpoint-source pollution models: review of applications.” Transactions of the American Society of Agricultural Engineer, 47(3), 789803.Google Scholar
Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., Galeotti, M., Massetti, E., and Tavoniet., M. (2006). “WITCH: a world induced technical change hybrid model.The Energy Journal, 27(1), 1337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, G. (1987). “Factor intensity and site geology as determinants of returns to scale in coal mining.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 69(1), 1823.Google Scholar
Britto, D. L. (1972). “A dynamic model of an armaments race.” International Economic Review, 13(2), 359–75.Google Scholar
Brooke, A., Kendrick, D., Meeraus, A., and Raman, R.. (2004). GAMS: A User’s Guide, Washington, DC: GAMS Development Corporation.Google Scholar
Caplan, A. J., Ellis, C. J. and Silva, E.. (1999). “Winners and losers in a world with global warming – noncooperation, altruism and social welfare.Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 37, 256–71.Google Scholar
Carraro, C. and Siniscalco, D.. (1993). “Strategies for the international protection of the environment.” Journal of Public Economics, 52, 309–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carraro, C. and Siniscalco, D.. (1998). “International environmental agreements: incentives and political economy.” European Economic Review, 42, 561–72.Google Scholar
Chander, P. and Tulkens, H.. (1997). “A core of an economy with multilateral environmental externalities.” International Journal of Game Theory, 26, 379401.Google Scholar
Chander, P. and Tulkens, H.. (2008). “Cooperation, stability, and self-enforcement in international environmental agreements: a conceptual discussion.” In Guesnerie, R. and Tulkens, H., eds., The Design of Climate Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 166–86.Google Scholar
Christensen, L. and Greene., W. (1976). “Economies of scale in U.S. electric power generation.” Journal of Political Economy, 84(4), 655–76.Google Scholar
Clarke, E. H. (1971). “Multipart pricing of public goods.” Public Choice, 11, 1733.Google Scholar
The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. (2018). “Economic growth, technological change, and climate change.” www.nobelprize.org/uploads/2018/10/advanced-economicsciencesprize2018.pdf/Google Scholar
Cornes, R. and Sandler, T.. (1996). The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods, 2nd ed. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cropper, M. L. and Oates, W. E.. (1992). “Environmental economics: a survey.” Journal of Economic Literature, 30, 675740.Google Scholar
D’Aspremont, C., Jacquemin, A., Gabszwwicz, J. J., and Weymark, J. A.. (1983). “On the stability of collusive price leadership.” The Canadian Journal of Economics, 16, 1725.Google Scholar
Daubanes, J. and Grimaud, A.. (2010). “Taxation of polluting non-renewable resource in the heterogeneous world.” Environmental and Resource Economics, 47, 567–88.Google Scholar
de Zeeuw, A. (2008). “Dynamic effects on the stability of international environmental agreement.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 55(2), 163–74.Google Scholar
Diamond, P. and Mirrlees, J.. (1973). “Aggregate production with consumption externalities.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87, 124.Google Scholar
Dinar, A., Albiac, J., and Sanchez-Soriano, J., eds. (2008). Game Theory and Policy Making in Natural Resources and the Environment. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ellerman, A. D., et al. (2000). Market for Clean Air: The US Acid Rain Program. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Environmental Protection Agency, the United States. (1994). “Radioactive Waste Disposal: An Environmental Perspective.” EPA 402-K-94-001.Google Scholar
Eyckmans, J. and Tulkens, H.. (2003). “Simulating coalitionally stable burden sharing agreements for the climate change problem.” Resource and Energy Economics, 25, 299327.Google Scholar
Farzin, Y. H. (1996). “Optimal pricing of environmental and natural resource use with stock externalities.” Journal of Public Economics, 62, 3157.Google Scholar
Farzin, Y. H. and Tahvonen, O.. (1996). “Global carbon cycle and the optimal time path of a carbon tax.” Oxford Economic Papers, 48(4), 515–36.Google Scholar
Finus, M. and Caparros, A., eds. (2000). Game Theory and International Environmental Cooperation – Essential Readings. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Finus, M. (2008). “Game theoretic research on the design of international environmental agreements: insights, critical remarks, and future challenges.” International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, 2, 2967.Google Scholar
Foley, D. K. (1970). “Lindahl’s solution and the core of an economy with public goods.” Econometrica, 38, 6672.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Folmer, H. and de Zeeuw, A.. (1999). “Chapter 70: Game theory in environmental policy analysis.” In van den Bergh, J., ed. Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. M. and Fisher., A. C. (1987). “Valuing the environment as input.” Journal of Environmental Management, 25, 149–56.Google Scholar
Ginsburgh, V. and Keyzer, M. (2002). The Structure of Applied General Equilibrium Models. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Groves, T. (1973). “Incentives in teams.” Econometrica, 41, 617–31.Google Scholar
Hanley, N. and Folmer, H., eds. (1998). Game Theory and the Environment, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Hansen, J., et al. (2005). “Efficacy of climate forcings.Journal of Geophysical Research, Vol. 110, doi: 101029/2005JD005776.Google Scholar
Hausfather, Z. (2010). “Common climate misconceptions: atmospheric carbon dioxide. www.yaleclimateconnections.org/2010/12/common-climate-misconceptions-atmospheric-carbon-dioxide/Google Scholar
Helpman, E. and Krugman, P.. (1985). Market Structure and Foreign Trade. The Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hoel, M., ed. (2004). Recent Developments in Environmental Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Holcombe, R. and Sobel, R. (2001). “Public policy toward pecuniary externalities.” Public Finance Review, 29(4), 304–25.Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. (1931). “The economics of exhaustible resources.” Journal of Political Economy, 39, 137–75.Google Scholar
IPCC (2001). Climate Change 2001, The Third Assessment Report. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
IPCC (2014). Climate Change 2014, The Fifth Assessment Report. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, C. (2005). “Chapter 16: Growth and ideas.” In Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. eds., Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1B. Amsterdam: Elsevier BV.Google Scholar
Kamien, M. I. and Schwartz, N. L.. (1982). “The role of common property resources in optimal planning models with exhaustible resources.” In Smith, V. K. and Kruilla, J. V., eds., Explorations in Natural Resource Economics. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Kohler, J., Grubb, M., Popp, D., and Edenhofer, O.. (2006). “The transition to endogenous technical change in climate-economy models: a technical overview to the innovation modeling comparison project.” The Energy Journal Special Issue, 17–55.Google Scholar
Kohn, R. E. (1993). “An economic model of pollution prevention.” Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 17(12), 21–8.Google Scholar
Kolstad, C. (2011). Environmental Economics, 2nd ed. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kolstad, C. D. and Krautkraemer, J. A.. (1993). “Natural resource use and the environment.” In Kneese, A. V. and Sweeney, J. L., eds., Handbook of Natural Resource and Energy Economics, Vol. 3. New York: Elsevier Science Publishers.Google Scholar
Krautkraemer, J. A. (1985). “Optimal growth, resource amenities and the preservation of natural environment.” Review of Economic Studies, 52, 153–70.Google Scholar
Krautkraemer, J. A. (1986). “Optimal depletion with resource amenities and a backstop technology.” Resource and Energy, 8, 133–49.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (1980). “Scale economies, product differentiation, and the patter of trade.American Economic Review, 70, 950–59.Google Scholar
Krugman, P., Obstfeld, M., and Melitz, M.. (2018). International Economics, 11th ed. New York: Pearson.Google Scholar
Laffont, J. (1988). Fundamentals of Public Economics. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Laffont, J. J. (2008). “Externalities.” In Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. New York: The Macmillan Press.Google Scholar
Laitner, J., DeCanio, S., and Peters, I.. (2001). “Incorporating behavioral, social, and organizational phenomena in the assessment of climate change mitigation options.” In Jochem, E. and Sathaye, J., eds., Society, Behaviour, and Climate Change Mitigation. Berlin, Germany: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Lessmann, K., Kornek, U., Bosetti, V., Dellink, R., Emmerling, J., Eyckmans, J., Nagashima, M., Weikard, H., and Yang, Z. (2015) “The stability and effectiveness of climate coalitions: a comparative analysis of multiple integrated assessment models.” Environmental and Resource Economics, 62, 811–34.Google Scholar
Lessmann, K. and Edenhofer, O.. (2011). “Research cooperation and international standards in a model of coalition stability.” Resource and Energy Economics, 33(1), 3654.Google Scholar
Martinet, V. and Doyen, L.. (2007). “Sustainability of an economy with an exhaustible resource: A viable control approach.” Resource and Energy Economics, 29, 1739.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A. and Silvestre, J.. (1989). “Cost share equilibria: a Lindahl approach.” Journal of Economic Theory, 47, 239–56.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D., and Green, J. R.. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mason, C. and Bulte, E., eds. (2007). Environmental Economics: Critical Concepts. London: Routledge Publishing.Google Scholar
McBride, M. (1981). “The nature and source of economies of scale in cement production.” Southern Economic Journal, 48(1), 105115.Google Scholar
McMahon, A. M. (1992). “‘Small matters’: Benjamin Franklin, Philadelphia, and the ‘progress of cities.’” The Pennsylvania Magazine of History & Biography, 116, 157–82.Google Scholar
Meade, J. E. (1973). The Theory of Economic Externalities: the Cost of Environmental Pollution and Similar Social Costs. Geneva, Switzerland: A. W. Sijthoff-Leiden.Google Scholar
Mitchell, R. B. (2003). “International environmental agreements: a survey of their features, formation, and effects.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 28, 429–61.Google Scholar
Mooney, C. (2018). “Someone, somewhere, is making a banned chemical that destroys the ozone layer, scientists suspect.” The Washington Post, May 16, 2018.Google Scholar
Muench, T. (1972). “The core and the Lindahl equilibrium of an economic with a public good: an example.” Journal of Economic Theory, 4, 241–55.Google Scholar
Mueller, D. (2003). Public Choice III. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Myerson, R. B. (1991). Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Myles, G. D. (1995). Public Economics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nash, J. (1950). “The bargaining problem.” Econometrica, 18, 155–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. (1953). “Two-person cooperative games.” Econometrica, 21, 129–40.Google Scholar
Negishi, T. (1960). “Welfare economics and the existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy.” Metroeconomica, 12, 92–7.Google Scholar
Newell, R. G. and Pizer, W. A.. (2003). “Regulating stock externalities under uncertainty.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45, 416–32.Google Scholar
Nielsen, H. (2018). “Technology and scale changes: the steel industry of a planned economy in a comparative perspective.” Economic History of Developing Regions, 33 https://doi.org/10.1080/20780389.2018.1432353.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. (1994). Managing Global Commons: the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. (2015). “Climate clubs: overcoming free-riding in international climate policy.” American Economic Review, 105(4), 1139–70.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. and Boyer, J. (2000). Warming the World: Economic Models of Global Warming. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. and Yang, Z.. (1996). “A regional dynamic general-equilibrium model of alternative climate-change strategies.” American Economic Review, 86(4), 741–65.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. (2002). “Modeling induced innovation in climate change policy.” In Grubler, A., Nakicenovic, N., and Nordhaus, W., eds., Technological Change and the Environment. Washington DC: RFF Press.Google Scholar
Parks, R. P. (1991). “Pareto irrelevant externalities.” Journal of Economic Theory, 54, 165–79.Google Scholar
Pearce, D. (2002). “An intellectual history of environmental economics.” Annual Review Energy and Environment, 27, 5781.Google Scholar
Phaneuf, D. J. and Requate, T.. (2017). A Course in Environmental Economics – Theory, Policy, and Practice. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. (1920). The Economics of Welfare. London, UK: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. (1947). A Study in Public Finance. London, UK: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Peters, I., Ackerman, F., and Bernow, S.. (1999). “Economic theory and climate change policy.” Energy Policy, 27, 501504.Google Scholar
Porter, M. (1990). The Comparative Advantage of Nations. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Ray, D. (2007). A Game-Theoretic Perspective on Coalition Formation. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ribaudo, M., Horan, R. and Smith, M.. (1999). Economics of Water Quality Protection from Nonpoint Sources: Theory and Practice. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Economic Report No. 782, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Roberts, J. (2008). “Lindahl Equilibrium.” In Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. New York: The Macmillan Press.Google Scholar
Romer, P. M. (1994). “The Origins of Endogenous Growth.The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 322.Google Scholar
Rudin, W. (1976). Principles of Mathematical Analysis, 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Rutherford, T. (1999). “Sequential joint maximization.” In Weyant, J., ed., Energy and Environmental Policy Modeling. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1954). “The pure theory of public expenditure.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 37, 387–9.Google Scholar
Scarf, H. E. (1967). “The core of an n-person game.” Econometrica, 35, 5069.Google Scholar
Shapley, L. S. and Shubik, M.. (1969). “On the core of an economic system with externalities.” American Economic Review, 59, 678–84.Google Scholar
Shortle, J. and Horan, R.. (2001). “The economics of nonpoint pollution control,” Journal of Economics Surveys, 15(3), 255–89.Google Scholar
Smith, V. K. and Zhao., M. (2019). “Economy-wide modeling, environmental macro-economics, and benefit cost analysis.” Huntington, UK: Mimeo On-line Printing.Google Scholar
Stanton, E. A. (2010). “Negishi welfare weights in integrated assessment models: the mathematics of global inequality.” Climatic Change, 107, 407–32.Google Scholar
Starrett, D. (1972). “Fundamental non-convexities in the theory of externalities.” Journal of Economic Theory, 9, 418–48.Google Scholar
Starrett, D. (1973). “A note on externalities and the core.” Econometrica, 41, 179–83.Google Scholar
Stern, N. (2007). Economics of Climate Change: the Stern Review. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Takayama, A. (1985). Mathematical Economics, 2nd ed. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tietenberg, T. H. and Lewis, L.. (2014). Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, 10th ed. London: Pearson.Google Scholar
Tol, R. (2009). “The economic effects of climate change.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(2), 2951.Google Scholar
Tol, R. (2019). Climate Economics, 2nd ed. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
The United States, Department of Commerce. (2016). “Steel Export Report: China.” http://trade.gov/steel/countries/pdfs/exports-china.pdf/Google Scholar
The United States, Department of Energy. (2016). www.eia.gov/beta/international/Google Scholar
Unruh, G. C. (2000). “Understanding carbon lock-in.” Energy Policy, 28, 817–30.Google Scholar
Uzawa, H. (2003). Economic Theory and Global Warming. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Van den Nouweland, A. (2013). “Lindahl and equilibrium.” In Baigent, Nick, Binder, C., Codgnato, G., Teschl, M. and Xu, Y., eds., Studies in Social Choice and Welfare. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd ed. W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Wang, Z., Wu, J., Liu, C., and Gu., G. (2017). Integrated Assessment Models of Climate Change Economics. Singapore: Springer.Google Scholar
Waschik, R. (2015). “Differentiated products, increasing returns to scale and heterogeneous firms in a CGE model of the Australian coal sector.” Energy Economics, 51, 521–9.Google Scholar
Weber, S. and Wiesmeth, H.. (1991). “The equivalence of core and cost share equilibrium in an economic with public goods.” Journal of Economic Theory, 54, 180–97.Google Scholar
Weitzman, M. L., (1974). “Prices vs. quantities.” Reviews of Economic Studies, 41, 477–91.Google Scholar
Wirl, F. (1994). “Pigouvian taxation of energy for flow and stock externalities and strategic, noncompetitive energy pricing.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 26, 118.Google Scholar
Withagen, C. (1994). “Pollution and exhaustibility of fossil fuels.” Resource and Energy Economics, 16, 235–42.Google Scholar
Xepapadeas, A. (1997). Advanced Principles in Environmental Policy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Yang, Z. (2006). “Negatively correlated local and global stock externalities: tax or subsidy?Environment and Development Economics, 11, 301316.Google Scholar
Yang, Z. (2008). Strategic Bargaining and Cooperation in Greenhouse Gas Mitigation. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Yang, Z. (2019). “Increasing returns to scale in energy-intensive sectors and its implications on climate change modelling.” Energy Economics, 83, 208216.Google Scholar
Yang, Z. and Menon, S.. (2013). “Tackling negatively correlated global and local stock externalities – an economic study of multiple gases issue in climate change.Climate Change Economics, 4(3), 121, doi: 10.1142/S2010007813500139.Google Scholar
Yang, Z., Wei, Y., and Mi, Z.. (2016). “Integrated assessment models for climate change.” In Wohl, Ellen, ed., Oxford Bibliographies in Environmental Science. New York: Oxford University Press. www.oxfordbibliographies.com/view/document/obo-9780199363445/obo-9780199363445-0043.xml/Google Scholar
Yi, S.-S. (1997). “Stable coalition structures with externalities.” Games and Economic Behavior, 20, 201–37.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Zili Yang, State University of New York at Binghamton
  • Book: The Environment and Externality
  • Online publication: 02 December 2020
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108762557.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Zili Yang, State University of New York at Binghamton
  • Book: The Environment and Externality
  • Online publication: 02 December 2020
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108762557.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Zili Yang, State University of New York at Binghamton
  • Book: The Environment and Externality
  • Online publication: 02 December 2020
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108762557.009
Available formats
×