Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T02:02:33.144Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

11 - British Economic Theory From Locke To Marshall

from PART I - SCIENCES OF THE SOCIAL TO THE LATE NINETEENTH CENTURY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 March 2008

Theodore M. Porter
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles
Dorothy Ross
Affiliation:
The Johns Hopkins University
Get access

Summary

The mercantilist pamphlets of the 1600s are commonly viewed as the first systematic writings on political economy, at least in the English language. While many of these works were unabashed promotions of merchant rights, historians have come to appreciate their rich array of insights on the topics of money, market forces, and the global economy. Two other important traditions of economic inquiry had emerged by the late seventeenth century, fostered by the rise of political freedom and the growth of a scientific culture. The first stems from John Locke’s Two Treatises of Government (1689–90), which addressed the problems of economic justice and distribution via the fundamental concepts of rights and property. Locke also privileged the economic contract in his state of nature and adumbrated a labor theory of value. The second tradition, exemplified by William Petty’s Political Arithmetic (1690), devised quantitative measures of economic phenomena, such as the national product of Ireland, the velocity and quantity of money, and the population of London. While Petty’s measures were bold and imprecise, they helped draw attention to aggregate phenomena and thus to new empirical relationships.

All three lines of thought spoke to the new capitalist system, which had transformed early modern Europe. As Joseph Schumpeter has rightly observed: “By the end of the fifteenth century most of the phenomena that we are in the habit of associating with that vague word Capitalism had put in their appearance,… [and] even then these phenomena were not all of them new.” He had in mind the prices of commodities and factors of production, such as the interest rate.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2003

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adam, SmithAn Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 2 vols., ed. Campbell, R. H. and Skinner, A. S. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976), vol. 1.Google Scholar
Alan, RyanJ. S. Mill (London: Routledge, 1974)Google Scholar
Bagehot, WalterThe Postulates of Political Economy,” in Economic Studies, ed. Hutton, R. H. (London: Longmans, Green, 1911).Google Scholar
Berg, MaxineThe Machinery Question and the Making of Political Economy, 1815–1848 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, VivienneAdam Smith’s Discourse: Canonicity, Commerce and Conscience (London: Routledge, 1994).Google Scholar
Collini, Stefan, Winch, Donald and John, JohnThat Noble Science of Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowherd, RaymondPolitical Economists and the English Poor Laws: An Historical Study of the Influence of Classical Economics on the Formation of Social Welfare Policy (Athens: Ohio University Press, 1977)Google Scholar
de Marchi, NeilThe Empirical Content and Longevity of Ricardian Economics,Economica, 37 (1970)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickey, LaurenceHistoricizing the ‘Adam Smith Problem’: Conceptual, Historiographical, and Textual Issues,Journal of Modern History, 58 (1986)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forbes, DuncanHume’s Philosophical Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1975)Google Scholar
Haakonssen, KnudThe Science of a Legislator: The Natural Jurisprudence of David Hume and Adam Smith (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacking, IanRepresenting and Intervening (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, DanielThe Inexact and Separate Science of Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilton, BoydCorn, Cash, Commerce: The Economic Politics of the Tory Governments, 1815–1830 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1977).Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O.The Passions and the Interests (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1977)Google Scholar
Hobsbawm, E. J.The Age of Capital, 1848–1875 (London: Abacus, 1975).Google Scholar
Hollander, SamuelThe Economics of Adam Smith (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1973).Google Scholar
Hollander, SamuelThe Economics of David Ricardo (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1979)Google Scholar
Hollander, SamuelThe Economics of Thomas Robert Malthus (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1997).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hont, IstvanThe ‘Rich Country–Poor Country’ Debate in Scottish Classical Political Economy,” in Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment, ed. Hont, Istvan and Ignatieff, Michael (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingrao, Bruna and Israel, IsraelThe Invisible Hand: Economic Equilibrium in the History of Science (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1990).Google Scholar
Kadish, AlonThe Oxford Economists in the Late Nineteenth Century (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1982)Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P.The Historical Background: Adam Smith and the Industrial Revolution,” in The Market and the State: Essays in Honour of Adam Smith, ed. Wilson, Thomas and Skinner, Andrew S. (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976).Google Scholar
Langer, Gary F.The Coming of Age of Political Economy, 1815–1825 (New York: Greenwood Press, 1987).Google Scholar
Maloney, JohnMarshall, Orthodoxy and the Professionalisation of Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985).Google Scholar
Maurice, DobbTheories of Value and Distribution since Adam Smith (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973)Google Scholar
Mirowski, PhilipMore Heat than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature’s Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Donnell, Roderick M.Keynes: Philosophy, Economics and Politics: The Philosophical Foundations of Keynes’s Thought and Their Influence on His Economics and Politics (London: Macmillan, 1989).Google Scholar
Peach, TerryInterpreting Ricardo (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Theodore M.The Rise of Statistical Thinking, 1820–1900 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986).Google Scholar
Schabas, MargaretMarket Contracts in the Age of Hume,” in Higgling: Transactors and Their Markets in the History of Economics, ed. Marchi, Neil and Morgan, Mary S. (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1994).Google Scholar
Schabas, MargaretParmenides and the Cliometricians,” in On the Reliability of Economic Models: Essays in the Philosophy of Economics, ed. Little, Daniel (Boston: Kluwer, 1995).Google Scholar
Schabas, MargaretVictorian Economics and the Science of the Mind,” in Victorian Science in Context, ed. Lightman, Bernard (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997).Google Scholar
Schabas, MargaretA World Ruled by Number: William Stanley Jevons and the Rise of Mathematical Economics (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A.A History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press, 1954).Google Scholar
Stigler, George J.Statistical Studies in the History of Economic Thought,” in his Essays in the History of Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1965).Google Scholar
Teichgraeber, RichardFree Trade and Moral Philosophy: Rethinking the Sources of Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1986)Google Scholar
Waterman, Anthony M. C.Revolution, Economics and Religion: Christian Political Economy, 1798–1833 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, FredPsychological Analysis and the Philosophy of John Stuart Mill (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1990)Google Scholar
Winch, DonaldAdam Smith’s Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, DonaldRiches and Poverty (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).Google Scholar
Wrigley, Edward A.Malthus’s Model of a Pre-industrial Economy,” in Malthus and His Time, ed. Turner, Michael (New York: St. Martin’s, 1986).Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×