Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T05:11:40.134Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The formal–informal dichotomy: Revisiting the debate on the agriculture–industry linkage

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Saumya Chakrabarti*
Affiliation:
Visva-Bharati Santiniketan, India
*
Saumya Chakrabarti, Associate Professor of Economics and Honorary Director, Agro-Economic Research Centre, Visva-Bharati University, Santiniketan, 731235, India. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Incorporation of the informal sector in the general Kaleckian framework of agriculture–industry linkage is the primary target of this article. We show that the agriculture–informal sector interaction is distinctly different from the agriculture–formal sector relationship. Although agriculture supports the formal sector only from the supply-side, it helps the informal sector by providing both demand- and supply-side inducements. Next, contrary to the general perception of formal–informal complementarities, we rather propose a fundamental conflict. This conflict arises in the presence of the food supply-constraint or the generic resource-constraint. Subsequently, with these theoretical perspectives, we show that policies that are beneficial for the formal sector, in fact, constrict the informal economy.

Type
Non-Symposium Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2013

Introduction

In the first two decades of left rule [rule of the Parliamentary-Left in West Bengal, India]… hawking was seen as a flexible strategy to manage urban poverty… Each of the petitions and policy reports thus relates to hawking as an inevitable fallout of urban poverty aggravated by the refugee influx. In the mid-1990s, however, ‘the tide turned’. Eager to regain the support of the urban middle classes, the… government of West Bengal made an all-out effort to make Bengal a safe investment destination. As a part of urban restructuring, in 1996, over a period of 2 weeks, in a well-planned and coordinated action called ‘Operation Sunshine’, municipal authorities and the police demolished all street-side stalls in Kolkata. In 1997, the state legislature brought about an amendment to the Kolkata Municipal Act that declared any form of unauthorised occupation of streets and pavements by hawkers a cognisable and non-bailable offence… But, within a few months, the hawkers began to reclaim their previous positions, mobilised by their unions, opposition party and even by the smaller constituents of the ruling Left Front… The government had to think again of ‘regulation’ of hawking as opposed to eviction and rehabilitation. (Reference BandyopadhyayBandyopadhyay, 2009: 18, emphasis added)

Thus,

… [t]he legitimate claim of capital to valorize and reproduce itself – and it can do so only by ‘accumulation by dispossession’ … – comes into conflict with the legitimate claim of petty producers to reproduce their subsistence. Here, two different economic systems are pitted against each other, each taking to the broader society its own moral claims – the capitalist economy representing itself as the vehicle of progress and development and the petty producers championing a human being’s inalienable right to survival. (Reference Sanyal and BhattacharyyaSanyal and Bhattacharyya, 2009: 42; emphasis added)

This article explores these ‘two different economic systems’ (the formal and the informal) explicating how they ‘are pitted against each other’. Its contribution is to construct a macroeconomic framework along Kaleckian lines, discussing these critical problems of contemporary development.

According to traditional development theory, economic development hinges on growth of a modern industrial sector. This modern industry-centric approach has been the dominant development discourse for years. However, since the early 1970s, it has been increasingly argued that such a ‘Lewisian’ path (Reference Lewis, Agarwala and SinghLewis, 1958 [1954]) is ineffective insofar as broad-based employment generation is concerned. On the other hand, studies have shown that the vast majority of the population in less developed countries (LDCs) has been engaged in non-agricultural activities outside the sphere of the modern/formal sector. Consequently, the focus has shifted towards the informal sector as capable of creating widespread employment and as the site of rehabilitation of surplus labour. It is argued that instead of being withered away through structural transformation (as indicated in Reference Hymer and ResnickHymer and Resnick, 1969), the informal sector is rather acting as an inclusive-development engine (Reference BangasserBangasser, 2000; Reference Lanjouw and LanjouwLanjouw and Lanjouw, 2001; Reference MellorMellor, 1976; Reference Ranis and StewartRanis and Stewart, 1993, Reference Ranis and Stewart1994; Reference Saith, Breman and MundleSaith, 1991). The nature and dynamics of the informal sector and the pattern of its relationship with other sectors have become important issues of research.

To understand the magnitude of the issue, we briefly present some facts regarding the informal sector in general and that of India in particular. First, the

… informal sector may be broadly characterized as consisting of units engaged in the production of goods or services with the primary objective of generating employment and incomes to the persons concerned. These units typically operate at low level of organization, with little or no division between labour and capital as factors of production and on a small scale. Labour relations, where they exist, are based mostly on casual employment, kinship, or personal or social relations rather than contractual arrangements with formal guarantees. (National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO), 2001: 1)

Second, we present a global scenario which clearly shows the importance of the informal sector and most importantly, its rising share! This is seen in Table 1.

Table 1. The informal economy as a percentage of GDP (un-weighted average).

GDP: gross domestic product; OECD: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

Now coming to India, we find the features summarised in Table 2.

Table 2. Share of the organised (formal) and the unorganised (informal) sector employment across industries in India (%).

Another very important trait of the Indian informal sector is that a very large part of it is linked with agriculture. Even the urban segment of the informal sector is heavily dependent on agriculture. In fact, this should not be a matter of surprise, as the overwhelming majority of informal sector enterprises belong to industry categories that are deeply integrated with agriculture and allied activities. Table 3, on industry groups, is self-explanatory.

Table 3. Major industry groups within the unorganised (informal) manufacturing sector of India.

If we identify some specific industries within the Indian informal manufacturing sector which account for more than 77% of the total number of informal manufacturing enterprises, we find the industry groups as in Table 3 according to the number of enterprises in descending order.

Thus, the significant size of the informal sector and its rising share even in times of growth make it an important issue for research. Not only the intra-sectoral characteristics, but also its relations with other sectors of the economy, become vital.

Consequently, the primary aim of the article is to analyse the relationship between the informal sector and other sectors, specifically the formal sector and agriculture. To do this, we place the informal sector in the general framework of agriculture–industry inter-linkage. This inclusion not only extends the traditional agriculture–industry linkage literature by bringing in the issues of agriculture–informal and formal–informal relations, but also helps to identify certain fundamental confusions that persist in the long-standing agriculture–industry literature. Next, contrary to the general perception that the formal and informal sectors are complementary to one another,Footnote 1 we posit that there is a fundamental conflict between them. Furthermore, this conflict points to an even more fundamental contradiction within the contemporary doctrine of ‘development management’.

A model of the formal–informal dichotomyFootnote 2

Agriculture–formal sector interaction

Review of the literature

  1. (a) Demand-side linkages: There is a vast literature that argues that agriculture provides a ‘home market’ for the formal industrial sector and thereby mitigates its ‘effective demand problem’ through the following channels:

  2. (1) Redistribution of income away from the net savers in the presence of differential propensities to consume formal sector output across different economic classes. This redistribution is initiated by a shift in the terms of trade between the agriculture and the formal sector (Reference Bose and RakshitBose, 1989; Reference RakshitRakshit, 1982; Reference TaylorTaylor, 1983).

  3. (2) Mutual exchange of surpluses between the formal sector and the agriculture. As agricultural production rises, more of its output is sold to the formal sector, raising agricultural income. Consequently, demand for the formal sector output rises (Reference Bhaduri and SkarsteinBhaduri and Skarstein, 2003; Reference Kaldor and KaldorKaldor, 1996 [1984]; Reference RajRaj, 1976).

  4. (b) Supply-side linkages: agriculture provides supply-side support for the formal industrial sector:

  5. (1) The agricultural sector supplies wage-goods and raw materials for the formal sector. These essential products are provided to the formal sector through simple inter-sectoral exchange (Reference Chakravarty and ChakravartyChakravarty, 1977; Reference Kalecki and OsiatynskiKalecki, 1993 [1954]).

  6. (2) Food-constraint pushes up food prices in the face of growing demand from the formal sector, which leads to either an upward wage-price spiral (Reference Kalecki and OsiatynskiKalecki, 1993 [1954]) or deterioration of terms of trade for the formal sector resulting in a ‘profit squeeze’ (as in Reference Ricardo and SraffaRicardo, 1815). Conversely, a cheap and abundant food supply ensures transfer of surplus from the agriculture to the formal sector (Reference PreobrazhenskyPreobrazhensky, 1965 [1926]; Reference Ranis and FeiRanis and Fei, 1961).

Our departures

(a) We depart from the assumption of the presence of a redistributive channel which is supposed to boost demand for formal sector output. Consider a situation where all the contending classes (capitalists and workers in the formal sector and farmers) form separate but equally strong lobbies. In such a situation, these classes can collude, the political expression of which is a ‘coalition government’. In a regime of ‘coalition politics’, each of the contending groups tries to maintain its relative socio-economic position. Therefore, we assume rigidity of the formal sector real-wage and product-wage and, hence, rigidity of the agriculture–formal sector terms of trade. However, we will relax this assumption of rigidity of distributive parameters in our third section.

Empirical evidence, as captured through Tables 4 and 5, using Indian data, supports our assumption of distributive inflexibilities. We have calculated mean and coefficient of variation from the series of data on agriculture–non-agriculture terms of trade and on non-agricultural real wages adjusted by using consumer price index. We find out that the decadal fluctuations of all these data sets have been reduced considerably after the 1970s.

Table 4. Index of TOT between agriculture and non-agriculture from 1982–1983 to 2005–2006 (base: triennium ending 1990–1991 = 100).

TOT: terms of trade.

Table 5. Index of annual real non-agricultural wage rates in terms of consumer price index of industrial workers (1973–1974 to 2003–2004).

(b) Next, we assume the absence of capital flows between the agriculture and the formal sector. Essentially, this means balanced trade between these two sectors. Balanced trade is assumed to remove the possibility of extracting a trade surplus by any sector from any other.

(c) Now we come to our third contention. Our claim is that simple exchange with balanced trade between the agriculture and the formal sector cannot create any extra demand for the latter. In fact, a popular perception is that a bumper crop facilitates industrial revival because it leads to an increase in income or purchasing power in the agrarian sector, raising demand for the formal sector goods.Footnote 3 This argument is based on the implicit assumption of constant terms of trade. The assumption is necessary because a bumper crop, ceteris paribus, will change the terms of trade against agriculture. This, in turn, will reduce the purchasing power of the agricultural sector, given inelastic demand for food from the formal sector.

However, even if we allow for the assumption of constant terms of trade, increased agricultural output is translated into actual additional purchasing power only after it is sold to the formal sector. Moreover, the purchase of additional agricultural output by the formal sector means a leakage from the expenditure on the formal sector incurred by that sector itself. This reduces the demand for formal sector output. On the other hand, when additional income that accrues to the agricultural sector through sale of additional food to the formal sector is, in turn, spent on formal sector products, demand for formal sector commodities rises. However, ultimately there is no impact on demand for formal sector output, as the two effects counter-balance each other.

Together, all these departures and contentions imply a complete absence of all the agriculture–formal sector demand-side interactions discussed in the literature.

When agriculture experiences a bumper harvest, even though it is capable of supplying more food to the formal sector, the additional food fails to be absorbed by the latter because of the lack of any consequent rise in demand for formal sector output, that could push up its production. Lack of rise in complementary demand for formal sector product from any of the inside or outside sources will restrict increase in demand for food as well. Thus, the formal sector and agriculture simultaneously suffer from the ‘realisation crisis’ (Reference Bhaduri and SkarsteinBhaduri and Skarstein, 2003; Reference Chakrabarti, Acharyya and MoitraChakrabarti, 2001, Reference Chakrabarti2011). On the other hand, expansion of the formal sector crucially depends on an exogenous supply of food, absence of which triggers off either profit squeeze in the formal sector or a price-wage spiral across the economy. Thus, even if agriculture cannot be the ‘home market’ for the formal sector, it provides crucial supply-side support.

Kalecki: concept of ‘domestic exports’

We assume, for the time being, that the primary problem for the formal sector is lack of effective demand while the agricultural sector’s supply of food to industry is sufficient.Footnote 4 In such a situation, the only option left for the expansion of the demand-constrained formal sector in a closed economy is the path of government intervention, given agriculture’s inability to provide a ‘home market’ for it.

The ‘home market’ for industry is defined as any non-industrial sector within the national economy vis-a-vis which domestic industry can enjoy an ‘export surplus’. The agrarian sector cannot be this ‘home market’ since it cannot finance its trade deficit vis-a-vis industry, given that the agrarian sector of the developing countries in general lacks the power to issue any financial asset like shares and bonds. Hence, the government sector is the proper candidate to play the role of ‘home market’. It can purchase goods from the industrial sector, given its monopoly power over printing money. In its trade with government, domestic industry ‘exports’ goods against ‘import’ of money. This ‘export’ which is, by definition, an ‘export surplus’ is what Kalecki terms ‘domestic exports’ (Reference KaleckiKalecki, 1971 [1934]).

Kalecki: agricultural supply-constraint

Kaleckian analysis rules out agriculture as a possible ‘home market’ for industrial product. However, there is clear recognition of agriculture as the source of supply of wage good or ‘food’ to the industrial sector. In other words, Reference Kalecki and OsiatynskiKalecki (1993 [1954]) recognises that agriculture may act as a supply-constraint on industry.

Now, given this whole context, we posit a capitalistic formal sector and try to capture its relationship with agriculture. We find that, given our departures/assumptions, a rise in agricultural production creates the potential for formal sector expansion only from the supply-side. However, on the demand-side, realisation of this potential without involving a change in distribution of income requires adequate adjustment of real government expenditure on formal sector output. Thus, this domestic export not only mitigates the problem of effective demand for formal sector output but also removes the realisation problem of agriculture. Our initial objective is to unite the two in a single framework and to develop the framework analytically through the incorporation of the informal sector as mentioned above. This incorporation of the informal sector will be found to generate crucial insights for the discourse on agriculture–industry linkage. On the other hand, this comprehensive framework also brings in the issues of informal–agriculture and formal–informal relations and thereby helps in understanding the nature and locus of the informal sector itself – the main target of this article.

Basic features of our economy with both the formal and informal sectors

  1. (a) We identify four sectors: a capitalistic formal industrial sector (formal sector), a non-capitalistic agriculture producing ‘food’, a non-capitalistic non-agricultural informal sector and the government.

  2. (b) The formal sector is characterised by excess capacity, unemployment and mark-up pricing. Price is cost-determined and output is demand-determined.

  3. (c) All profits in the formal sector are saved whereas all wages are consumed. A part of wage-income is spent on food so that there is the possibility of the formal sector facing agricultural supply-constraint.

  4. (d) A fixed marketable surplus of food represents the agricultural supply-constraint for the formal as well as the informal sectors. Consequently, the price of food is demand-determined. The total capacity is given in the short run due to natural, technological and also institutional rigidities.Footnote 5

  5. (e) Contrary to the basis of the formal sector being a capital–labour dichotomy and the accumulation motive being the driving force for production, the non-agricultural informal sector is characterised by the consumption motive – the motive of satisfaction of basic needs (Reference ChatterjeeChatterjee, 2008; Reference SanyalSanyal, 2007: 211–213),Footnote 6 self-employment and absence of ‘capital’.Footnote 7 Moreover, there is surplus labour. It essentially comprises ‘petty commodity producers’ who produce for the sole purpose of consumption and use only indigenous resources. We can also refer to the International Labour Organisation (ILO) definition of the informal sector (Reference BangasserBangasser, 2000) for most of these characteristics (see also NSSO, 2001: 1–2).

  6. (f) The informal sector is self-sufficient in terms of both implements and non-food consumption. However, like the formal sector, it has to depend on agriculture for food which is obtained with the proceeds received through the sale of net output (net of requirements for self-consumption and reproduction) to agriculture itself.

  7. (g) Aggregate agricultural income is earned by selling marketable surplus in the combined food-market, which is purchased by the agents of both formal and informal sectors. These two sectors purchase food at a single price. This income, in turn, is spent on the products of both formal and informal sectors. The division of income depends on the relevant terms of trade.

  8. (h) There is balanced trade between agriculture and informal sector, on one hand and between agriculture and the formal sector, on the other.

  9. (i) The government purchases the formal sector products by money creation. It constitutes the ‘domestic exports’ for the formal sector and relaxes the ‘effective-demand-constraint’ by providing the ‘home market’.

  10. (j) The distribution of income among different classes is determined exogenously and there is social resistance to any drastic change in this pattern.

  11. (k) We assume away any interaction between the formal and informal sectors. As a very small part of the informal sector is able to interact with the sophisticated formal sector, this seems to be a plausible assumption.Footnote 8

  12. (l) Ours is a short-run analysis, and we assume a closed economy set-up.

Thus, the basic structure of the model economy can be represented through the flowchart in Figure 1.

Figure 1. Structure of the model economy.

Working of our model

Interaction among formal sector, agriculture and government.Footnote 9

Excess capacity in the formal sector implies a given labour-output ratio l, and we take l = 1 through an appropriate choice of unit. Hence

(1) L = Y

Here L and Y are the formal sector’s total employment and output, respectively.

Using equation (1), the marked-up price (p) over unit wage-cost (w) in the formal sector can be represented as

(2) p = ( 1 + τ ) w

Here τ is a constant mark-up.

Workers’ demand for a targeted real-wage in the formal sector is given by

(3) w / p f = β

Here pf is the food-price and β is a positive constant.

Using equations (2) and (3), real-wage in terms of the formal sector output and terms of trade between agriculture and the formal sector can be written, respectively, as

(3.1) ( w / p ) = 1 / ( 1 + τ ) = α

(3.2) ( p f / p ) = 1 / [ β ( 1 + τ ) ] = θ

α and θ are exogenously determined.

The basic income–expenditure accounting equation for the formal sector using the features listed in the section ‘Basic features of our economy with both the formal and informal sectors’ can be written as

(4) Total formal sector output = ( Total formal sector wage - bill in terms of formal sector output ) 10 + ( Total formal sector investment in terms of formal sector output ) + ( Total government expenditure on formal sector output )

We assume that real investment (I) in the formal sector and nominal government expenditure (G) on the formal sector output are exogenously given at I0 and G0. These assumptions along with equations (1), (3.1) and (3.2) transform equation (4) as follows

(5) Y = L = ( w / p ) . L + I 0 + ( p f / p ) . ( G 0 / p f ) = α . Y + I 0 + θ . ( G 0 / p f )

Solution of equation (5) gives

(6) L * = [ I 0 + θ . ( G 0 / p f ) ] / ( 1 α )

Now, food-demand per worker employed in the formal sector, given equations (3.1) and (3.2), can be expressed as

(7) a f = a f ( w / p , p f / p ) = a f 0 ( a positive constant )

Hence, aggregate food-demand from the formal sector is

(8) D f = a f 0 . L * = a f 0 . [ I 0 + θ . ( G 0 / p f ) ] / ( 1 α )

There is an inverse relation between food-price and aggregate food-demand from the formal sector. As food-price falls, the money-wage is reduced, reducing formal sector price as well. Consequently, given the volume of nominal domestic exports, the real domestic exports rise, raising the level of formal sector employment following equation (8) and, hence, increasing the demand for food.

Now, we assume that for the time being a fixed amount of marketable surplus of food is supplied to the formal sector,Footnote 11 which can be written as

(9) F = F 0

Using equations (8) and (9), the food-market equilibrium condition is

(10) F 0 = D f = a f 0 . [ I 0 + θ . ( G 0 / p f ) ] / ( 1 α )

Equation (10) determines the equilibrium food-price p f * . It can be represented in a simple food-market demand–supply diagram with linear approximation (Figure 2).

Figure 2. Food-market equilibrium representing the agriculture–formal sector interaction.

The equilibrium food-price, p f * , determines equilibrium money-wage, w*, in the formal sector, given equation (3). w*, in turn, determines equilibrium price, p*, the formal sector output-price, given equation (2). Consequently, the equilibrium size of real government expenditure, g*, is endogenously determined as g* = G0/p*. This equilibrium level of real domestic exports, in turn, can determine the equilibrium levels of employment and output in the formal sector using equation (5).

Corollary I:

We can analyse the effect of an expansionary fiscal policy without any change in agricultural production. We assume an increase in nominal government expenditure on formal sector output. The effect of this policy is illustrated in Figure 3.

Figure 3. Effect of expansionary policy on the formal sector represented through food-market equilibria.

We start with the food-market equilibrium position E1 with equilibrium food-price p f * Now, G rises, with F = F0. This leads to a rise in pf. The process continues until one arrives at p f * such that the size of real domestic exports and, hence, the equilibrium levels of employment and output in the formal sector shrink back to their original values.

Corollary II:

It follows that given the amount of per capita food consumption in the formal sector, a bumper harvest creates a potential for formal sector expansion. However, realisation of this potential requires an adequate increase in the value of real domestic exports. Such a case can be presented in terms of Figure 4.

Figure 4. Effects of a bumper harvest on the formal sector shown through food-market equilibria.

Consider a case of downward flexibility of the formal sector money-wage. Let us assume a bumper harvest, raising the value of F to F1. As a result, the equilibrium food-price falls from p f * to p f * . Given the distributive factors, this reduces w and, subsequently, p also falls. This, in turn, expands the size of real domestic exports and, hence, the levels of formal sector output and employment rise. Correspondingly, we get the movement of food-market equilibrium from E1 to E2.

However, with downward rigidity of w, a fall in pf due to a bumper harvest does not automatically increase real domestic exports. In that case, adequate expansion of the home market can only be achieved by a proper expansion of nominal government expenditure. The required expansion is such that the food-market clears at p f * and the equilibrium position moves to E3.

Interaction between agriculture and the informal sector

Let us now turn to the agriculture–informal sector interactions separately from the agriculture–formal sector linkage as discussed above. This separation is a hypothetical one, which will be relaxed subsequently.

First, from the condition of labour-surplus in the informal sector, we can specify constancy of food requirement rate at the minimum subsistence level. Hence, afi = a. This is the constant per capita food consumption rate in the informal sector.

The absence of fixed (limiting) capital in the informal sector implies fixity of the labour-output ratio (li). Thus, li = b, a constant.

We also assume without loss of generality that the fraction of intra-sectoral utilisation of output in the informal sector for self-consumption and reproduction (βi) is constant. Hence, βi = c, a constant.

All these combined together indicate that the real average cost of production in the informal sector due to food and non-food consumption and use of implements and raw materials is structurally determined and is constant. Furthermore, as there is no surplus, the food and non-food consumption-cost and implements and raw materials costs solely determine the informal sector product-price. This price can be expressed as pi = [pf.a.b + pi.c]. Here pi is the informal sector output-price and pf is the food-price as before. Assuming, b = 1 (for simplicity), we have

(11) p i / p f = a / ( 1 c ) = 1 / t ( say )

Thus, absence of fixed capital and the assumption of surplus labour along with the fixity of the fraction of intra-sectoral utilisation of output jointly imply a given terms of trade between the informal sector and agriculture.Footnote 12 Moreover, at these given terms of trade, the supply of net output, s, for the informal sector will be perfectly elastic and hence its value is demand-determined. Consequently, the s curve will be horizontal on the ‘s–pi/pf’ plane (Figure 5). Furthermore, a particular amount of food supply to the informal sector always induces a definite volume of trade between agriculture and the informal sector. As the perfectly elastic s and, hence, the informal sector output, y, and the corresponding employment, m, are demand-determined, the equilibrium values of these variables are solely set by the portion of marketable surplus of food or, more precisely, that of agricultural income transacted with the informal sector.

Figure 5. Informal sector–market equilibrium representing the agriculture–informal sector interaction.

As the supply of informal sector output is perfectly elastic and as it is determined only by the food supply, we get a crucial result that demand for food from the informal sector is also perfectly elastic. Agriculture does not face any demand problem so far as the informal sector is concerned. Thus, we have a sharp dichotomy between the agriculture–formal sector and the agriculture–informal sector inter-linkages.

Agriculture–informal sector and agriculture–formal sector interactions: a fundamental contrast

In our framework, agriculture acts as a source of food and raw materials and of demand for the informal sector. However, as we bring in the issue of agricultural supply, we implicitly incorporate in our analysis the question of the realisation of income by farmers. Only if the potential income is realised, is there the possibility of generating demand for the informal sector products. In our analysis, the crucial characteristic of the consumption motive for both the informal sector petty-producers and the (non-capitalistic) farmers closes this gap. There is no realisation problem for agriculture so far as the informal sector is concerned.

However, the absorption of agricultural surplus in the formal sector is not at all guaranteed. Agriculture may suffer from a ‘realisation crisis’ so far as its interaction with the formal sector is concerned. Mere supply of agricultural commodities does not automatically imply their sale in the capitalistic formal economy, as production in this sector is organised with accumulation motive and not for consumption as such.

A capitalistic economy would not invest and grow unless there is any (ex ante) guarantee of absorption of its ‘surplus’; mere (equivalent) exchange of its output with inputs like food and agro-raw materials cannot serve that purpose. If the capitalistic formal sector suffers from any inherent problem of insufficient demand and if no external support (such as net exports or government expenditure) is forthcoming, the simple supply of agricultural surplus can ensure demand for only an equivalent amount of formal sector output without assuring the absorption of the ‘surplus’ per se. Because of this non-realisability of ‘surplus value’, simple supply of agricultural surplus cannot induce capitalistic expansion.

Back to our model

From our preceding analyses, we know that the value of aggregate demand for informal sector output is equal to the part of aggregate agricultural income that is spent on it.

Hence

(12) p i . d = e . ( p f . F )

Here d signifies the aggregate demand for the informal sector output and e is the fraction of the aggregate agricultural income spent on the informal sector output or that of the aggregate marketable surplus of food transacted with this informal sector.Footnote 13

From the basic feature (g) of the section ‘Basic features of our economy with both the formal and informal sectors’, we know that aggregate agricultural income is earned by selling a marketable surplus which is purchased by the agents of both formal and informal sectors. This income, in turn, is spent on the products of formal and informal sectors. As we have formulated earlier, the division of this income depends on the relevant terms of trade. Hence, we can write

(13) e = e ( p f / p , p f / p i ) ; with e 1 < 0 and e 2 > 0

But, putting equations (3.2) and (11) into equation (13), we get

(14) e = e 0

Now, rearranging equation (12), substituting equations (14) and (11) into it and assuming a fixed marketable surplus of food, F0, we have

(15) d = ( p f / p i ) . e 0 . F 0 = t . e 0 . F 0 = d 0

This gives a vertical d0 curve on the ‘d–pi/pf’ plane (Figure 5).

From our characterisation of s (the net output in informal sector) as demand-determined and using equation (15), we get equilibrium s as

(16) s * = d 0 = t . e 0 . F 0

This equilibrium is shown graphically in Figure 5.

As s is the net output in the informal sector, gross output (y) and employment (m) can be derived, given c (the constant fraction of the informal sector output utilised intra-sectorally).

Now, in the presence of an informal sector, only the fraction (1 − e) of the aggregate food supply is directed to the formal sector instead of the full F0. Thus, the formal sector faces a shrinkage of food supply to [(1 − e0).F0] from F0 (which would have been the supply of food to the formal sector in the absence of informal sector). This supply-side squeeze reduces the formal sector’s potential employment and output. Contrarily, if we assume that given an informal sector–agriculture complex, the formal sector–agriculture composite is incorporated into the economy, the former circuit gets constricted. The introduction of the formal sector siphons off crucial food supply from the informal sector and destroys it. On the other hand, the formal sector simultaneously fills the shortage of non-food owing to the contraction of informal sector through a supply of formal sector goods and services to agriculture (exactly as in Reference Hymer and ResnickHymer and Resnick, 1969).

Thus, we have a basic conflict between the formal and informal sectors in terms of employment and output in the presence of (the generic) agricultural supply-constraint.

In our above analysis, the two complexes, the agriculture–formal sector linkage and the agriculture–informal sector interactions, are treated as separate entities. This was essential to clarify certain crucial characteristics of these two sets of interactions in the context of the centuries old debate on agriculture–industry linkage. It was also necessary to explicate the fundamental conflict between the formal and informal sectors. But we need to relax this hypothetical segregation in order to analyse certain policy issues.

Formal–informal conflict: ‘Accumulation by dispossession’

First, we modify some of the crucial assumptions of our basic framework pertaining to the formal sector by considering certain contemporary changes in the developing economies.

As the population engaged in the formal sector, both workers and capitalists, spend a very small fraction of their income on food, it is quite likely that the wage is set independently of the price of food. Hence, from a short-run macro perspective, treating the money-wage as fixed is not a strong assumption (Reference Bose and RakshitBose, 1989; Reference TaylorTaylor, 1983). Even if the price of food varies, the money-wage remains the same. The price of formal sector output, as before, is set by imposing a mark-up over wage. Hence, this price is also fixed (Reference Bose and RakshitBose, 1989; Reference TaylorTaylor, 1983).

A change in food-price has the following consequences. On one side, given the assumption of fixed per capita food consumption by the workers, if the food-price rises, the expenditure on formal sector output will fall. However, under the assumption of formal sector–agriculture balanced trade, this leakage of demand from the workers is just counterbalanced by the increased income and hence expenditure on formal sector output by the farmers. Thus, a food-wage adjustment has no demand-side impact on the formal sector.

As the money-wage is assumed to be fixed, say at w0, the formal sector price p is fixed, say at p0. Hence, the product-wage in terms of formal sector output is fixed at (w0/p0) = 1/(1 + τ) = α; but the food-wage-rate, (w0/pf), is now a variable. Moreover, terms of trade between agriculture and the formal sector, (pf/p0), is also a variable.

Now, given the earlier notations and the assumptions w = w0 and p = p0 and given that pf/p0 is a variable now, equation (6) is modified (through modifications of equation (5)) in the following way

(17) L * = ( I 0 + g 0 ) / ( 1 α )

Food-demand per worker employed in the formal sector has been assumed as a f 0 , a positive constant; the relatively well-off formal sector population consumes a fixed amount of food per capita, irrespective of real income. Hence, food-demand from the formal sector can be written as

(18) D f = a f 0 . [ ( I 0 + g 0 ) / ( 1 α ) ] = D f 0

This gives us the vertical food-demand curve for the formal sector, that is, Df on the ‘Df–pf’ plane as in Figure 6.

Figure 6. Simultaneous effects of expansionary policies on the formal and informal sectors represented through food-market equilibria for the formal sector and through the informal sector-market equilibria.

Next, we turn to food supply. Until now we have considered ‘e’ to be exogenous. We need to relax this assumption to explicate the probable impacts of a change in the terms of trade. Putting equation (11) and the condition, p = p0 into equation (13), we have

(19) e = e ( p f / p 0 , t ) , with e 1 < 0

Consequently, with equation (19), the equilibrium condition (16) changes to

(20) s * = d = t . e ( p f / p 0 ) . F 0 = d ( p f / p 0 , F ) , with d 1 < 0 , d 2 > 0 .

This implies a leftward shift of the vertical informal sector demand curve d, drawn on the ‘d–pi/pf’ plane, owing to a rise in pf (Figure 6). Furthermore, equilibrium condition (20) is also shown in Figure 6.

Given (e.F) as the fraction of food supply that is transacted with the informal sector and given equation (19) and the condition F = F0, we can write food supply to the informal sector as

(21) f = e ( p f / p 0 ) . F 0 = f ( p f / p 0 , F ) , with f 1 < 0 , f 2 > 0 .

Given equation (21), food supply to the formal sector can be rewritten as

(22) F f = F 0 f = [ 1 e ( p f / p 0 ) ] . F 0 = F f ( p f / p 0 , F ) , with F f 1 > 0 , F f 2 > 0

It implies a positively sloped Ff curve on the ‘Ff–pf’ plane (Figure 6).

Consequently, equations (18) and (22) modify the equilibrium condition (10) as

(23) F f ( p f / p 0 , F ) = D f 0 = a f 0 . [ ( I 0 + g 0 ) / ( 1 α ) ]

This equilibrium condition (23) modifies Figures 1 to 3, by making the Ff (earlier F) curve positively sloped instead of being vertical. The fundamental difference is that, now expansionary thrust is effective in expanding the formal sector. However, we will see that it happens only at the cost of expropriation of the informal sector.

The substitutability of food supply to the formal and informal sectors (given the overall potential) can be captured through a production-possibility-frontier (PPF). Assuming perfect substitutability, the PPF becomes a straight line (Figure 6).

Hence

(24) F 0 = ( F f + f )

Using equations (20)(24), we can formulate Figure 6.

Next, we take up some policy issues, given these formal sector–agriculture–informal sector interactions as represented by Figure 6.

  1. (a) Let us start from the initial equilibrium points E and e generated through the interactions between the sets of demand and supply curves (Df, Ff) and (d, s), respectively, and mediated by the PPF. Now, we assume an increase in g0 (or I0) pushing up Df to, say, Df′. Consequently, the food-market equilibrium for formal sectoragriculture interactions shifts to E′ moving along the Ff curve raising the equilibrium food-price from pf to pf′ and, hence, drawing resources towards the formal sector. This squeezes resources for the informal sector. On the other hand, a rise in pf shifts d to the left (d′) following equation (20). Hence, we get the new informal sector equilibrium point e′ through the interaction between s and d′. Thus, expansionary boosts to the formal sector are effective (unlike in Figure 3), but that happens at the cost of contraction of the informal sector.

    As the formal sector expands, it drives up the food-price, which, in turn, raises informal sector prices, given the agriculture–informal sector terms of trade. However, the formal sector price remains the same, given the money-wage and the mark-up. Hence, the formal–informal relative-price falls, reorienting (induced) demand and, thus, food supply away from the informal sector. Modernisation of the economy through expansion of the formal sector is not at all a cost less phenomenon. And it is quite possible that the social costs are higher than the corresponding benefits, not only in the short run but also in the long run.

  2. (b) Contractionary effects on the informal sector due to formal sector expansion, as above, could be checked, only if a simultaneous and an appropriate increase in aggregate food supply F is ensured (that can be captured by an appropriate outward shift of PPF as shown in Figure 6) counterbalancing the impacts of food-drain to the formal sector. This could be materialised when formal sector expansion takes place only in conjunction with a bumper harvest so that food supply rises appropriately and the new formal sectoragriculture equilibrium is at E″. Food-price does not change and, hence, the informal sector demand (d) does not shift from the initial position. The formal sector expands without changes in the informal sector output and employment.

  3. (c) However, the impact of an increase in food supply, say through a bumper harvest, without any simultaneous expansionary demand-boost for the formal sector is revealing. As food supply rises, PPF shifts out and food supply to the formal sector, that is, Ff shifts to Ff′. Consequently, the food-price pf falls to pf′′ shifting out the informal sector demand d to d″. Thus, the informal sector expands, without any effect on the formal sector. Though food supply rises, reducing food-price, the formal sector price cannot fall due to money-wage rigidity. Thus, the formal sectorinformal sector relative-price rises, raising the (induced) demand for and, hence, supply of food to the informal sector. As food prices fall and there is redistribution of real income to the formal sector workers away from the farmers, workers’ demand for the formal sector output rises. But farmers’ demand for this formal sector output falls by an equivalent amount under balanced trade. Hence, we do not have any effect on the formal sector.

  4. (d) Hitherto, to integrate the formal sector–agriculture–informal sector interactions and, hence, to capture the variability of the fraction of aggregate agricultural income spent on the informal sector (i.e. variability of e), we assumed fixity of w and p. But we could make w and p flexible and fix pf and hence, pi, given the informal sectoragriculture terms of trade. The rigidity of pf is also reasonable, given the practice of price-support to the farmers and price-regulation in the open-market or ‘fair-pricing’ through a public distribution system in the developing countries. But under such an altered assumption, the above-mentioned policy effects are reversed. When there is an excess demand for formal sector output under expansionary policy, formal sector prices rises. This raises the formal sectorinformal sector relative-price inducing demand-leakage, and food supply increase towards the informal sector. Thus, the formal sector ultimately contracts. Hence, the policy of fixing pf should be objected to by the formal sector. This is corroborated by the contemporary reaction against agricultural price-fixing under the pretext of ensuring efficiency through the ‘free-market’.

Conclusion

The first objective of this article has been to show that the formal sector–agriculture relation is distinctly different from the informal sector–agriculture linkage. Second, contrary to the claims in a vast literature that agriculture constitutes the home market for the formal sector, it has been shown that agriculture provides only supply-side support for the latter and cannot be the home market.

The most important objective of this article was to show an inherent conflict between the formal and informal sectors originating from the crucial condition of economic resource-sharing. Furthermore, as the formal sector expands, we have shown that it squeezes the informal sector by dragging out resources. On the other hand, this destruction of the informal sector itself creates the ‘home market’ for the formal sector.Footnote 14 Thus, the processes of modernisation boosting capital accumulation in the formal sector create the mass of dispossessed, and we have intensification of the formal–informal conflict owing to ‘accumulation by dispossession’ (Reference HarveyHarvey, 2003).

Acknowledgements

The article is dedicated to the Late Kalyan Sanyal, the author’s PhD supervisor. The author is also grateful to Arup Mallik, Sarmila Banerjee, Aparajita Mukherjee, Anirban Kundu and Gary Mongiovi for valuable inputs. He also thanks the anonymous referees for important suggestions. However, the usual disclaimer that the author accepts full responsibility for errors and omissions applies.

Earlier versions of this article were presented at the Burdwan and Jadavpur Universities, India; University of Newcastle, Australia; and at The Max Planck Institute for Economics, Germany. Comments from conference participants are gratefully acknowledged

Funding

This research received no specific grant from any funding agency in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.

Footnotes

1. ‘The goal must be to make these informal activities part of a growing formal sector that provides decent jobs, incomes and protection, and can trade in the international system’ (World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalization, 2004: 61).

2. In this context, we refer to Reference Chakrabarti, Acharyya and MoitraChakrabarti (2001, Reference Chakrabarti2009, Reference Chakrabarti2011) and Reference Chakrabarti and KunduChakrabarti and Kundu (2009). These frameworks have been modified, extended and developed substantially. We need to introduce and reorient these frameworks for the sake of continuity of analysis and, most importantly, for a comparative study of agriculture–formal sector and agriculture–informal sector linkages.

3. ‘The second piece of good news is the monsoon has been very good … with a bountiful harvest, and with the associated activities like animal husbandry, poultry, also picking up, you can see a lot more value in the rural areas, which will help sentiment and growth’. (Reserve Bank of India’s Governor R. Rajan at Harvard Business School on 16 October 2013. The Indian Express, 2013)

4. According to many researchers, unemployment and underemployment in underdeveloped countries result from supply shortages rather than from deficiency of effective demand. But, at the same time, low demand can be an additional cause of complication, and this article aims to concentrate on this latter issue along with the former problem. In fact, we intend to address both the issues of demand and supply shortages in this article. And here lies the novelty of our approach.

5. In fact, this agricultural supply-constraint represents the generic resource-limitation. To capture the whole lot of resources required for both the formal and informal sectors, we are using ‘food’ as a proxy. Essentially, the formal and informal sectors share different types of economic resources like food, agro-raw materials, minerals, water resources, forest products and, most importantly, physical space that is very crucial for densely populated countries of Asia and even Latin America. Across many countries of the Third World, the bone of contention between the formal/centre and its outside/informal has been the ‘water–forest–land’ resources (jaal-jangal-jameen).

Although in the context of a specific country, some of these resources could be non-binding, given the option of international trade, these are essentially binding at the global level (e.g. global food-shortage – a possibility in near future with full entry of Chinese and Indian consumers into the global market, non-renewable resource constraint across the globe, etc.). Moreover, most of the resources (jaal-jangal-jameen) are not even tradable. Incorporation of such resource-use by both the formal and informal sectors could be an extension of our following analysis, but it will only technically enrich our models without contributing much in terms of the fundamental message of this article: the global supply-side conflict between the capital/centre/formal-sector and its outside/non-capital, that is, the traditional and informal sectors.

6. ‘The fundamental logic that underlies the operations of corporate capital is further accumulation of capital, usually signified by the maximisation of profit. For (the informal sector), while profit is not irrelevant, it is dominated by another logic – that of providing the livelihood needs of those working in the units’. (Reference ChatterjeeChatterjee, 2008: 58)

7. Simple tools produced in the informal sector itself are used. However, these means of production cannot be ‘capital’ because of the absence of the profit motive (Reference BhaduriBhaduri, 1986). More importantly, as these rudimentary tools are produced indigenously, they do not limit the production capacity unlike the case of fixed (limiting) capital of the modern sector.

8. ‘ … while some informal workers provide low-cost inputs to global production systems, the majority are excluded from the opportunities of globalisation and confined to restricted markets’ (World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalisation, 2004: 60).

9. More comprehensive analyses of this particular issue can be found in our own earlier works: Reference Chakrabarti, Acharyya and MoitraChakrabarti (2001, Reference Chakrabarti2009, Reference Chakrabarti2011) and Reference Chakrabarti and KunduChakrabarti and Kundu (2009). We need to introduce and reorient these frameworks for the sake of continuity of analysis.

10. A part of the wage-bill though spent on food, it fully comes back to the formal sector as agriculture–formal sector trade is balanced.

11. However, only a fraction of food supply should go to the formal sector in presence of the informal sector as we see below. But, for the time being, we assume away such a presence of informal sector. As we introduce the informal sector, the relevant conditions will be modified.

12. While agriculture–formal sector terms of trade is fixed through class-bargaining, agriculture–informal sector terms of trade become rigid following the logic of survival. As the requirement of survival binds the agriculture–informal sector terms of trade, it cannot change. But, the other terms of trade may change depending on the structure of the economy.

13. As we have a single food-market and agriculture–informal sector and agriculture–formal sector balanced trades, e represents fraction of both agricultural income and marketable surplus of food transacted with the informal sector. This is a demand-driven outcome and the division of agricultural supply is just a result of that.

14. This reminds us of ‘primitive accumulation’ (Reference MarxMarx, 1958) in spite of crucial differences in the historical processes. It is quoted by Reference LeninLenin (1972 [1899]: 42) from Marx (Capital, vol. 1) that ‘(t)he expropriation and eviction of a part of the agricultural population not only set free for industrial capital the laborers, their means of subsistence, and material for labor; it also created the home market’. As ‘primitive accumulation’ proceeds and agricultural and non-agricultural population gets expropriated, a void is created which is filled up with the products of the upcoming capitalistic industry. ‘Thus, from the standpoint of abstract theory, the ruin of the small producers in a society of developing commodity economy and capitalism means … the creation … of the home market’.

References

Bandyopadhyay, R (2009) Hawkers’ movement in Kolkata, 1975–2007. Economic and Political Weekly 64(17): 116119.Google Scholar
Bangasser, PE (2000) The ILO and the informal sector: an institutional history. ILO employment paper (Informal Economy Resource Database), Geneva. Available at: http://www.ilo.org/ (accessed 24 October 2013).Google Scholar
Batini, N, Kim, Y, Levine, P, et al . (2011) Informal labor and credit markets: A survey. Working paper no. 2011-94, November. New Delhi, India: National Institute of Public Finance and Policy.Google Scholar
Bhaduri, A (1986) Macroeconomics: The Dynamics of Commodity Production. New Delhi, India: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhaduri, A, Skarstein, R (2003) Effective demand and the terms of trade in a dual economy: a Kaldorian perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics 27(4): 583595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bose, A (1989) Short period equilibrium in a less developed economy. In: Rakshit, M (ed.) Studies in the Macroeconomics of Developing Countries. New Delhi, India: Oxford University Press, pp. 2641.Google Scholar
Chakrabarti, S (2001) Agriculture-industry relation: aggregate demand, supply constraint and the concept of ‘domestic exports’. In: Acharyya, R, Moitra, B (eds) Effects of Globalization on Industry and Environment. New Delhi, India: Lancer Books, pp. 191210.Google Scholar
Chakrabarti, S (2009) Contradictions of ‘doing development’: a structuralist framework. American Review of Political Economy 7(1–2): 136.Google Scholar
Chakrabarti, S (2011) A macroeconomic structure of employment: rural-urban conflict in a Kaleckian framework. Review of Radical Political Economics 43(2): 172197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakrabarti, S, Kundu, A (2009) Formal-informal sectors’ conflict: a structuralist framework for India. Journal of Economic Development 34(2): 2767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakravarty, S (1977) Reflections on the growth process in the Indian economy. In: Chakravarty, S (ed.) Writings on Development. New Delhi, India: Oxford University Press, pp. 207236.Google Scholar
Chatterjee, P (2008) Democracy and economic transformation in India. Economic and Political Weekly 19: 5362.Google Scholar
Harvey, D (2003) The New Imperialism. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hymer, S, Resnick, S (1969) A model of an agrarian economy with non-agricultural activities. American Economic Review 59(4): 493506.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N (1996 [1984]) The problem of intersectoral balance. In: Kaldor, N (ed.) Causes of Growth and Stagnation in the World Economy (Mattioli Lectures). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 3954.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalecki, M (1971 [1934]) On foreign trade and domestic export. In: Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M (1993 [1954]) The problem of financing economic development. In: Osiatynski, J (ed.) Collected Works of Michal Kalecki, vol. 5. Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 4560.Google Scholar
Lanjouw, JO, Lanjouw, P (2001) The rural non-farm sector: issues and evidence from developing countries. Agricultural Economics 26(1): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lenin, VI (1972 [1899]) The Development of Capitalism in Russia (Collected Works), vol. 3 Moscow: Progress Publishers.Google Scholar
Lewis, WA (1958 [1954]) Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor. In: Agarwala, AN, Singh, SP (eds) The Economics of Underdevelopment. New Delhi, India: Oxford University Press, pp. 400449.Google Scholar
Marx, K (1958) Capital, vol. I. Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House.Google Scholar
Mellor, JW (1976) The New Economics of Growth – A Strategy for India and Developing World. New York: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO) (2001) Informal sector in India 1999–2000: Salient features. NSS 55th round (July 1999–June 2000). Report no. 459 (55/2.0/2), May. New Delhi, India: NSSO.Google Scholar
National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO) (2002) Unorganised manufacturing sector in India 2000–2001. Key results. NSS 56th round (July 2000–June 2001). Report no. 477 (56/2.2/1), September. New Delhi, India: NSSO.Google Scholar
Preobrazhensky, E (1965 [1926]) The New Economics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Raj, KN (1976) Growth and stagnation in Indian industrial development. Economic and Political Weekly 11: 223236.Google Scholar
Rakshit, M (1982) The Labor Surplus Economy. New Delhi, India: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ranis, G, Fei, JCE (1961) A theory of economic development. American Economic Review 51(4): 533565.Google Scholar
Ranis, G, Stewart, F (1993) Rural non-agricultural activities in development: theory and application. Journal of Development Economics 40(1): 75101.Google Scholar
Ranis, G, Stewart, F (1994) V-goods and the role of the urban informal sector in development. Centre discussion paper no. 724. New Haven, CT: Economic Growth Centre, Yale University.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D (1815) An essay on the influence of low price of corn on the profits of stocks. In: Sraffa, P (ed.) Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 110127.Google Scholar
Saith, A (1991) Asian rural industrialization: context, features and strategies. In: Breman, J, Mundle, S (eds) Rural Transformation in Asia. New Delhi, India: Oxford University Press, pp. 458489.Google Scholar
Sakthivel, S, Joddar, P (2006) Unorganised sector workforce in India: trends, patterns and social security coverage. Economic and Political Weekly 27: 21072114.Google Scholar
Sanyal, K (2007) Rethinking Capitalist Development: Primitive Accumulation, Governmentality and Post Colonial Capitalism. New Delhi, India: Routledge.Google Scholar
Sanyal, K, Bhattacharyya, R (2009) Beyond the factory: globalisation, informalisation of production and the new locations of labour. Economic and Political Weekly 44(22): 3544.Google Scholar
Taylor, L (1983) Structuralist Macroeconomics. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
The Indian Express (2013) Indian economy will pick up by year-end: Raghuram Rajan. The Indian Express, 16 October. Available at: http://www.indianexpress.com/news/indian-economy-will-pick-up-by-yearend-raghuram-rajan/1183306/ (accessed 2 November 2013).Google Scholar
World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalisation (2004) A fair globalization: creating opportunities for all. Report of the Director-General on the World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalisation, International Labour Organisation, Geneva, February.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. The informal economy as a percentage of GDP (un-weighted average).

Figure 1

Table 2. Share of the organised (formal) and the unorganised (informal) sector employment across industries in India (%).

Figure 2

Table 3. Major industry groups within the unorganised (informal) manufacturing sector of India.

Figure 3

Table 4. Index of TOT between agriculture and non-agriculture from 1982–1983 to 2005–2006 (base: triennium ending 1990–1991 = 100).

Figure 4

Table 5. Index of annual real non-agricultural wage rates in terms of consumer price index of industrial workers (1973–1974 to 2003–2004).

Figure 5

Figure 1. Structure of the model economy.

Figure 6

Figure 2. Food-market equilibrium representing the agriculture–formal sector interaction.

Figure 7

Figure 3. Effect of expansionary policy on the formal sector represented through food-market equilibria.

Figure 8

Figure 4. Effects of a bumper harvest on the formal sector shown through food-market equilibria.

Figure 9

Figure 5. Informal sector–market equilibrium representing the agriculture–informal sector interaction.

Figure 10

Figure 6. Simultaneous effects of expansionary policies on the formal and informal sectors represented through food-market equilibria for the formal sector and through the informal sector-market equilibria.