Nothing is more fundamental in setting our research agenda and informing our research methods than our view of the nature of the human beings whose behavior we are studying
1 Introduction and Overview
Behavioral Strategy and This Element
What is behavioral strategy? Where does it come from? Why is it important? One approach to answer these questions is to perform a little thought experiment. Imagine you are a high-level manager in the 1960s. Having attended business school (of which there were much fewer than now) you possess a highly diverse toolbox, derived from different disciplines, such as psychology, mathematics, political science, and economics. Yet when attempting to use these diverse tools, you soon realize they are based on widely different underlying assumptions about managers and employees, making them both incompatible and variably applicable in the real world. For example, the principles of negotiation you were taught, drawing on psychology and political science, are helpful in your managerial role in the company. In contrast, the economic principles you learned provide qualitative market- or industry-level predictions (Machlup, Reference Machlup1967), but are less useful for addressing many other issues you face as a manager. In economics, managers (like you) are assumed to be highly rational instantaneously choosing profit-maximizing input combinations. In practice, you know (too well) that managers are not capable of this.
In the face of managerial realities – complexity, limited information, political conflict, competing motivations, uncertainty, ill-defined goals, and power struggles – the need for strategy tools built on more realistic behavioral assumptions became apparent. Pioneering scholars in the field of strategy – Herbert A Simon (1948), Edith Penrose (Reference Penrose1959), Alfred Chandler (1962), Richard Cyert and James G March (Reference Cyert and March1963) – recognized that sound strategic management theory needs to come to grips with this reality. Thus, the field of strategy that emerged in the 1960s viewed managers as boundedly rational – that is, incapable of processing all available information, and therefore likely to make suboptimal decisions if evaluated through the lens of perfect rationality. With this auspicious start, one may expect strategy scholars to have made great strides in the understanding of boundedly rational managerial behavior, and at the very least to take great care in specifying behavioral assumptions about managerial behavior. However, much (perhaps most) strategy theory has not done this. Instead, the field became preoccupied with macro-level concepts such as industry or resource analysis, firm routines, capabilities, or competencies, and, more recently, with business models and ecosystems (Felin & Foss, Reference Felin and Foss2005). As a result, most strategy theorizing leaves assumptions about individuals unspecified and opaque.
In this Element, we delve into the field of behavioral strategy, which attempts to address this theoretical blindspot by using evidence-based behavioral assumptions as the foundation of strategic thinking. We see behavioral strategy as microfoundational: it seeks to ground theorizing (and explanation and prediction) in individuals and their interactions. Thus, instead of building theory around an organizational actor, who merely has limited information processing capacity, this research also assumes individuals have a variety of motivations and emotions, use heuristics, and are subject to cognitive biases. Yet, after surveying the research in behavioral strategy, we see that these intentions have only been partially fulfilled, and further, not all of what passes as behavioral strategy is actually microfoundational. Thus, a key purpose of this Element is to uncover the substantial “microfoundational potential” that remains untapped within the field of behavioral strategy.
A second key objective of the Element is to present the diversity of behavioral strategy research. A significant part of this tradition is rooted in the already well-researched behavioral theory of the firm (Cyert & March, Reference Cyert and March1963), which addresses firms’ responses to performance deviations from “aspiration levels” (basically, their quantified goals). As a result, scholars less acquainted with behavioral strategy typically equate the subfield with this perspective. Yet, many other streams of behavioral strategy research have developed more recently. By exposing readers to this work, we hope to demonstrate the diversity of behavioral strategy research, and inspire others to take up these novel research threads and weave them into an even more vibrant behavioral strategy tapestry than that created only with the behavioral theory of the firm.
The Relevance of a Behavioral Approach to Strategic Decisions
To start our journey into behavioral strategy, we need to go back to the very definition of “strategy” itself. A “strategy” is an action plan chosen by general management that allows an organization to create and capture value over an extended time period in a way that builds on the strengths of the organization (e.g., Chandler, 1962; Rumelt, Reference Rumelt, Schendel and Hofer1979). Since the 1960s, academics, consultants, and gurus have devised diagnostic and analytical frameworks to aid in strategy formulation and implementation. Yet, these tools often overlook the boundedly rational nature of managers and the psychological influences at play.
Take, for example, Michael Porter’s (Reference Porter1980) well-known Five Forces framework, a staple in strategy courses. It analyzes industry profit potential as driven by intraindustry rivalry, supplier and customer bargaining power, as well as the competitive threats posed by potential entrants and substitutes. In developing their firm’s strategy, managers are urged to take these forces into account and shield against them. There are several tacit psychological assumptions in this strategy development process, which remain that way because decision-making and decision-makers are not explicitly discussed in most presentations of the framework. Specifically, the framework implicitly assumes managers possess a uniform cognitive representation (or “mental model”) of the industry and complete information on various market elements like customers’ willingness to pay, supplier costs, and competitive motivations and actions. This overlooks the reality that managers may hold different interpretations of the same industry, even if they conduct a Five Forces analysis.
As both a research field and an emerging managerial practice, behavioral strategy is fundamentally about making these implicit psychological assumptions explicit by exploring the intersection of psychology and strategy to understand and improve strategic decision-making. While the field of psychology uses the term “behavioral” to mean “behaviorist,” echoing the stimulus-response theories of Pavlov and Skinner, this term takes on a distinctly different meaning in the field of strategy. Introduced in 2010 by Fox and Lovallo during their consulting work for McKinsey, behavioral strategy simply means “Strategy + Psychology.”
The importance of adding psychology to strategy in today’s world cannot be overstated, as recent events highlighted how it shapes decision-making and outcomes. For example, financial decision-makers’ cognitive biases and herd behavior contributed to the 2008 financial crisis. Similarly, social influences and behavioral biases among individual investors drove the recent GameStop stock market frenzy.
Historical examples abound, but the Covid-19 pandemic and the disruptions it induced in the global economy clearly underscore the importance of understanding how decision-makers interpret and adapt to major disturbances that produce deeply complex, highly uncertain strategic problems. To most decision-makers, the pandemic was a “black swan” in the sense of Taleb (Reference Taleb2007): an unknown (or at least something very much out of the ordinary) with massive negative consequences that required extensive sensemaking. For medical and health decision-makers, uncertainty was rampant, including the dynamics of the spread of the disease, the spatial variation in incidence, the epidemiological parameters, the role of superspreaders, and so on. Governments faced ambiguities about Covid-19’s economic impact, the set of possible policy actions, and the outcomes of such actions under different scenarios (Ehrig & Foss, Reference Foss2020). Corporate decision-makers also faced uncertainties regarding end markets, supply chains, and workforce consequences. Their responses differed markedly. For example, while most containerized shipping companies cut back on tonnage, one of the world’s biggest operators, Danish Maersk did not, dramatically increasing its earnings when the pandemic’s influence on trade patterns turned out to be less severe than anticipated (Maersk, 2023).
Most policy decision-making during the pandemic was characterized by “novelty, complexity and open-endedness” (Mintzberg et al., Reference Mintzberg, Raisinghani and Theoret1976: 250), and, initially, a lack of clarity on how to respond (Foss, Reference Foss2020). However, countries that had recently experienced major influenza-like epidemics (e.g., Taiwan) quickly implemented preventive measures. In other words, prior experience played a major role in how rapidly actors could react and how much search was required among available responses. The observed response patterns suggest the presence of anchoring effects stemming from, for example, dramatic footage of global spots that were particularly hard hit by the pandemic outbreak. They also showcase confirmation bias supporting the choice of such reference points and leading to escalation of commitment to the chosen courses of action. While the pandemic prompted policymakers to implement a range of measures to contain the spread of the virus and mitigate its impact on public health and the economy, the global political response to the crisis was chaotic, fragmented, and often myopic, which led some policymakers to delay or underfund public health interventions, such as testing and contact tracing, in favor of measures that had more immediate effects, such as lockdowns. Governments tried to muddle through in the face of uncertainty by imitating each other (Sebatu et al., Reference Sebhatu, Wennberg, Arora-Jonsson and Lindberg2020). In sum, the Covid-19 pandemic certainly highlighted the crucial role of psychology in shaping strategic decision-making and outcomes, particularly under uncertainty. Behavioral strategy (Powell, Lovallo, & Fox, Reference Powell, Lovallo and Fox2011) is vital in the broader world today, as suggested by the fact that psychological explanations are often invoked in explaining overall firm behavior and outcomes in both the popular business press (Forbes, Fortune, etc.), newspapers (Wall Street Journal, Financial Times), and magazines (Harvard Business Review, Sloan Management Review, McKinsey Quarterly). Additionally, well-known business failures (such as those of Blockbuster, Kodak, and Polaroid) that are a staple in MBA teaching, are at least partially attributed to senior managers’ cognitive limitations constraining the development of organizational capabilities and, ultimately, adaptation (e.g., Tripsas & Gavetti, Reference Tripsas and Gavetti2000). Given their frequency, these explanations further underscore the need for research-driven inquiries into these psychological aspects of firm performance.
What Is “Behavioral Strategy”?
There is a long tradition in strategy research of drawing on psychology (especially cognitive psychology, which is very roughly the study of how people think). But as already suggested the increasingly turbulent business and social environment has underscored the relevance and explanatory power of behavioral strategy research, as it is uniquely positioned to shed light on decision-making in environments characterized by high levels of uncertainty (Cyert & March, Reference Cyert and March1963), complexity (Busenitz & Barney, Reference Busenitz and Barney1997), and urgency (Forbes, Reference Forbes2005). Specifically, behavioral strategy research draws on psychological theories and concepts – such as cognitive biases, emotions, motivations, and social influences – to understand how firms obtain and sustain competitive advantage (or, fail to achieve such advantage). This understanding helps managers and employees make decisions and take actions that enable their organizations to adapt to new challenges, sustain their performance, and ensure long-term survival. As such, it represents a vital area of inquiry for scholars and practitioners alike who seek to better understand the complexities of today’s world and help organizations thrive in the face of uncertainty. It is thus not surprising that behavioral strategy research is an increasingly important voice in the strategy field, especially following its institutionalization as a distinct subfield in 2013: the founding of the Behavioral Strategy Interest Group in the Strategic Management Society.
Yet, the field of strategy has not always been open to studying behavioral strategy. To underscore the importance of including cognitive biases in strategic decision-making research, Lovallo and Sibony (Reference Lovallo and Sibony2010) worked with McKinsey & Company to conduct a survey of 2,207 executives about the quality of strategic decision-making inside organizations. About 60 percent of respondents indicated that good and bad decisions occur with equal frequency, while 13 percent noted that good decisions were very infrequent. Probing into the reasons for this skepticism, the survey further examined the role of detailed analysis versus the structure of decision-making processes. The results revealed that decision process structure was six times more influential on decision quality than the depth of analysis. That is not to say analysis is unimportant. But, it highlights that a biased decision process can undermine even the most thorough analysis. Additionally, they discovered that implementing practices to debias decision-making could improve a company’s ROI by 6.9 percent, demonstrating the tangible benefits of high-quality decision-making.
While behavioral strategy is receiving increasing recognition and acceptance, there is still disagreement as to how to define this subfield. Powell, Lovallo, and Fox (Reference Powell, Lovallo and Fox2011: 1371) offered the following definition of behavioral strategy:
Behavioral strategy merges cognitive and social psychology with strategic management theory and practice. Behavioral strategy aims to bring realistic assumptions about human cognition, emotions, and social behavior to the strategic management of organizations and, thereby, to enrich strategy theory, empirical research, and real-world practice.
Other definitions of behavioral strategy have followed, either narrowing or expanding the subfield’s scope (see Gavetti, Reference Gavetti2012; Hambrick & Crossland, Reference Hambrick, Crossland, Augier, Fang and Rindova2018). A comparably narrow definition provided by Levinthal (Reference Levinthal2011) suggests that a behavioral approach to strategy involves systematically building from the idea of a “cognitive representation” of a decision problem (Levinthal, Reference Levinthal2011: 1519). Gavetti (Reference Gavetti2012) also refers to behavioral strategy as “the psychological underpinnings of a given phenomenon, where psychological broadly denotes ‘being about mental process’” (Gavetti, Reference Gavetti2012: 267). On the other hand, Rindova et al. (Reference Rindova, Reger, Dalpiaz and Dagnino2012) adopts a broad “socio-cognitive perspective” focusing on “the roles of managers’ and observers’ attention; the bounded rationality of their cognitions, intuitions, and emotions; and the use of biases and heuristics to socially construct ‘perceptual answers’ to traditional strategic management questions about how firms obtain and sustain competitive advantage” (Pfarrer et al., Reference Pfarrer, Devers and Corley2019: 768). Finally, Hambrick and Crossland make a distinction between behavioral strategy “tents” of varying sizes. The small tent interpretation “amounts to a direct transposition of the logic of behavioral economics (and behavioral finance) to the field of strategic management,” while the large tent conception includes “all forms and styles of research that consider any psychological, social, or political ingredients in strategic management” (Reference Hambrick, Crossland, Augier, Fang and Rindova2018: 25). However, the tent size favored by Hambrick and Crossland views behavioral strategy as a “commitment to understanding the psychology of strategists,” which falls in the middle.
As illustrated by these diverse views of behavioral strategy, many disagreements remain around the definition of behavioral strategy, its current scope (what it seeks to explain and how it explains it), and its boundaries (what is behavioral strategy proper amidst the huge literature that makes use of psychology for theorizing about organizations and strategies). Despite these disagreements, most understandings of this subfield anchor on Herbert A. Simon’s work and, more specifically, on the concept of bounded rationality.
Bounded rationality emerged from Simon’s field studies of decision processes in local government bureaus. In contrast to classical economics models of perfect rationality, he observed that individuals are not capable of making optimal decisions. Bounded rationality posits that decision-making is influenced by a range of cognitive and environmental factors, including incomplete information, time constraints, and computational limitations that, in turn, make individuals satisfice rather than maximize (i.e., select courses of action that are satisfactory – rather than optimal) (Simon, Reference Simon1955). Simon was explicitly committed to microfoundations, that is, the idea that we should seek to understand the characteristics and behaviors of aggregate social entities (such as organizations) in a manner that takes account of the nature and behavior of the individuals composing them (Simon, Reference Simon1991; Felin, Foss, & Ployhart, Reference Felin, Foss and Ployhart2015). He was also committed to the notion that the study of decision-making must be evidence-based (Simon, Reference Simon1978). Given that Simon’s work is the commonality across inceptions of behavior strategy, we propose a definition of behavioral strategy based on these Simonian methodological commitments, which also provides shared ground between the existing definitions:
Definition: Behavioral strategy is the body of thought that addresses strategic management issues (e.g., CEO and top management team behaviors, entry decisions, competitive interaction, firm heterogeneity) in a way that: 1) is microfoundational, 2) embraces a psychology-based understanding of the actions and interactions of individuals to explain exchange or firm-level strategy phenomena, and 3) grounds theorizing in realistic and robust evidence about behaviors and interaction.
Thus, behavioral strategy reinforces other influences that have shaped strategy research over the last few decades, particularly the increased emphasis on microfoundations (Felin & Foss, Reference Felin and Foss2005; Felin et al., Reference Felin, Foss and Ployhart2015) and on empirical methods that go beyond the regression-based analysis of archival data, as they do not allow for testing of underlying mechanisms. Behavioral strategy inherently requires mixed-methods approaches, involving various kinds of experimental and qualitative methodologies.
Themes and Currents in Behavioral Strategy
Simon’s notion of bounded rationality imprinted much of the subsequent psychology-based strategy literature, including what we consider today to be behavioral strategy. Figure 1 provides a visual summary of the major contributions in the behavioral strategy field, grouping them into major research traditions. These traditions are plotted based on the most commonly adopted psychological constructs impacting strategy outcome variables and the level at which a construct is theorized within each tradition (i.e., microlevel (individual), meso-level (group), and macro-level (organization)).Footnote 1 This figure thus acts as a roadmap of the behavioral strategy subfield, as well as of Sections 2–4 in this Element.
Building on Simon’s Bounded Rationality
As noted earlier, one traditional theme in behavioral strategy research hinges on premises that date back to Richard Cyert and James March’s book A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (Reference Cyert and March1963) – a truly foundational contribution in terms of the inspiration it has provided behavioral strategy scholars (and strategy scholars in general). In their behavioral theory of the firm (BTOF), Cyert and March (Reference Cyert and March1963) follow Simon in explicitly criticizing neoclassical economics, specifically the neoclassical theory of the firm (i.e., the basic iso-cost and iso-quant curve apparatus taught in basic microeconomics). The inspiration for key parts of their theory is explicitly drawn from Simon. Rationality in BTOF is best understood in terms of satisficing aspiration levels, which may be thought of as the smallest acceptable outcomes for a goal, the line between perceived successes and failures, or as rules for simplifying evaluations (Greve, Reference Greve1998). Moreover, quasi-resolution of conflict and priority rules govern which goal is addressed. Furthermore, firms are assumed to (only) act when they face a problem – when performance falls below an aspiration level – by searching for a solution. Additionally, similar to goal selection and performance assessment, this search is governed by rules (March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958), specifying the proximity of search to the problem, the current state of the organization, and vulnerable areas inside of it. Thus, search is problemistic, “simple-minded” (governed by simple models of causality), path-dependent (based on organizational history and accumulated knowledge embedded in the standard operating procedures and routines of the organization), and reflective of managerial preferences and employees’ training and experience. From a methodological standpoint, A Behavioral Theory of the Firm commits to developing process-oriented models of the firm and linking them to the empirical world through decision-making simulations. As a result, this simulation approach has become a key tool for understanding and deriving nonobvious implications in subsequent behavioral theory of the firm research (Gavetti et al., Reference Gavetti, Greve, Levinthal and Ocasio2012; Puranam et al., Reference Puranam, Stieglitz and Pillutla2015).
Another traditional behavioral strategy research area directly descending from Cyert and March’s theory (Reference Cyert and March1963) is organizational learning research (Argote, Reference Argote1999; Levit & March, Reference Levitt and March1988; Argote & Greve, Reference Argote and Greve2007) which examines how organizations, seen as complex adaptive systems (Denrell & March, Reference Denrell and March2001), learn and draw inferences from experience (Levitt & March, Reference Levitt and March1988). Local (myopic) search is assumed as the main mechanism driving learning, resulting in suboptimal outcomes (Levinthal & March, Reference Levinthal and March1993). These studies typically rely on agent-based simulation models, including NK models and bandit models, characterizing choices of action as existing on performance landscapes (Levinthal, Reference Levinthal1997).
Another closely related traditional research stream builds on Cyert and March’s rule-based view of organizational decision-making to examine the implications of decision rules for a series of organizational processes and outcomes, including learning (Lant & Mezias, Reference Lant and Mezias1992), adaptation (Lant, Reference Lant1992), innovation (Mezias & Glynn, Reference Mezias and Glynn1993), and performance. Adjacent to these contributions, is the view that organizational routines perform the double role of (1) providing stability and encapsulating firm-specific knowledge (Nelson & Winter, Reference Nelson and Winter1982), and (2) generating organizational change (Feldman & Pentland, Reference Feldman and Pentland2003). This work augments March and Simon’s (Reference March and Simon1958) and Cyert and March’s conceptualization of routines as abstract and stable patterns shaping and guiding organizational behavior with human agency – organizational members’ doings and acts – to introduce changes to routines, and therefore organizational change and performance.
While we will refer to these foundational contributions and their direct descendants several times in the subsequent sections, because of their centrality and extraordinary influence in the organization sciences, they have already been the subject of excellent reviews by Argote and Greve (2006) (Carnegie’s School tradition), Baumann et al. (Reference Baumann, Schmidt and Stieglitz2019) (search in performance landscapes), Gavetti et al. (Reference Gavetti, Levinthal and Ocasio2007) (Carnegie’s School tradition), Gavetti et al. (Reference Gavetti, Greve, Levinthal and Ocasio2012) (behavioral theory of the firm), Posen et al. (Reference Posen, Keil, Kim and Meissner2018) (problemistic search), and Puranam et al. (Reference Puranam, Stieglitz and Pillutla2015) (bounded rationality).
However, as Figure 1 illustrates, behavioral strategy research encompasses more than these traditional streams, so we focus on the many other parts of behavioral strategy that explore topics beyond search and organizational learning, including, for example, Kahneman and Tversky’s (Reference Tversky1974, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1982) research on heuristics and biases (Section 2), the distinction between “hot” and “cold” cognition (e.g., Hodgkinson & Healey, Reference Hodgkinson and Healey2011) (Section 2), Weick’s thinking on managerial and organizational cognition (Weick, Reference Weick1979) (Section 3), and work based on cognitive or motivational psychological theories, such as regulatory focus theory (e.g., Weber & Mayer, Reference Weber and Mayer2011) (Section 4). We delve into each of these sections in more detail below.
Information Processing, Heuristics, and Biases
In the second section, we present work on microlevel biases and heuristics that build on the notion of bounded rationality (continuous-line-patterned areas in Figure 1). It originates from two major individual-level research traditions that predict organizational decision-making: information-processing research (Simon & Newell, Reference Simon and Newell1971) and behavioral decision research (Tversky & Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974; Kahneman & Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979). Information processing research concerns human problem-solving and heuristics and views the decision-making process as a key unit of analysis (Simon & Newell, Reference Simon and Newell1971). In particular, organizational behavior is explained by the discrepancy between the real world and the simplified model of reality in the human mind (Simon, Reference Simon1955).
In behavioral decision research, bounded rationality leads humans to make fast decisions that produce systematic biases (or cognitive illusions). This research stream aimed to create an evidence-based map of bounded rationality “by exploring the systematic biases that separate the beliefs that people have and the choices they make from the optimal beliefs and choices assumed in rational-agent models” (Kahneman, Reference Kahneman2003: 1449). According to the two main exponents of this stream, Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman, fast thinking manifests itself in decision-makers relying on rules of thumb (heuristics) – such as representativeness, availability, and anchoring and adjustment – which lead to systematic divergences from the normative models of behavior in classical economic theories. Still lying within the behavioral decision research tradition but promoting a fundamentally different view of heuristics is the work on fast-and-frugal heuristics (Gigerenzer et al., Reference Gigerenzer and Todd1999; Gigerenzer, Hertwig, & Pachur Reference Gigerenzer, Hertwig and Pachur2011). Here, humans are seen as intuitive statisticians, who can adopt heuristics in a way that increases accuracy and minimizes effort, achieving what is defined as ecological rationality. Another important extension of behavioral decision research is represented by the dual-systems theory of cognition (Chaiken & Trope, Reference Chaiken, Trope, Press and handler1999). This theory builds on Kahneman and Tversky view’s of decision-making as dominated by two systems: a system that operates through largely automatic, preconscious processes involving the development of heuristics; and one that operates via more effortful, deeper, and analytical processes. Yet, in contrast to Kahneman and Tversky’s view of automatic thinking to be seen as the default mode and the main source of systematic biases, researchers in this stream view the two systems as operating simultaneously and emphasize the importance of humans’ capability to switch back and forth between these two processes depending on situational circumstances (Hodgkinson & Healey, Reference Hodgkinson and Healey2011).
Interpretive Perspectives
The third section addresses the stream of work exploring enactment and the related notion of sensemaking (dashed-dotted-patterned areas in Figure 1) – which has received substantial attention (e.g., Hodgkinson, Reference Hodgkinson1997; Walsh, Reference Walsh1995). This stream challenges the notion of bounded rationality and its positivistic view of the world as an objective entity. In contrast, scholars belonging to this stream maintain a view of the environment as enacted – that is, socially constructed via a process of sensemaking through which individuals develop meaning from ambiguous environmental cues via local action, in turn, giving rise to even radically different perceptions of the business environment. Research in this interpretive stream can further be grouped into three traditions: micro- and meso-level work on schema and mental maps (Huff, Reference Huff1982, Reference Huff1990; Porac et al., Reference Porac, Thomas and Baden‐Fuller1989), micro- and meso-level work on social identity and identification (Ashforth & Mael, Reference Ashforth and Mael1989; Albert, Ashforth, & Dutton, Reference Albert, Ashforth and Dutton2000); and meso- and macro-level work on enactment and sensemaking (Daft & Weick, Reference Daft and Weick1984). The first sheds light on managers’ cognitive mapping process (Hodgkinson et al., Reference Hodgkinson, Maule and Bown2004), the content of these maps (Porac et al., Reference Porac, Thomas, Wilson, Paton and Kanfer1995; Reger & Huff, Reference Reger and Huff1993), and their implications for strategic decisions (e.g., Barr et al., Reference Barr, Stimpert and Huff1992). It also provides insight into divergences between managers’ cognitive maps and aggregation issues. The second tradition illuminates organizational members’ social identity construction and its impact on the firm (Ashforth & Mael, Reference Ashforth and Mael1989). The third stream focuses on the sensemaking process through which organizational members, when faced with disruptive events, collectively construct meaning and continue to enact the environment (Weick, Reference Weick1995). Therefore, in contrast to the first stream, which assumes that a frame of meaning (or cognitive map) is already in place, and one needs to connect a new cue to the existing frame (through the act of mapping), the second stream is more concerned with the “invention” of a new frame. In this section, we shed insight into the distinctive facets of this stream’s constitutive research traditions. We also discuss the difficulties of studying the mental representations and sensemaking processes of the organization’s top management team members.
Behavioral Governance
In the fourth section of the Element, we focus on the motivation-related part of the behavioral strategy landscape in Figure 1 (dashed-patterned areas), and, specifically, on the behavioral governance traditions. Work in this tradition aims at augmenting corporate governance theories (i.e., agency theory; Fama & Jensen, Reference Fama and Jensen1983; Jensen & Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1976) and transaction cost economics (TCE; Williamson, Reference Williamson1975, Reference Williamson1985) with psychological theories and concepts to predict organizational outcomes, with a special focus on the role of governance – that is, “the formal structures, informal structures, and processes that exist in oversight roles and responsibilities in a corporate context” (Hambrick, Werder, & Zajac, Reference Hambrick, Werder and Zajac2008: 381) – in supporting cooperation among firms’ internal and external constituents (Westphal & Zajac, Reference Westphal and Zajac2013). In particular, work in this stream can be organized into three separate streams differing on the context of application, in terms of the “main agent(s)” to which they apply: (1) corporate leaders; (2) organizational members and employees; and (3) external stakeholders. Work focusing on corporate leaders examines executives’ behaviors, as guided by self-interest and personal risk preferences and characterized by bounded rationality, and how certain incentives (e.g., equitable compensation), structures, and systems, by acting on executives’ intrinsic, extrinsic motivation, and prosocial motivations can channel executives’ efforts in directions that contribute positively to organizational and/or societal outcomes (Devers, Cannella, Reilly, & Yoder, Reference Devers, Cannella, Reilly and Yoder2007).
Research in the second stream explores how different organizational designs induce different motivations, leading to specific types of opportunism or cooperation (Weber, Foss, & Lindenberg, Reference Weber, Foss and Lindenberg2023), as well as specific transaction costs (Foss & Weber, Reference Foss and Weber2016). Finally, work in the third stream examines how contract frames impact employees’ regulatory focus, emotions, perceptions, and behaviors (Weber & Mayer, Reference Weber and Mayer2011), inducing desired exchange behaviors (Weber, Mayer, & Macher, Reference Weber, Mayer and Macher2011) and impacting the relationship between firms. This section also builds on the second and third sections to examine efficient transaction governance decisions that take different organizational cognitive frames into account (Weber & Mayer, Reference Weber and Mayer2014).
Research Challenges in Behavioral Strategy
In the final section of the Element (Section 5), we present the major research challenges in behavioral strategy research and propose a roadmap to advance research in this field. We focus on definitional and methodological issues. From a definitional standpoint, we describe how existing behavioral strategy research has largely overlooked possible implications of branches of psychology beyond cognition (cf. Gigerenzer & Goldstein, Reference Gigerenzer and Goldstein1996), such as emotions, affect, intuition, and even motivation. Because of these tendencies, we note that there is a huge potential for future behavioral strategy research that has not yet been tapped, for example, examining the impact of strategic beliefs on firm performance, or the psychology of goals (Lindenberg & Foss, Reference Lindenberg and Foss2011), or motivational psychology, and how these aspects influence firm value creation. We also present potential issues with the widespread approach of anthropomorphizing organizations. From a methodological standpoint, we discuss the potential benefits of methodological pluralism to capture and account for the complex dynamics of real organizational settings.
2 Bounded Rationality, Heuristics, and Biases: From Simon to Computational Models
Introduction
While bounded rationality is foundational to most management thought, it is particularly important in a behavioral strategy context. A key purpose of this section is to trace thinking on bounded rationality from its earliest history in Simon (Reference Simon1947) through the heuristics and biases program of Kahneman and Tversky (Reference Tversky1974) to modern computational approaches and ecological rationality. As such, the section lays the foundations for subsequent sections. However, along the way, we will also note various limitations in the way behavioral strategy has dealt with bounded rationality, such as a tendency to reify the concept, specifically, move it to the organizational level without considering the aggregation process.
Bounded Rationality: Simon’s Grand Theme
From “Perfect” to “Bounded” Rationality
As its name suggests, bounded rationality was coined as a critique of the assumption of “perfect” rationality. Extreme assumptions often serve science well, and, arguably, the assumption of perfect rationality has, in many ways, served economics well, as it furthers tractability (i.e., decision problems can be represented as maximization problems), tends to lead to unique predictions (given certain assumptions on the maximization problem) and is not completely unrealistic (e.g., when a decision situation is sufficiently simple). And yet, the assumption has also been criticized for as long as it has been articulated (e.g., Veblen, Reference Veblen1898).
To understand what the critique is about, it is important to understand what the assumption entails and what it does not. Perfect rationality does not assume omniscience or perfect foresight. Economics has long since dispensed with those assumptions in favor of assumptions of “asymmetric and imperfect information.” Thus, information and uncertainty or risk are included in the set of constraints on the decision problem, but decision-makers are nevertheless assumed to be capable of maximizing and arriving at the best possible solution. This view – further refined in the 40s and 50s in the works of von Neumann and Morgenstern (Reference Neumann and Morgenstern1944), Friedman and Savage (Reference Friedman and Savage1948), and Luce and Raiffa (Reference Luce and Raiffa1957) – implicitly assumes that decision-makers have an unlimited capacity for processing the information they possess or acquire. Accordingly, any decision problem can potentially be addressed and handled immediately and perfectly.
If taken literally, it is easy to see how extreme this view is, as “there is a complete lack of evidence that, in actual human choice situations … these computations are in fact performed” (Simon, Reference Simon1955: 104). Providing this evidence, and, more generally, understanding how decision-makers actually make decisions and if general principles can be constructed about such decision-making, was a significant part of the multi- and interdisciplinary oeuvre of Herbert A Simon.
Simon (Reference Simon1947) points out that although we may intend to be rational, we do not have the wits to calculate the optimal solution for many decision situations. In Simon’s often-quoted phrase, we are boundedly rational: “intendedly rational, but limitedly so” (1947: 88). Of course, this is a negative definition in the sense that it tells us what bounded rationality is not rather than what it actually is (Foss, Reference Foss and Rizzello2003). However, exploring what bounded rationality entails for individual decision-making and, in particular, in an organizational context, has constituted a central scholarly effort in a number of related but distinct research streams over the last seven decades. This includes work in information processing (Simon & Newell, Reference Simon and Newell1971), within the broad Carnegie School (March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958) – including, the behavioral theory of the firm (Cyert & March, Reference Cyert and March1963), the attention-based view of the firm (Ocasio, Reference Ocasio1997), and modern computational approaches that highlight the search and adaptation aspects of bounded rationality (Levinthal, Reference Levinthal1997; Puranam et al., Reference Puranam, Stieglitz and Pillutla2015) – as well as work on behavioral decision research from behavioral economics (Tversky & Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974; Kahneman & Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979), top management teams (Ha0mbrick & Mason, Reference Hambrick and Mason1984), and even TCE (Williamson, Reference Williamson1996; see Section 4). The first major advance in the bounded rationality program is the expansion to consider satisficing and search.
Bounded Rationality in Individual Decision-Making: Information Processing, Heuristics, and Satisficing Search
In his Reference Simon1955 article, “A behavioral model of rational choice,” Simon centers his critique around two fundamental assumptions inherent in rational decision theory, namely (1) perfect computational powers on the part of decision-makers and (2) the existence of a well-defined set of conceivable actions which lead to certain consequences that can all be evaluated and compared, thereby translating into a complete preference ordering and a unique optimal action.
In place of such unrealistic assumptions, Simon (Reference Simon1955, Reference Simon1956) fundamentally redefines rationality from the “substantive” notion associated with standard economics to a more “procedural” notion (Simon, Reference Simon1978), whereby “an explanation of an observed behavior of the organism is provided by a program of primitive information processes that generates this behavior” (Newell, Shaw, & Simon, Reference Newell, Shaw and Simon1958: 151). Thus, the attention turns to decision-making and problem-solving (or search in later work) processes as guided by “programs.” In particular, when human beings are observed working on problems that are difficult but not unsolvable for them, their behaviors reveal basic properties that relate to how they process information, namely serial processing, small short-term memory, and infinite long-term memory with fast retrieval but slow storage (Simon & Newell, Reference Simon and Newell1971). These properties impose strong constraints on how individuals can seek solutions to problems in large problem spaces (cf. Simon & Newell, Reference Simon and Newell1971: 149). In these situations, regardless of how large the problem space is, heuristics direct problem solvers’ attention to small, promising regions of the problem space or “a set of possible outcomes … such that the pay-off is satisfactory … for all these outcomes,” while ignoring the rest, and to search around certain “behavior alternatives” until those “whose outcomes are all [in the set]” are identified (p.106). In other words, search involves refining the understanding of how actions map onto consequences in a sequential manner, which inherently depends on how information is embedded in problem spaces, extracted by heuristic processes, and used to guide search.
According to Simon, the simplest way to extract and use information for problem-solving is hill climbing. Using the heuristics of “always going upward,” decision-makers try to identify alternatives that are associated with a higher performance payoff compared with the current one. The choice of an efficient next step is dictated by means-end analysis–a type of heuristics that allows a decision maker to find differences between already explored alternatives and a goal state (Simon & Newell, Reference Simon and Newell1971). Therefore, search continues until an outcome that is “satisfactory” in terms of meeting the target is found (Simon, Reference Simon1947). As Simon (Reference Simon1955: 114) explains, satisficing as a decision heuristic has the advantage of being “computationally manageable,” and at the same intuitively realistic.
In this sense, Simon’s theory of decision-making is primarily a theory describing problem-solving programs and their role in making the decision-maker, as an information-processing system, adapt to the task environment (i.e., the objective problem space). Such a focus embeds a quest for generalizability and parsimony to make the theory applicable to a variety of problem situations as well as allowing for examination via mathematical and computational modeling. Indeed, as we discuss in the next section, Simon’s work inspired the development of an entire research program relying strongly on formal (mathematical and computational) modeling to describe and analyze the processes of search and adaptation in organizations (Puranam et al., Reference Puranam, Stieglitz and Pillutla2015).
Moving Bounded Rationality into the Firm: Problemistic Search and Attention
From Cyert and March to Computational Models
Although Simon’s (1947) concern with bounded rationality emerged from his close study (for his Ph.D. thesis) of decision-making in a public bureau, much of his early work on the topic, including his multiple collaborations with Alan Newell, mainly considers individual decision-making. Instead, the concept of satisficing search was extended to the organizational level by Cyert and March in their landmark Reference Cyert and March1963 book, A Behavioral Model of the Firm. As mentioned in Section 1, the most important elaboration of the book is the notion of problemistic search, that is search triggered by negative divergences between realized performance and aspiration levels (acceptable performance thresholds set by a dominant coalition of boundedly rational decision-makers through quasi-resolution of conflict (see Posen et al., 2020 for a review)). In doing so, Cyert and March emphasized the importance of feedback in guiding search (which had also appeared in Simon 1966).
Since Cyert and March (Reference Cyert and March1963), a substantial number of papers have been published following a basic scheme in which: (1) agents are equipped with models of their environments, (2) representations inform the choices agents make, (3) these choices are “tested” in the relevant environment generating feedback, and (4) the representations in the environmental model are adapted, resulting in novel choices (see Puranam et al., Reference Puranam, Stieglitz and Pillutla2015). This scheme underpins research on the behavioral theory of the firm, including research on the “exploitation-exploration tradeoff” (March, Reference March1991) and work that uses “NK models,” originally developed by theoretical biologist Stuart Kauffman (1993) and introduced to management research by Levinthal (Reference Levinthal1997).
Behavioral strategy using an NK model depicts organizations as moving on a “fitness landscape,” an N-dimensional space that maps each attribute (characteristic or policy dimension of an organization) and its performance consequences. Crucially, the topology of the landscape is determined by the degree of interdependence (i.e., complementarity) between the attributes, K. That is, K measures how many other attributes influence a given attribute. While a small value of K implies few peaks in the landscape or just a single one (a “smooth landscape”), a high value indicates many peaks (a “rugged landscape”). Even though the landscape exists in objective reality, the organization does not know its topology and therefore has to engage in search, either local (i.e., only changing one attribute) or global (“long jumps”; changing all attributes). It is intuitive that if the landscape has just one peak, this peak will be reached through local search. In contrast, in a rugged landscape, organizations that engage in only local search may get stuck on local peaks. While this seems to make global search generally attractive, such search is more costly to engage in. Thus, organizational search behavior results from a tradeoff between the benefits and costs of the two types of search. This line of research has been thriving since the late 1990s (Gavetti & Levinthal, Reference Gavetti and Levinthal2000; Puranam et al., Reference Puranam, Stieglitz and Pillutla2015), percolating widely beyond the community of modelers and resulting in empirical work investigating the impact of negative performance feedback on the likelihood and intensity of organizational and strategic changes (e.g., Audia & Greve, Reference Audia and Greve2006; Greve Reference Greve1998). This stream of empirical research has also shown that, especially under conditions of uncertainty, decision-makers selectively imitate the actions of other firms (Rhee et al., Reference Rhee, Kim and Han2006). In particular, to improve firm performance while avoiding the risks and costs of online search and experimentation, they learn vicariously by absorbing knowledge produced by other firms’ explorations (Baum et al., Reference Baum, Li and Usher2000; Levitt & March, Reference Levitt and March1988).
From March and Simon to the Attention-Based View
Further implications of bounded rationality at the organizational level were added through work from Simon’s collaboration with the political scientist James G. March and, more recently, by Ocasio’s (Reference Ocasio1997) attention-based view of the firm. In Simon’s (1948) original view, the main role of organizations was to structure the attention of individual decision-makers by offering both a physical and cognitive division of labor (member A works on problems of type Z, while B works on type Y problems, etc.) (Dearborn & Simon, Reference Dearborn and Simon1958). In the book Organizations, March and Simon explicitly focus on providing a theory for when, where, and how organizations search for information about urgent problems, alternatives, and their consequences. More specifically, they illustrate that organizations structure and channel the allocation of cognitive effort and attention through the division and spatial allocation of labor, and decide which problems should be worked on based on “decision premises” (March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958). We will return to some of these aspects in Section 4.
Building on March and Simon (Reference March and Simon1958), Ocasio (Reference Ocasio1997) formulated the attention-based view of the firm in an article published almost four decades after their classic work. Ocasio interprets bounded rationality as individuals’ limited attentional capacity. Attention is the “noticing, encoding, interpreting, and focusing of time and effort on issues (problems, opportunities, threats …) and answers (alternatives, projects, procedures, …)” (Ocasio, Reference Ocasio1997: 188). A key purpose of organizations is therefore to direct attention in the best possible manner (Joseph & Gaba, Reference Joseph and Gaba2020). While the main emphasis is on the attention of the firm’s top decision-makers, Ocasio develops a more general theory that picks up on Simon (Reference Simon1947) and March and Simon (Reference March and Simon1958) in showing how organizations sculpt decisions by defining and allocating the stimuli that channel attention (cf. Ocasio, 2011). Thus, organizational problems (“Hey, demand dropped in market x,” “Ugh, a machine broke down”) in a specific unit selectively trigger the attention of that unit’s employees.
Heuristics and Biases and Ecological Rationality
The Heuristics and Biases Program
A key theme in Simon’s idea of bounded rationality is that decision-makers often rely on cognitive shortcuts because they lack the processing capacity to make fully informed decisions (Schwenk, Reference Schwenk1984; Simon, Reference Simon1956). Satisficing is one such heuristic, enabling decision-makers to economize on cognitive resources as compared to computationally more demanding approaches, such as maximizing. The downside is, of course, that decision-makers may choose and stick to inferior alternatives. This basic duality is central in the behavioral decision research initiated by the behavioral economists Tversky and Kahneman (Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974) (see Kahneman (Reference Kahneman2003) for a summary), and often referred to as the heuristics and biases program (Kahneman, Reference Kahneman2003, 2011; Kahneman & Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979). Additionally, it is now seen as an important instance of “dual processing theory” which stresses the “twin imperative of having to process information deliberatively and in detail, but also being able to cut through such detail with minimal cognitive effort to perform tasks more efficiently” (Hodgkinson et al., Reference Hodgkinson, Burkhard and Foss2023: 1042). Notably, the heuristics and biases program, albeit originating directly from Simon’s bounded rationality notion, was framed as a new paradigm departing from “bounded rationality, satisficing, and simulations” through the reliance on empirical evidence – mainly of an experimental nature (Sent, Reference Sent2004: 742).
The key idea in the heuristics and biases program is that the manifold heuristics that decision-makers utilizeFootnote 2 are likely to result in a rich set of cognitive biases, rendering the decision-making process systematically flawed – at least if evaluated related to a perfect rationality ideal. The search for such biases has become a major industry, with the number of biases at 188 at last count.Footnote 3 While it is debatable how distinct many of these biases truly are (Oeberst & Imhoff, Reference Oeberst and Imhoff2023), representativeness and availability biases, both stemming from the tendency to focus attention on supposedly typical features of a decision situation, are among the more well-known ones (Hodgkinson et al., Reference Hodgkinson, Burkhard and Foss2023; Kiesler & Sproull, Reference Kiesler and Sproull1982). Other well-known biases (probably so well-known that an explanation is not necessary) are hindsight, self-serving, overconfidence, anchoring, and confirmation biases.
One of the most influential theories in this program is Kahneman and Tversky’s (Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979) prospect theory. Conceived as an alternative to expected utility theory, it provides a model for predicting individual decision-making under risk in contexts of isolated gambles characterized by simple choices with two clear prospects or alternatives and stated probabilities (Kahneman, Reference Kahneman2003). The theory is based on the following three core assumptions: (1) decision-makers weigh assured outcomes more than probable outcomes, (2) they simplify decision-making by focusing on differences between choices rather than their commonalities, and (3) they tend to be risk-averse in the domain of (small) gains and risk-seeking in the domain of (small) losses. As a result, decision-makers prefer an assured gain over an uncertain gain with a marginally higher expected value and prefer an uncertain loss over an assured loss with a marginally lower expected value (Bromiley & Rau, Reference Bromiley and Rau2022; Holmes et al., Reference Holmes, Bromiley, Devers, Holcomb and McGuire2011).
Prospect theory has been very popular in strategy research (see e.g., Holmes et al., Reference Holmes, Bromiley, Devers, Holcomb and McGuire2011; Hoskisson et al., Reference Hoskisson, Chirico, Zyung and Gambeta2017). It is typically applied to the top management team or the organization to explain the relationship between a firm’s negative performance and its risk-taking (e.g., risky actions such as acquisitions, divestitures, and new product introductions). The application of prospect theory to firm strategic decisions has not come without criticism (Bromiley, Reference Bromiley2010; Bromiley & Rau, Reference Bromiley and Rau2022). While prospect theory examines the behavior of an individual decision-maker confronted with a simple well-structured problem with clear prospects or alternatives and known probabilities, the problems organizations are confronted with are generally complex, collective, and involve a substantial level of uncertainty. Explicit examinations of the validity of prospect theory to predict individual choices in more complex contexts similar to organizational ones have provided far from reassuring results (e.g., Bromiley, Reference Bromiley2010; Spiliopoulos & Hertwig, Reference Spiliopoulos and Hertwig2023).
This aggregation issue emerges in most strategy research building on the heuristics and biases program. Another example is the upper echelons research area founded by Hambrick and Mason (Reference Hambrick and Mason1984), who were early adopters of the heuristics and biases program (e.g., Barnes, Reference Barnes1984; Das & Teng, Reference Das and Teng1999) (see the review and discussion in Hodgkinson et al., Reference Hodgkinson, Burkhard and Foss2023). In their foundational work and that built on it, executives’ and senior managers’ characteristics and traits were grafted onto behavioral theories of decision-making (cf. Hambrick, Reference Hambrick2007) to show the heuristic nature of their decision-making and the possibly biased nature of the resulting firm-level strategic decisions and outcomes (e.g., Chen et al., Reference Chen, Crossland and Luo2015; Li & Tang, Reference Li and Tang2010; Wesley et al., Reference Wesley, Martin, Rice and Lubojacky2022). As suggested, these studies tend to take an aggregate view without delving into how biases and heuristics may be either mitigated or accentuated by social interactions and dynamics between firm leaders. Moreover, the bulk of this work focuses primarily on top-manager overconfidence (Burkhardt et al., Reference Burkhard, Sirén, van Essen, Grichnik and Shepherd2022), with Hodgkinson et al. (Reference Hodgkinson, Burkhard and Foss2023) identifying approximately 50 percent of published papers in this area addressing this particular bias.
In contrast to the work on decision-making in top management, even less attention has been paid to how heuristics and biases at lower organizational levels impact value creation. In one such application, Foss and Weber (Reference Foss and Weber2016) consider framing and social comparison biases that may arise in exchanges between members and units in firms. They argue that different hierarchical structures induce different biases, giving rise to predictable frictions in internal exchanges. Given that this line of research is very recent, this area represents a significant research opportunity in behavioral strategy.
Finally, Kahneman and Tversky’s original goal “to obtain a map of bounded rationality” recently re-gained momentum in work examining individual-level beliefs and strategic choices (Kahneman, Reference Kahneman2003) using neurocognitive experiments. To do so, a group of behavioral strategy scholars directly examine decision-makers’ mental processes via brain imaging techniques (e.g., Laureiro-Martínez, Brusoni, & Zollo, Reference Laureiro-Martínez, Brusoni and Zollo2010; Laureiro-Martínez, Brusoni, Canessa, & Zollo, Reference Laureiro‐Martínez, Brusoni, Canessa and Zollo2015). While holding some promise, this approach may risk excessively detaching decision-making from its organizational context, thereby losing external validity (cf. Felin et al., Reference Felin, Foss and Ployhart2015). Moreover, the nature of brain imaging methodology may change the nature of the decision-making task, perhaps reducing its internal validity. We will return to some of these issues in the final section of the Element.
Ecological Rationality
Whereas most research in the heuristics and biases tradition emphasizes the downside of heuristics (i.e., biases), the ecological rationality program accentuates their upside. Picking up on Simon’s (Reference Simon1955) idea, this approach focuses on the skilled application of heuristics by decision-makers. So in this research, a heuristic is seen as “a strategy with the goal of making decisions more quickly, frugally, and/or accurately than more complex methods” (Gigerenzer & Gassmeier, Reference Gigerenzer and Gaissmaier2011). Strikingly, Gigerenzer and his co-authors show that heuristics are not second-best approximations to maximizing rationality, but may often lead to faster and better outcomes, particularly in uncertain, ambiguous environments with few useful data points (e.g., Gigerenzer & Gaissmaier, Reference Gigerenzer and Gaissmaier2011). As with the neuroscience approach to behavioral strategy, the study of ecologically rational, fast, and frugal heuristics in organizations in general and in strategy in particular is still in its infancy. Pioneer work has been done by Bingham and Eisenhardt (Reference Bingham and Eisenhardt2011), who studied the formation of heuristics during the internationalization processes of six technology-based ventures. However, except for Luan, Reb, and Gigerenzer (Reference Luan, Reb and Gigerenzer2019), there is still very little research examining the formation and use of heuristics at the firm level and their implications for organizational decision-making and strategic adaptation. Again, the dearth of research on this important topic represents an important opportunity for work in behavioral strategy.
Conclusion: Simon’s Incomplete Revolution
This section briefly outlines the history of the evolution of bounded rationality originally proposed by Simon (Reference Simon1947). On one hand, the revolution around rationality, information processing, and behavior that Simon initiated has been exceedingly successful. As a result, the implications of bounded rationality have become increasingly concrete in such concepts as satisficing search (Simon, Reference Simon1955), representations (March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958, discussed in Chapter 3), aspiration levels and problemistic search (Cyert & March, Reference Cyert and March1963), and limited attention (Ocasio, Reference Ocasio1997). It is also more clear how it is embedded in an organizational context (Simon, 1947; March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958; Cyert & March, Reference Cyert and March1963; Ocasio, Reference Ocasio1997), linked to top manager decision-making (Hambrick & Mason, Reference Hambrick and Mason1984; Hodgkinson et al., Reference Hodgkinson, Burkhard and Foss2023), articulated in terms of the competing heuristics and biases (Tversky & Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974) and ecological rationality (Gigerenzer & Gassmeier, Reference Gigerenzer and Gaissmaier2011), and formalized relying on modeling techniques like NK-modeling and other computational models (Puranam et al., Reference Puranam, Stieglitz and Pillutla2015). In other words, bounded rationality evolved through refinement, extension, application, and formalization, which is how successful scientific ideas usually advance. Indeed, it is not amiss to suggest that bounded rationality is the way in which most management scholars view human rationality.
On the other hand, there is significant imprecision and inconsistency in the basic conceptualization and model of bounded rationality in management research, as well as its application to organizations and their strategies. A fundamental critique of this work (which does not apply to Simon’s research) is that it focuses on errors rather than success of decision-making. As the ecological rationality critique implies, the heuristics and biases program itself is strongly representative of this tendency, but so too is bounded rationality research on, for example, the exploitation/exploration tradeoff (March, Reference March1991). This critique also suggests that much bounded-rationality research implicitly accepts the standard optimization model as its normative benchmark – rationality is “bounded” relative to this benchmark (Foss, Reference Foss and Rizzello2003). Indeed, formal treatments of bounded rationality make ample use of standard probabilistic reasoning (e.g., Kahneman, Reference Kahneman2003), and some of the best-developed and most influential models of bounded rationality (notably, prospect theory, Kahneman & Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979) are models that assume environments characterized by risk. However, strategy formulation and implementation often involve epistemic conditions to which probabilistic tools are less well suited, notably Knightian uncertainty (i.e., decision-makers do not confront a given state space, cannot place probabilities on outcomes, etc.). There are some obvious links, as, for example, the inability to put meaningful probabilities to outcomes or identify the full set of possible outcomes (both manifestations of Knightian uncertainty) may result from bounded rationality. But, at least so far bounded-rationality research has said little about decision-making and behaviors under uncertainty rather than risk (Mousavi & Gigerenzer, Reference Mousavi and Gigerenzer2014). Furthermore, as Hodgkinson and Healey (Reference Hodgkinson and Healey2011) argue, most interpretations of bounded rationality in strategy are through the lens of “cold cognition.” inherently downplaying the importance of affect and emotions.
Although research has made several significant advances in how bounded rationality is applied in the context of firm strategy, many aspects are still unclear in this research program. For instance, despite the importance and centrality of problemistic search in strategy research, how problem identification, diagnosis, and solving occur in an organization remains something of a black box (Posen et al., Reference Posen, Keil, Kim and Meissner2018). Additionally, while both March and Simon (Reference March and Simon1958) and Cyert and March (Reference Cyert and March1963) theorized about how firms establish priorities in the presence of multiple goals and corresponding aspiration levels (e.g., different goals and aspiration levels for different units), empirical evidence of the mechanisms regulating the allocation of attention is scant (cf. Mazzelli et al., Reference Mazzelli, Nason, De Massis and Kotlar2019). Moreover, while research distinguished between social and historical sources of aspiration levels, the mechanisms driving choices of such levels, including why particular social referents are chosen, remain less well understood.
More fundamentally, significant challenges remain in bringing bounded rationality to bear at all organizational levels, and not just the individual and the dominant coalition or top management team levels (Hambrick, Reference Hambrick2007). Indeed, bounded rationality is an individual-level construct developed from the observation of decision-makers solving rather simple problems in controlled environments – as was the case for several of the constructs in the heuristics and biases program. Therefore, by applying it unreflectively to predict firm strategic decisions and outcomes, we may incur the risk of “forfeiting the intellectual challenges thrown off by real-world problems” (Fischhoff, Reference Fischhoff1996: 246). In Section 5, we will offer some ideas on how to approach and circumvent this fundamental problem. In sum, while Simon’s (1947) introduction of the notion of bounded rationality set in motion what may well be described as a revolution, that revolution remains quite unfinished, offering significant opportunities for research in the subfield of behavioral strategy.
3 Managerial and Organizational Cognition: Interpretive Microfoundations of Strategy
Introduction
In recent years, the strategy field dramatically increased its exploration of the cognitive dimensions underlying firms’ strategic decisions (e.g., Hodgkinson, Reference Hodgkinson1997; Walsh, Reference Walsh1995). This movement was driven by a recognition that managerial cognition plays an instrumental role in shaping strategic outcomes, fostering innovation, and ensuring organizational adaptability in increasingly volatile and complex environments. This section provides an overview of the historical development of theory and research applying cognitive psychology and social cognition to the analysis of behavior in organizations. Although it originated with Simon’s (1947) notion of bounded rationality, this research tradition took a very different path, relying on Weick’s (Reference Weick1979) idea of enacted sensemaking and individuals’ subjective differences in perception. The section covers three important theoretical perspectives in this stream: (1) schema theory and the related construct of mental maps/representations, (2) social identity theory and self-categorization, and (3) enactment and sensemaking, along with the related view of organizations as interpretative systems. Finally, it discusses some theoretical and empirical challenges in moving forward in the study of these topics. Overall, the section offers an overview of the microfoundational work examining how managers actively perceive, interpret, constitute, and act upon their business environments, and in turn, how these cognitive processes affect firm behavior and outcomes.
Simon’s Bounded Rationality Challenged: Weick’s Interpretative Perspective
As discussed in Chapter 2, Simon’s (1947) notion of bounded rationality is foundational in understanding human decision-making in organizations. At its core, bounded rationality posits that decision-makers are unable to make perfectly rational decisions due to cognitive limitations and the complexity of real-world situations. They thus strive for rationality within the boundaries of their cognitive capacities and information availability (March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958). This realist perspective considers the environment as an external entity, independent of individuals’ perceptions or beliefs, and views knowledge as something that is discovered, measured, and generalized. As a result, the focus of this perspective is to arrive at, as much as possible, an objective understanding of the world in the face of uncertainty.
Yet, in the late 1970s and early 1980s, Karl Weick challenges this goal of an objective understanding of reality in Simon’s bounded rationality through his work on enactment and the related notion of sensemaking. He argues that sensemaking, a continuous process through which individuals develop meanings based on local actions and experiences, gives rise to a variety of subjective – and potentially divergent – perceptions of the business environment (Weick, Reference Weick1979). Thus, instead of viewing the world as a homogenous reality to be uncovered, Weick espouses a constructivist approach, viewing the environment as continuously formulated and reformulated through social interactions and interpretations.
Influenced by Weick’s work as well as by a burgeoning interest in cognition in the field of social psychology (cf. Fiske & Taylor, Reference Fiske and Taylor1984), management scholars in the early 1980s began to embrace the view of the environment as socially constructed (e.g., Bartunek, Reference Bartunek1984; Daft & Weick, Reference Daft and Weick1984; Huff, Reference Huff1982; Spender, Reference Spender1989; Walsh & Fahey, Reference Walsh and Fahey1986). As a result, researchers examine how managers use cognitive frames to make sense of the environment, and how this sensemaking shapes their strategic choices and actions (Daft & Weick, Reference Daft and Weick1984; Kaplan, Reference Kaplan2011).
Naturally, this move toward a socially constructed view translates into significant methodological shifts. Aligning with its objectivist worldview, research building on Simon’s notion of bounded rationality predominantly deploys computational models and quantitative tools, intending to reveal and quantify overarching cognitive patterns (e.g., Simon & Newell, Reference Simon and Newell1976). In contrast, the emerging interpretive trend utilizes qualitative methodologies, such as cognitive mapping techniques (e.g., repertory grid technique), ethnographic studies, in-depth interviews, and narrative inquiries. Unlike models or quantitative approaches, these qualitative approaches allow for the exploration of multifaceted cognitive processes, the dynamism of sensemaking, and the contextually embedded construction of knowledge (e.g., Bougon, Weick, & Binkhorst, Reference Bougon, Weick and Binkhorst1977).
Yet, the study of such cognitive processes continues to pose substantial theoretical and methodological challenges due to fragmentation, construct proliferation, aggregation issues, and validity concerns.
Theoretical Perspectives on Managerial and Organizational Cognition
Three major perspectives pervade existing interpretative work on cognition in organizations: (1) schema theory including mental maps/representations (e.g., strategic groups and framing), (2) social identity theory and self-categorization, and (3) sensemaking and the related view of organizations as interpretative systems.
Schema Theory, Mental Representations, and Frames
Schemas are cognitive structures through which individuals recognize, process, organize, and interpret information from their environment. Rooted in cognitive psychology, schema theory posits these mental frameworks guide humans’ perceptions, beliefs, and actions by providing a structured means of understanding. In essence, schemas are the “mental templates” that individuals use to categorize the world (Walsh, Reference Walsh1995).
When applying this theory, strategy scholars tend to assume information converges and is interpreted at the top manager level (Fahey & Narayanan, Reference Fahey and Narayanan1989; Lyles & Schwenk, Reference Lyles and Schwenk1992). Thus, researchers examine how managers’ schemas influence their interpretations of complex business environments, their expectations of how these may evolve (Gick & Holyoak, Reference Gick and Holyoak1983), and their subsequent strategic decisions (Kaplan, Reference Kaplan2011). To do so, these scholars generate managers’ mental maps or representations, which are “tangible” expressions of schemas, by outlining managerial perceptions and beliefs of the internal and external environment of the firm. These mental maps may include firm structure, technology, industry landscapes, stakeholder interplay, and competitive dynamics (Kaplan, Reference Kaplan2011). For instance, prominent work by Huff (Reference Huff1982), Porac et al. (Reference Porac, Thomas and Baden‐Fuller1989), and Reger and Huff (Reference Reger and Huff1993) shed light on the role mental maps play in shaping managerial perceptions of strategic groupings and competitive positioning. While some of these studies indicate strategists within a given sector tend to hold highly similar representations of the competitive landscape (e.g., Porac et al., Reference Porac, Thomas and Baden‐Fuller1989; Reger & Huff, Reference Reger and Huff1993), others suggest these representations reflect subjective perceptions (Rindova & Fomburn, Reference Rindova and Fombrun1999), prompting radically different strategic groupings across firms in the same industry (e.g., Hodgkinson & Johnson, Reference Hodgkinson and Johnson1994) within the same timeframe (e.g., Fahey & Narayanan, Reference Fahey and Narayanan1989). One such example is from Kilduff (Reference Kilduff2019), in which he argues that managers may interpret certain firms as relational rivals (similar to long-standing university rivals), increasing the likelihood of nonrational competitive actions and reactions, exceeding those predicted from market conditions.
Closely related to schema theory is framing theory (Goffman, Reference Goffman1974), where frames define the way experience is organized, described, and presented (Cornelissen & Wener, Reference Cornelissen and Werner2014; Fiss & Zajac, Reference Fiss and Zajac2004; Hodgkinson et al., Reference Hodgkinson, Bown, Maule, Glaister and Pearman1999). By influencing the categorization process (Starbuck & Milliken, Reference Starbuck, Milliken and Hambrick1988), frames determine the perceived importance, urgency, or relevance that managers attribute to issues and events (Jackson & Dutton, Reference Jackson and Dutton1988), activate expectations about potential outcomes (Goffman, Reference Goffman1974), shape how attention is allocated (Benner & Tripsas, Reference Benner and Tripsas2012; Ocasio & Joseph, Reference Ocasio, Joseph, Szulanski, Porac and Doz2005), and influence how strategy is formulated (Dutton, Fahey, & Narayanan, Reference Dutton, Fahey and Narayanan1983; Kaplan, Reference Kaplan2008) and implemented (Thomas, Clark, & Gioia, Reference Thomas, Clark and Gioia1993).
One prolific stream of this strategy research examines how frames impact decision-makers’ categorizations and responses to stakeholder evaluations (Bitektine, Reference Bitektine2011; Elsbach, Reference Elsbach2003). For example, some studies show that the way decision-makers frame stakeholders’ feedback results in more or less symbolic responses (e.g., Bass et al., Reference Bass, Pfarrer, Milosevic and Titus2023; Nason, Bacq, & Gras, Reference Nason, Bacq and Gras2018; Wang et al., Reference Wang, Jia, Xiang and Lan2022). In contrast, another stream highlights how mental representations and frames, despite their advantages for information processing and meaning construction, lead to rigidities (Benner & Tripsas, Reference Benner and Tripsas2012; Gilbert, Reference Gilbert2006; Lovallo, Clarke, & Camerer, Reference Lovallo, Clarke and Camerer2012) that can, in turn, introduce biases or blind spots in the strategic decision-making process (e.g., Barr et al., Reference Barr, Stimpert and Huff1992; Tripsas & Gavetti, Reference Tripsas and Gavetti2000). This work suggests that socialization with other relevant actors, including social class peers, business advisors, and family members may alter preexisting schemas, potentially reducing this negative effect (Bartunek & Moch, Reference Bartunek and Moch1987; Nason, Mazzelli, & Carney, Reference Nason, Mazzelli and Carney2019; Strike & Rerup, Reference Strike and Rerup2016).
The conceptual apparatus provided by schema and framing theories is cross-level, and microfoundational, offering individual-level explanations for higher-level organizational phenomena. Nevertheless, the field faces challenges due to the proliferation and inconsistent application of related constructs. This issue is particularly evident in the overlapping and sometimes interchangeable use of terms such as mental representations, cognitive frames, frameworks, schemas, maps, and knowledge structures (Walsh, Reference Walsh1995). For behavioral strategy research to progress, it is crucial to achieve greater conceptual clarity. This entails precisely defining each construct and delineating their specific roles and interactions in the context of interpretation and strategic decision-making. Furthermore, despite notable attempts (e.g., Kaplan, Reference Kaplan2008), further empirical evidence is needed to examine the mechanisms through which individual-level cognitions translate into collective cognition or shared mental models, especially in the presence of spatial and temporal distances between organizational members.
Social Identity Theory, Self-Categorization, and Organizational Identification
Social psychology theories based on identity and self-categorization suggest individuals delineate groups based on perceived features and then affiliate themselves with those satisfying their personal needs for self-definition and meaning (Tajfel, Reference Tajfel1978; Hogg & Terry, Reference Hogg and Terry2000; Tajfel & Turner, Reference Tajfel, Turner and Austin1986). This social categorization process shapes member behaviors. That is, individuals incorporate distinctive group features into their own identity (Tajfel & Turner, Reference Tajfel, Turner and Austin1986; Terry & Hogg, Reference Terry and Hogg1996) and embrace a shared set of values and beliefs, fostering ingroup cohesion and normative behavior (Brewer & Gardner, Reference Brewer and Gardner1996; Tajfel & Turner, Reference Tajfel, Turner and Austin1986). Moreover, this delineation is preserved, as ingroup members craft their attributes, norms, and values relative to outgroups to achieve “optimal distinctiveness” (Brewer, Reference Brewer1991).
Ashforth and Mael’s (Reference Ashforth and Mael1989) work illuminates the role of organizations (and their subgroups) in organizational members’ social identity construction and its impact on the firm (see Ashforth, Harrison, & Corley, Reference Ashforth, Harrison and Corley2008; Ashforth & Johnson, Reference Ashforth, Johnson, Hogg and Terry2001; Dutton, Dukerich, & Harquail, Reference Dutton, Dukerich and Harquail1994; Liu, Fisher, & Chen, Reference Liu, Fisher and Chen2018).Footnote 4 For instance, some scholars illustrate how CEO organizational identification – defined as a CEO’s sense of oneness or belongingness with an organization (Lange, Boivie, & Westphal, Reference Lange, Boivie and Westphal2015; Mael & Ashforth, Reference Mael and Ashforth1992) – can foster goal alignment (Davis, Schoorman, & Donaldson, Reference Davis, Schoorman and Donaldson1997; Kogut & Zander, Reference Kogut and Zander1996), reducing agency costs and, in turn, increasing firm performance (Boivie et al., Reference Boivie, Lange, McDonald and Westphal2011). Relatedly, other scholarly work examines how a CEO’s identification within a particular group in the organization, or adoption of a specific role, shapes their priorities and conduct (e.g., Miller & Breton-Miller, Reference Miller and Le Breton–Miller2011; Miller, Breton-Miller, & Lester, Reference Miller, Le Breton‐Miller and Lester2011).
This work on social identity branches out beyond CEOs. Literature on group faultlines – referred to as virtual dividing lines that split a group into relatively homogeneous subgroups based on group members’ alignment and identification with the subgroup prototype (Lau & Murnighan, Reference Lau and Murnighan1998; Thatcher & Patel, Reference Thatcher and Patel2012) investigates how organizational members’ multiple identities and their relationships shape firm strategy and performance (Lawrence & Zyphur, Reference Lawrence and Zyphur2011). For example, Leicht-Deobalda et al. (Reference Leicht‐Deobald, Huettermann, Bruch and Lawrence2021) show that organizational identification among firm employees can be hampered by demographic faultlines, especially when functional heterogeneity within demographic subgroups is low, in turn, generating negative consequences for firm performance and innovation. Kaczmarek, Kimino, and Pye (Reference Kaczmarek, Kimino and Pye2012) article illustrates how task-related faultlines within corporate boards can have value-destroying effects. Faultlines also have a similar effect in top management teams. Although TMT heterogeneity positively impacts the formulation of deviant competitive actions (Ndofor, Sirmon, & He, Reference Ndofor, Sirmon and He2015), this benefit disappears when strong faultlines are present. This represents a more nuanced view of the impact of demographic characteristics on firm performance in the upper echelon’s research stream (Hambrick & Mason, Reference Hambrick and Mason1984).
Despite these important contributions, the literature on how social identification impacts firm behavior and outcomes is still in its infancy, especially when examining the dark side of overidentification in organizations (Bouchikhi & Kimberly, Reference Bouchikhi and Kimberly2003; Fiol, Reference Fiol1991, Reference Fiol2001). Furthermore, significant empirical challenges exist in reliably assessing whether and to what extent social identification affects distal firm-level variables (cf. Ashforth et al., Reference Ashforth, Harrison and Corley2008).
Enactment and Sensemaking
As mentioned, Weick’s (Reference Weick1979) pioneering work on enactment and sensemaking is at the heart of the interpretative perspectives on managerial cognition. These intertwined constructs assume managers actively shape, or “enact,” their environments through their interpretations and actions, rather than passively receiving environmental stimuli (Sutcliffe, Reference Sutcliffe, Augier and Teece2013; see Maitlis & Sonenshein, Reference Sonenshein2010 for a review). Weick (Reference Weick1995) elucidates seven properties of sensemaking: (1) identity construction, (2) retrospective analysis, (3) enactive, (4) social, (5) ongoing, (6) focused on extracted cues, and (7) driven by plausibility rather than accuracy. These properties underscore the subjective and often post hoc nature of interpretation, emphasizing that sensemaking is not about uncovering objective truths but rather constructing plausible narratives (Balogun & Johnson, 2005).
The stream of work on enactment and sensemaking highlights how organizational members socially construct their environments by developing shared meanings to rationalize ambiguous events and situations (Elsbach, Barr, & Hargadon, Reference Elsbach, Barr and Hargadon2005; Ford & Baucus, Reference Ford and Baucus1987; Perrow, Reference Perrow1984 Weick, Reference Weick1988, Reference Weick2010). For instance, sensemaking is triggered in contexts where expectations are violated (Daft & Weick, Reference Daft and Weick1984), such as during environmental jolts and organizational crises (e.g., Christianson et al., Reference Christianson, Farkas, Sutcliffe and Weick2009; Meyer, Reference Meyer1982) as well as in response to identity threats (e.g., Elsbach & Kramer, Reference Elsbach and Kramer1996; Ravasi & Schulz, Reference Ravasi and Schultz2006; Weick, Reference Weick1995). According to this perspective, action and discourse are the main means to create understanding, allowing organizational members to “consolidate an otherwise unorganized set of environmental elements” and achieve intersubjective meaning creation (Weick, Reference Weick1988: 135).
Top managers and other influential organizational members have an important role in guiding collective sensemaking processes (Balogun & Johnson, Reference Balogun and Johnson2004; Monin et al., Reference Monin, Noorderhaven, Vaara and Kroon2013). To capture this notion, Gioia and Chittipeddi (Reference Gioia and Chittipeddi1991) introduced the concept of sensegiving, where influential figures within organizations attempt to shape the perceptions of others, promoting certain understandings of events and situations. This work emphasizes the leaders’ roles in crafting and framing organizational narratives as “the preferred sensemaking currency” (Boje, Reference Boje1991: 161; e.g., Brown, Stacey, & Nandhakumar, Reference Brown, Stacey and Nandhakumar2008; Maitlis & Lawrence, Reference Maitlis and Lawrence2007).
Likely the most significant way in which sensemaking research influences strategy research is through work elucidating how sensemaking enables or inhibits key organizational processes, including learning (Christianson et al., Reference Christianson, Farkas, Sutcliffe and Weick2009; Thomas, Sussman, & Henderson, Reference Thomas, Sussman and Henderson2001), strategic change (Corley & Gioia, Reference Corley and Gioia2004; Nag et al., Reference Nag, Corley and Gioia2007), and innovation (Dougherty et al., Reference Dougherty, Borrelli, Munir and O’Sullivan2000; Jay, Reference Jay2013). A clear theme emerging from this literature is the importance of sensemaking in developing novel meanings that underpin new ways of understanding and organizing.
As the business landscape grows in complexity and uncertainty, Weick’s interpretative lens becomes increasingly salient. Future endeavors should build on his rich theoretical bedrock by comparing multiple instances of sensemaking to examine when and how individuals collectively construct new meanings and how this process affects firm behavior and outcomes. Because sensemaking intersects with other theoretical domains, there is also a need to clarify the boundaries of this construct to ensure its theoretical distinctiveness.
Conclusion: The Future of Managerial and Organizational Cognition
Frames and mental representations, social identity and identification, and sensemaking emerge as important constructs to elucidate the microfoundations of firm behavior and outcomes. For example, when industry environments change, schema theory and the related concepts of frames and mental representations point to the cognitive frameworks that strategists use to recognize, interpret, and negotiate unfamiliar information from the external environment, enabling managers to classify information and form subjective representations of the environment, including social evaluations. Similarly, the constructs of social identity and identification shed light on how managers’ personal and social self-concepts influence the impact of organizational design on firm strategic choices. Finally, sensemaking anchors schemas and identity in the realm of dynamic interpretation and meaning-making. It emphasizes the ongoing nature of understanding, suggesting that strategists continually weave and reweave their narratives to retrospectively make and give sense to what occurs. This is also particularly important for understanding microfoundations of competitive advantage. As the external environment changes, managers with different views of their organizations are likely to develop divergent interpretations, suggesting that responses to environmental changes may be different.
Looking ahead, behavioral strategy researchers interested in the role of cognition in organizations will need to confront challenges concerning theoretical fragmentation and construct proliferation, the need for empirical evidence of aggregation mechanisms, and validity. In particular, despite the fundamental synergies between the various perspectives presented, we are still a long way from a truly integrated interpretative perspective. The main hurdles come from the proliferation and inconsistent use of constructs. First, there is a significant ontological divide on whether cognition is solely an individual-level construct or if a collective supra-individual cognition also exists (Maitlis & Sonenshein, Reference Sonenshein2010; Walsh, Reference Walsh1995). Relatedly, some scholars view sensemaking as a within-individual process through which one develops schema and mental models (e.g., Hill & Levenhagen, Reference Hill and Levenhagen1995; Starbuck & Milliken, Reference Starbuck, Milliken and Hambrick1988), whereas others conceive it as inherently social (e.g., Maitlis, Reference Maitlis2005; Weick, Reference Weick2005). This tension could probably be resolved by providing evidence of the mechanisms through which organizational members “produce, negotiate, and sustain a shared sense of meaning” (Gephart et al., Reference Gephart, Topal, Zhang, Hernes and Maitlis2010: 285). Being explicit in the level of analysis and producing empirical evidence of cross-level mechanisms would also be important to avoid arbitrary anthropomorphizing tendencies (granting organizations analogous agency to think and act as humans (cf. Whetten, Reference Whetten2006: 221)), which may undermine the importance of strategy microfoundations.
Still, such mechanisms are extremely difficult to observe, measure, and compare, as they are highly contextual. Even though scholars have established and employed an impressive array of procedures to produce fine-grained empirical accounts – including case studies, ethnographies, text analysis, and cognitive mapping techniques – doubts remain regarding the adequacy of these techniques and their relative merits (Hodgkinson & Healey, Reference Hodgkinson and Healey2008). We see value in methods that allow for systematic comparisons, such as causal mapping, as it may allow future research to shed light on relevant contextual contingencies and, thus, specify boundary conditions on existing theory. We will return to some of these methods in Section 5.
4 Behavioral Governance: Synthesizing Carnegie-Based and Governance Perspectives
Introduction
Research on governance – the mechanisms deployed to control or coordinate organizational agents or exchanges within or between firms (alternative contracts and governance structures) – developed independent of the various behavioral strategy theories. Governance research traditionally arose from the organizational economics literature (e.g., Jensen & Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1976; Williamson, Reference Williamson1985), which did not overlap with the behavioral strategy literatures. However, when governance research is augmented with psychology, a place for governance theories emerged in behavioral strategy. Thus, adding realistic behavioral assumptions to traditional governance theories (e.g., agency theory and TCE) allows us to bring this work together with organizational design research (e.g., Galbraith, Reference Galbraith1973; Burton & Obel, Reference Burton and Obel2018) and the attention-based view of the firm (Ocasio, Reference Ocasio1997) in a novel research agenda that we term behavioral governance.
We envision behavioral governance as an approach that draws on realistic behavioral assumptions to design systems, mechanisms, or organizations to promote coordination and cooperation between parties. This approach considers information salience, flow, and interpretation, in addition to the mitigation of agency or transaction costs arising from cognitive and emotional sources. It leads to two main objectives of this section. The first goal is to highlight the importance of aligning the behavioral assumptions in traditional governance theories with those in the attention-based view and organizational design literatures. This is a necessary step to allow the three literatures to be used together and to build on one another. The second goal is to then bring these three areas of research together to create an exciting research stream that offers managers, with limited attention and information as well as a myriad of motivations, realistic guidance for designing governance with minimal transaction costs arising from conflict and coordination issues between the parties.
To understand the promise of behavioral governance, we start by briefly sketching the Carnegie tradition (Simon, 1947; March & Simon, Reference March and Simon1958) and its links to these three literatures (economic governance augmented with psychology, organizational design, and the attention-based view of the firm) to understand why bringing them together augments our understanding of governance design. Then we present the attention-based view of the firm and organizational design literatures, noting their realistic behavioral assumptions. Next, we explore the nascent work on augmenting economic-based theories of the firm. Finally, we examine how bringing these three perspectives together creates significant opportunities for future research in behavioral governance.
Behavioral Roots in the Carnegie Tradition
As discussed in Sections 2 and 3, the Carnegie tradition concentrated on decision-making in the organization based on realistic behavioral assumptions, and how this leads to firm-level actions such as resource allocation. This multidisciplinary approach was a reaction to the firm-level focus of economic theory at the time. Simon (1948) introduced the idea of bounded rationality, suggesting that “human behavior is intendedly rational but only limitedly so” due to cognitive constraints. Large swaths of organization theory were directly based on this idea, and of course, March and Simon’s (Reference March and Simon1958) Organizations, another foundational work in the Carnegie school, further extended bounded rationality in an organizational context. Specifically, it examined how bounded rationality leads to “simplified subjective representations of objective reality” (Bromiley et al., Reference Bromiley, Koumakhov, Rousseau and Starbuck2019: 1519) in organizations, influencing all managerial decision-making. They also argued that organizations are mechanisms for coordinating information flows to increase exchange performance. Together, these aspects are the basis of the information-processing perspective, in which the organizational design literature and the attention-based view are rooted.
Finally, Cyert and March’s (Reference Cyert and March1963: 19) Behavioral Theory of the Firm used these concepts to examine “the fundamental decisions of the firm, decisions such as price, output, and resource allocation.” As a result, they predicted how “a firm behaves as a result of lower-level processes, possibly involving individual and group, and certainly leading to observable decisions on economically important variables” (Gavetti, Greve, Levinthal, & Ocasio, Reference Gavetti, Greve, Levinthal and Ocasio2012: 3). This book specifically brought in the idea of power and politics, and how to design the organization to mitigate these issues, which again is similar to the psychologically augmented economic-based governance research.
Yet, despite the common roots in the Carnegie tradition, economic-based governance theory is not typically combined with organizational design research or the attention-based view because the underlying behavioral assumptions are incompatible. That is, while the attention-based view and the organizational design literatures embrace a full spectrum of motivations and bounds on individuals’ rationality, the economic-based governance literature does not.
Behavioral Governance Theories with Realistic Behavioral Assumptions
As suggested, both the attention-based view of the firm (Ocasio, Reference Ocasio1997) and the organizational design literature (e.g., Galbraith, Reference Galbraith1973; Burton & Obel, Reference Burton and Obel2018) fully embrace individuals’ cognitive limits and motivations. The attention-based view explores how the firm directs management and employee attention, influencing firm behavior. Furthermore, the field of organizational design examines how the arrangement of organizational units and authority impacts knowledge flows.
The Attention-Based View of the Firm
Ocasio (Reference Ocasio1997) expanded Simon’s (1961) bounded rationality into the attention-based view of the firm, which addresses coordination inside the firm. He specifically suggested that firm behavior results from the way in which firms direct the attention of the individuals within it. As such, the organizational actors’ information is both limited and distorted by the firm in which they work. This approach is frequently used in both theoretical work (Ocasio & Joseph, Reference Ocasio, Joseph, Szulanski, Porac and Doz2005) and empirical studies (e.g., Bouquet & Birkinshaw, Reference Bouquet and Birkinshaw2008; Bouquet, et al., Reference Bouquet, Morrison and Birkinshaw2009; Hung, Reference Hung2005; Ocasio & Joseph, Reference Ocasio and Joseph2008). For example, Joseph and Wilson (Reference Joseph and Wilson2018) used the attention-based view to predict when the firm will expand to include new subunits to address intrafirm attentional conflicts. This type of work explores using organizational design to direct employee attention to increase coordination.
Organization Design
There is also a large body of work on organization design (e.g., Galbraith Reference Galbraith1973; Burton & Obel, Reference Burton and Obel2018). This research stream addresses coordination and cooperation inside the firm. That is, organizational design research “investigate[s] the information flows essential for accomplishing the organization’s objectives, then examine[s] what these information patterns imply for organization structure” (Simon, Reference Simon1967: 1). This work relies on the simplistic mental representations proposed by March and Simon (Reference March and Simon1958), and the influence that organizational structure has on them. Thus, organizational actors in this theory have both limits on the amount of information processed, as well as distortions of this information due to the organization’s design. There are many studies in this area that examine how these information processing needs lead to centralization and decentralization in the organization (e.g., Obel & Burton, Reference Obel and Burton1984; Galbraith, Reference Galbraith1973, Reference Galbraith1977; Thompson, Reference Thompson1967; Tushman & Nadler, Reference Tushman and Nadler1978).
Augmenting Economic-Based Governance Theory with Psychology
In contrast to the focus on information flows and attention, economic-based governance theories focus on the design of effective exchanges within and between firms to mitigate transaction costs. Two main theories guide this study: agency theory and TCE.
Agency theory examines how a principal delegates a task to a self-interested agent (Jensen & Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1976). The principal, the residual claimant, pays the agent for their work. However, because their interests differ, the agent is not likely to act in the interest of the principal without proper incentives (Eisenhardt, Reference Eisenhardt1989). Specifically, this approach focuses on designing the optimal contract to align principal and agent interests.
Transaction cost economics (Williamson, Reference Williamson1985) focuses instead on minimizing transaction costs in the exchange by discriminately aligning ex post governance structure with transaction hazards (Williamson, Reference Williamson1975; Reference Williamson1985). In this theory, boundedly rational actors create unavoidably incomplete contracts, which cannot safeguard an exchange characterized by asset specificity, the presence of highly specific assets with no value in another exchange (Riordan & Williamson, Reference Williamson1985). Asset specificity allows one party to holdup the other, creating transaction costs in the exchange. That is, an opportunistic party can take advantage of the party with the specific investment because the latter has no other options. As such, transaction hazards pose a significant risk for parties in an exchange, as ex post adaptation is likely, and cannot be fully safeguarded against in a contract. Williamson (Reference Williamson1991) then discriminately matches the level of the transaction hazard with three governance forms (market, hybrids, and hierarchy) based on their ability to mitigate them. In his analysis, markets efficiently govern transactions with low asset specificity, while hierarchies efficiently govern those with high specificity, and hybrids best govern those in between.
Misaligned Behavioral Assumptions
However, the behavioral assumptions underlying these two economic-based theories do not match those of the attention-based view and organization design, making it difficult to combine them. In particular, agency theory is firmly based on the traditional economics model of maximization. Transaction cost economics, which creates a discriminating alignment between exchange characteristics and efficient governance to mitigate transaction costs, assumes boundedly rational actors. Even with these assumptions, the theories narrowly define actors’ cognitive limitations, in the case of TCE including bounds on the amount of information they process (Foss & Weber, Reference Foss and Weber2016) and in the case of principal-agent theory recognizing no such bounds but postulating asymmetric information conditions. The thin bounded rationality assumption of TCE (Foss, Reference Foss2001) allows all contracts to be unavoidably incomplete, which is necessary for agency and transaction costs to arise ex post (Eisenhardt, Reference Eisenhardt1989; Williamson, Reference Williamson1985). However, it ignores the distortions due to cognitive biases and heuristics (e.g., Tversky and Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974) that Simon intended. Thus, as conceived, it is incompatible with the full form of bounded rationality assumed in both the organizational design and the attention-based view literatures.
Moreover, both theories focus solely on negative motivations. Agency theory only considers self-interest, suggesting agents act in their own interest, unless these are aligned with those of the agent (Eisenhardt, Reference Eisenhardt1989). TCE takes this self-interested view further by assuming an even stronger form of self-interest, opportunism. Opportunism is self-interest seeking “with guile” (Williamson, Reference Williamson1985), which permits actors to lie, cheat, and steal in pursuit of their own interests, as they are not constrained by laws and rules. Again, the motivational assumptions of these economic-based governance theories are incompatible with those of organizational design research and the attention-based view, which both allow for more expansive positive (e.g., reciprocity) or negative (e.g., internal politics) motivations.
Given these extensive differences in both cognitive and motivational assumptions of economic-based governance theories and the attention-based view and organizational design literatures, there is a need to augment the less complex behavioral assumptions of the former to bring them in line with those of the latter. Some work has started to do just that. However, this work has only begun to scratch the surface of expanding these behavioral assumptions for governance.
Behavioral Agency Theory
Scholars expanded the behavioral assumptions of agency theory in two ways. First, they put bounded rationality assumptions in the form of cognitive distortions explicitly into the foundations of the theory. Second, they increased the precision of negative motivations, as well as added positive motivations into agency theory.
Cognitive Expansion. Behavioral agency theory augments agency theory with a variety of cognitive constraints that distort the information processes. Specifically, problem framing, drawing on prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979), was added to address agent risk-taking behavior (Wiseman & Gomez-Mejia, Reference Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia1998), with greater risk-taking linked to positive versus negative framing. Further, Foss and Stea (Reference Foss and Stea2014) augmented agency theory with boundedly rational sensemaking, allowing the principal to learn the agent’s effort and type. This addition allowed for the reduction of information asymmetry, leading to greater value creation in the exchange than predicted by traditional agency theory.
Motivational Expansion. More recent work elaborated on the motivational assumptions of agency theory. The broad concept of self-interest was replaced with the negative emotions of envy, guilt, and greed, and augmented with the positive motivation of fairness (Pepper, Gosling, & Gore, Reference Pepper, Gosling and Gore2015). This greater specificity was better able to explain the results found in empirical data than the rational choice model. Further, Bosse and Phillips (Reference Bosse and Phillips2016) combined traditional agency theory with the positive motivations of reciprocity and fairness to limit self-interest, resulting in the expansion of the theory from simply limiting self-serving agent behaviors to expanding social welfare. Further, Pepper and Gore (Reference Pepper and Gore2015) centered the agents in the theory, suggesting motivated managers tended to perform better than those with incentives aligned with the principal. Finally, Cuevas-Rodríguez, Gomez-Mejia, and Wiseman (Reference Cuevas‐Rodríguez, Gomez‐Mejia and Wiseman2012) added trust to suggest that agents can behave honestly and loyally, leading to cooperative relationships with the principal.
Behavioral Transaction Cost Economics
Additionally, since the inception of TCE, scholars continued to offer expansions of the behavioral assumptions underlying the theory (e.g., Ouchi, Reference Ouchi1980; Ghoshal & Moran, Reference Ghoshal and Moran1996). As with behavioral agency theory, this augmentation resulted in different predictions than traditional TCE.
Cognitive Expansion. Like agency theory, TCE’s bounded rationality assumption was also expanded. In the context of contractual governance, Weber and Mayer (Reference Weber and Mayer2011) examined how contract frames impact views of the exchange, emotions, behaviors, and exchange relationships. Further, Weber and Bauman (Reference Weber and Bauman2019) empirically extended this theory by uncovering attributions of benevolence as the underlying psychological mechanism. Additional research in this area examined how regulatory focus impacts contract design (Weber, Mayer, & Macher, Reference Weber, Mayer and Macher2011), as well as how contract design influences trust development and learning in repeated exchanges (Weber Reference Weber2017), and innovation (Mayer, Xing, & Mondal, Reference Mayer, Xing and Mondal2022). Finally, Weber and Coff (Reference Weber and Coff2023) elaborated on the idea of cognitive biases to suggest asset specificity perceptions drive most governance decisions, and these perceptions are likely to be biased and even manipulated.
Foss and Weber (Reference Foss and Weber2016) moved the discussion of augmented bounded rationality away from contract framing. Instead, they focused on how bounded rationality alone may lead to specific transaction costs inside the firm. Moreover, Nickerson and co-authors drew on an expanded bounded rationality assumption to identify antecedents to governance decisions, creating the problem formulation-problem solving perspectives (e.g., Nickerson, Silverman, & Zenger, Reference Nickerson, Silverman and Zenger2007; Baer, Dirks, & Nickerson, 2009).
Motivational Expansion. Additionally, due to the concern over Williamson’s negative motivational assumption in TCE (Ghoshal & Moran, Reference Ghoshal and Moran1996), scholars expanded this behavioral assumption. Ouchi (Reference Ouchi1980) brought social comparison into TCE, introducing clan governance to address it. Moreover, Ouchi and Barney (Reference Ouchi and Barney1980) suggested goal alignment influences the efficient governance form, expanding the options from market and hierarchy to include clans, bureaucracies, quasi-markets, and their intermediate forms. Further, Husted and Folger (Reference Husted and Folger2004) elaborated on this idea, incorporating organizational justice into the theory and arguing that transaction costs typically occur because it is difficult to assess fairness in an exchange. Nickerson and Zenger (Reference Nickerson and Zenger2008) further expanded on the incorporation of social comparison in TCE, showing that these comparisons and their resulting negative emotions can lead to hierarchical failure, as they and their associated costs increase with the scope and scale of the firm. More recently, Weber, Foss, and Lindenberg (Reference Weber, Foss and Lindenberg2023) expanded Williamson’s opportunism assumption into different types of opportunisms, as well as added the positive motivation of cooperation. Specifically, they suggested that different hierarchical forms tend to invoke distinct motivations, which lead to specific behaviors.
A Behavioral Governance Research Agenda
Simon (Reference Simon1985: 303) argued that in thinking about designing a transaction for optimal performance, “[n]othing is more fundamental in setting our research agenda and informing our research methods than our view of the nature of the human beings whose behavior we are studying.” By augmenting economic-based governance theory with psychology, we contend it can be combined with the attention-based view and organizational design to create high-performance transactions within and between firms. This goal suggests two separate but critical future research streams in behavioral governance to gain a more realistic understanding of how to design efficient transactions.
Psychology-Augmented Governance Theory
First, the work on augmenting economic-based governance theories with psychology is in its infancy. While work on contract framing has gained some traction, there are still ample opportunities to examine the impact of other bounds on rationality in these theories. Moreover, the studies on expanding motivations and adding the impact of external environments on governance are just starting to emerge. Finally, the idea of bringing in informational, attentional, and governance issues together to design high-performance transactions has not yet been done. Thus, this area of research is wide-open, offering extensive opportunities for future work.
Opportunities to Expand Bounded Rationality. There are several areas for additional research in expanding the bounded rationality assumption in economic-based governance theories. First, behavioral agency theory is much less developed than behavioral TCE. As a result, research on the impact of framing tasks and incentives, beyond those using prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979), should be considered, as the prior work using prospect theory has been criticized as improperly applying base predictions from the lens to the firm (Bromiley, Reference Bromiley2010). For example, considering the impact of prevention and promotion framing in agency theory could create interesting prescriptions for managers who are looking to induce vigilant versus eager behavior in their agents.
Additionally, even in TCE, the work on framing only considered regulatory focus theory. However, there are other ways to frame the same contract. For example, the contract’s time horizon could be framed as short term versus long term. Additionally, contract detail could be framed at a high-level or extremely detailed, based on construal theory. Moreover, the exchange relationship between the partners can be framed as competitive or cooperative. Thus, there are many different possibilities for framing the exact same contract that have not yet been explored.
Another distortion of human cognition emerges from stereotypes. While organizational behavior research examines how gender and racial stereotypes impact individual career paths and job satisfaction, this work does not examine how these cognitive elements influence transactions within and between firms. Yet, these stereotypes can influence organizational actors’ perceptions of opportunistic behavior or the attributions of benevolence, directly impacting transaction performance. Further, while some studies explore attributions of performance in exchanges, no one explicitly examines when the fundamental attribution error may occur, which may impact the formation of trust, as well as the perception of opportunistic behavior in the exchange. As such, both aspects of governance are virtually unexplored at this time.
In addition, only one study (Weber & Coff, Reference Weber and Coff2023) examines the biases and malleability of perceptions of key TCE constructs, such as asset specificity, uncertainty, and frequency. Additionally, the concept of perceptions has not been brought into agency theory at all. Yet, in both cases, it is likely that perceptions of these key constructs drive both choices and behaviors in these theories. Thus, it is imperative to understand how incorporating perceptions into these economic-based governance theories may change their predictions and may explain empirical evidence that traditional theories cannot address.
Finally, most psychological theories address individual behaviors, which is appropriate for its application to agency theory. However, TCE discusses firm-level outcomes. Thus, when augmenting TCE with psychology, there is a need to either work with transactions involving a small group of managers or to examine how these effects aggregate to the firm level. That is, the cognitive impact on a single person does not matter unless that impact is likely to dominate the individuals in the transaction. Thus, there is a need for a deeper examination of this topic.
Opportunities to Expand Motivations. In addition to these opportunities to extend the cognitive assumptions in agency theory and TCE, there is also a need for research that expands the motivational assumptions of these theories. For example, nonconscious affect could impact contract design. That is, witnessing a supplier manager berating their assistant during a negotiation, may unconsciously activate negative exchange attitudes, leading to the inclusion of more safeguards in the contract.
Moreover, while emotions are examined as an outcome variable in behavioral governance, their influence on transaction costs or governance is not yet explored. Emotions were shown to impact both cognition and motivation. Thus, they are good candidates for future exploration in economic-based governance theories.
Additionally, most motivations examined in agency theory and TCE are broad. That is, self-interest and opportunism are both negative, but not precise motivations. Thus, there is also a need to expand the types of opportunisms that may be motivating specific behaviors. So far, only one paper explores a more nuanced look at opportunism (Weber, Foss, & Lindenberg, Reference Weber, Foss and Lindenberg2023). Further, while a few positive motivations are incorporated into agency theory (e.g., Devers, Cannella, Reilly, & Yoder, Reference Devers, Cannella, Reilly and Yoder2007), fewer are incorporated into TCE. Thus, there is a broad area of motivational expansion that can occur in economic-based governance theory.
Finally, while the expansion of TCE’s motivations started with social comparison, little empirical research examines envy costs. In addition, there has not been an application of this concept to alliances or contracts. As a result, there is a significant opportunity to explore this extension as well.
Holistic Behavioral Governance Theories
There are also several opportunities to bring attention, knowledge flows, and governance together to design optimal transactions within and between firms. For example, incentives can be used to increase knowledge flows. Further, organizational design can impact perceptions of transaction hazards, impacting governance choice. To understand the potential for this combination to expand our understanding of transaction performance, we explore a few of these potential areas of interest in detail.
Situated Cognition and Motivation in Governance. First, there is a chance to bring in the attention-based view of the firm to understand how perceptions of governance variables are formed, and how they may be biased. Additionally, by bringing concepts of organizational design into governance, Williamson’s concept of administrative mechanisms can be expanded to include centralization and decentralization, as well as other aspects of structure. Further, organizational structures are likely to impact managers’ and employees’ motivations, which also can be used to inform contracts in agency theory. As there may be opportunities to shape agent behavior without aligning their incentives in an employment contract.
Design to Optimize Organization Performance. In addition, organizational design may increase or reduce the need for governance, while potentially also allowing for optimal information flow. Thus, rather than focusing on one aspect of the other, the field can return to multi-theoretical perspectives, such as those that dominated economic-based strategy in the early 2000s (transaction cost plus the resource-based view, for example), but in a behavioral strategy realm. Neither information flows nor governance are mutually exclusive in an organization. Instead, each aspect likely influences the other, so it is important to understand how these elements work together or in opposition when designing the organization.
Design to Optimize Transaction Performance. Moreover, the only research examining how transactions are designed is within the context of organizations (i.e., the organizational design literature). While this is an interesting topic, the governance literature is also interested in how transactions between firms (e.g., alliances) or within markets are designed. Given that not all markets, contracts, or alliances are the same, but instead may have many different characteristics, these may be used as design levers to both increase information flows and minimize transaction costs. Also, these different governance forms shape actors’ attention, which further impacts their perceptions in these transactions, bringing in the attention-based view (Ocasio, Reference Ocasio1997).
Tradeoffs between Informational Benefits and Transaction Costs. Finally, there are likely tradeoffs between optimizing information flow and minimizing transaction costs. There is a huge opportunity to examine when these would occur and the most effective solutions to address them. There is also a significant prospect to examine how to potentially shape managers’ or employees’ attention to avoid these tradeoffs.
Conclusion
The promise of behavioral governance is significant. By augmenting economic-based governance theory with psychology, we can create common behavioral assumptions, allowing us to bring together attention, design, and governance. This multi-theoretical view of transactions within and between organizations is a powerful lens that provides a more complete view of how to optimize all aspects of a transaction, not just transaction cost mitigation, knowledge flow, or managerial attention. Thus, this approach offers a more holistic understanding of transactions, as well as more realistic advice for managers who are overseeing them.
5 Advancing Behavioral Strategy Research: A Microfoundational Roadmap
Behavioral Strategy Research: The Search for Generalizability, Parsimony, and Accuracy
A basic theme of this Element is that behavioral strategy is a fundamentally microfoundational approach rooted in robust, evidence-based knowledge of human nature, behavior, and social interaction. Despite the many advances in linking the psychology of organizational actors and firms’ behaviors and outcomes, much (perhaps most) work in strategy still treats the organization as an almost “mechanistic” entity governed by rules and processes, and acquiring and developing resources and competencies to fulfill the demands of the external environment. Decision-making, including generating, implementing, and executing strategy, easily gets lost in such an account. Surprisingly, this is also a problem in behavioral strategy.
Throughout this Element, we highlighted how behavioral strategy still needs to overcome multiple microfoundational challenges related to theorizing and testing aggregation mechanisms (i.e., Sections 2 and 3), finding unity within diversity (i.e., Sections 3 and 4), enhancing construct clarity and avoiding their proliferation (i.e., Sections 3 and 4), and integrating methods (i.e., Sections 2 and 3). For instance, we argued that concepts such as bounded rationality (Section 2), mental representations (Section 3), and attention (Sections 2 and 4) have been often unreflectively applied to the organizational level. This runs the risk of granting organizations analogous agency to humans. We also highlighted how the same construct (e.g., bounded rationality) has been defined in very different and ways across different research streams (Section 4), how constructs with overlapping theoretical meanings have been given distinct labels (Section 3), and how less stable psychological constructs, such as affect and emotions, have received less attention because of measurability issues (Section 2).
Arguably, some of these issues are rooted in the historical evolution of the field of behavioral strategy and the goals that Simon set for himself and posterity with his theory of decision-making. As mentioned in Section 2, Simon’s original goal was to develop a generalizable, simple, and accurate theory that would have predicted individual choice across a variety of contexts and problem situations. However, as Thorngate argued, “It is impossible for a theory of social behavior to be simultaneously general, simple or parsimonious, and accurate” (1976: 406).Footnote 5 Over the years, the balance tilted in favor either of generalizability and parsimony, or accuracy.
Attempts to develop generalizable and parsimonious theories largely resulted in desubjectification tendencies, with behavioral scholars shifting attention from the micro level (individuals and their interactions) to the mechanisms governing and stabilizing exchanges among individuals (or, more precisely, coalitions of individuals). For example, to solve the problem of defining organizational goals, Cyert and March shifted their focus away from the conflicting motivations and preferences of individuals and the bargaining processes underlying coalition formation and goal priorities, towards an assumption of quasi-resolution of conflict as a mechanism leading to goal stabilization (Reference Cyert and March1963: 30–39) (see Mithani & O’Brien, Reference Mithani and O’Brien2021 for a review). This issue is also pervasive in the upper echelons theory (Hambrick & Mason, Reference Hambrick and Mason1984): although this theory emphasizes the importance of characterizing the linkages among individuals, organizations, and their competitive environments, it assumes the top management team “embodies” the cognition of the organization.
On the other hand, attempts to develop realistic and accurate theories have certainly provided rich insights into local meanings and micro practices, but sometimes at the risk of downplaying the connections between local subjective worlds and macro-organizational processes and phenomena (cf. Prasad & Prasad, Reference Prasad and Prasad2002). Research opportunities may likely emerge from better balancing generalizability and accuracy (at the expense of parsimony). This would require a commitment towards social contextualization (i.e., who, what, where, when, why, and how) by adding detail and contextual reality to develop theories with substantially greater power to predict real-world organizational behaviors and outcomes both within and across contexts. In this respect, the first fundamental step is characterizing the organizational member(s) involved in the firm-level phenomenon (or decision) being investigated. It also requires a shift from treating levels of analysis as compartmentalized theoretical domains toward a focus on situated social interactions among relevant actors within and outside the organizations as the loci of aggregation. This new approach may not only overcome some of the aforementioned challenges and fill some of the voids in the current behavioral strategy landscape but also influence the direction of strategy research at large.
More generally, microfoundations are theoretically generative: new or revised assumptions about the cognition, motivations, and abilities of individuals and how they interact are likely to result in new theory (Foss & Hallberg, Reference Foss and Hallberg2014). For example, in Section 4, we argued that bringing in psychological and motivational factors such as contract framing and emotions, may affect governance theories’ predictions regarding contractual design and outcomes. In this section, we present a roadmap for future microfoundational research on behavioral strategy, proposing a series of research questions inspired by fundamental considerations about better contextualizing current theories. See the following Table 1.
Topic | Research Question(s) |
---|---|
Strategic Beliefs and Interfaces | How are strategic beliefs regarding competitive dynamics formed and altered through interfaces within and across organizational boundaries (in the absence of direct communication channels)? |
Motivations and Noncognitive Elements |
|
Goal Frames and Organizational Performance | How do differences in individual goal frames within cross-functional teams impact the development and execution of organizational strategies? |
Imagination and Strategic Narratives | How do shared strategic narratives among employees contribute to generating new solutions under conditions of deficient knowledge and experience? |
Predispositions and Unconscious Competence | What mechanisms enable organizations to tap into the collective unconscious competencies to drive innovation? |
Coalition Formation Dynamics | What is the role played by emotions, primary needs (e.g., need to belong), as well as stable personality traits, in either counterbalancing or accentuating mental model differences during coalition formation? |
Leadership and Mental Models |
|
Governance and Mental Model Divergences |
|
Strategists’ Psychology and Organizational Design |
|
Decision-Making and Performance Outcomes |
|
AI’s Role in Decision-Making |
|
Uncertainty and Adaptive Heuristics |
|
Theoretical Avenues
The Who?
Most work in behavioral strategy focuses on top managers’ decision-making, whereas applications to decision-making at lower levels are less common. However, decision-making at lower levels may impact the phenomena that behavioral strategy researchers are investigating, notably because such decisions may aggregate to firm-level outcomes (e.g., Foss & Weber). Such aggregation may happen through social interaction. Relatedly, a nascent microfoundational stream in strategy research encourages a focus on interfaces – that is, “instances in which individuals’ attributes, aspirations, and activities influence one another” – as germane for explicitly considering “both sides of the ledger” in terms of the actors involved” and their proximate and distal organization-level outcomes (Simsek, Heavey, & Fox, Reference Simsek, Heavey and Fox2018: 284). Indeed, interfaces are not only the primary means for strategic leaders to carry out their daily work but also the main conduit for bottom-up influence. For example, Dutton and Ashford (Reference Dutton and Ashford1993) show how middle managers’ issue-selling efforts focus senior managers’ attention and shape their understanding of strategic issues. and teams outside of the TMT, but catalyzed by the interactions of managers at different levels. Huy, Corley, and Kraatz (Reference Huy, Corley and Kraatz2014) shed light on how the emotions of middle-level managers can play a significant role in fostering or hampering the implementation of strategic changes, thus potentially affecting firm adaptation and performance. Sonenshein (Reference Sonenshein2010) highlights how managers’ and employees’ narratives about strategic change interact to either facilitate or hinder implementation.
In sum, framing the “who” from an interface perspective is likely to trigger questions about what intersects at the interface (e.g., goals, cognitions, emotions). It also prompts investigation into the type of influence at the interface (motivational, cognitive, behavioral), its direction (up, down, lateral), and its pattern (constraining, enabling) (Simsek et al., Reference Simsek, Heavey and Fox2018). This examination offers opportunities to understand which interactions, among whom, shape firm strategies, influence decision-making processes, and ultimately drive firm performance.
The What?
Our discussion of the behavioral strategy landscape so far suggests that existing perspectives largely explore the cognitive side of bounded rationality (Gigerenzer & Goldstein, Reference Gigerenzer and Goldstein1996). Yet, even this topic has not been fully examined, suggesting that there is still significant potential for research in this area. Moreover, noncognitive elements including motivations, goals, emotions, imagination, and predispositions, have not been incorporated into behavioral strategy research. We examine the potential for incorporating these aspects into behavioral strategy research below.
Strategic Beliefs. In traditional decision-making models, beliefs are estimates of the payoffs associated with the decision alternatives. Some scholars suggest that explicitly integrating them into the existing theories may lead to new firm-level predictions, such as search in response to increasing performance (rather than decreasing, as traditionally posited) (e.g., Keil, Posen, & Workiewicz, Reference Keil, Posen and Workiewicz2023). Belief updating is another area for potential work in behavioral strategy research. While research on Bayesian approaches to belief updating (e.g., Cyert & DeGroot, Reference Cyert and DeGroot1974; Daw et al., Reference Daw, Gershman, Seymour, Dayan and Dolan2011) could be extended to predict firm behaviors and outcomes, it would not solve the basic problem that Bayesianism cannot address unforeseen events, surprises, and novelty (Ehrig & Foss, Reference Ehrig and Foss2022). Moreover, as March and Olsen point out, individual beliefs and models of the world are not always tied to experience and objective reality – “individuals, as well as organizations or nations, develop myths, fictions, legends, and illusions.” (1975: 154). In particular, ideologies often serve as lenses through which information is interpreted, guiding how it is assimilated and beliefs are updated (Semadeni, Chin, & Krause, Reference Semadeni, Chin and Krause2022). This interpretation process can, therefore, lead to belief updating that is less about Bayesian adjustments and more about reinforcing existing frameworks and worldviews (Staw & Ross, Reference Staw and Ross1980). Further exploration into the nuances of belief formation and updating in organizations, especially those not rooted in direct experience, may offer valuable insights for behavioral strategy. Indeed, such an exploration would allow for a more dynamic and comprehensive understanding of experience- vs. non-experience-based belief updating. This distinction may make beliefs more or less likely to change, and therefore, have a greater or lesser influence on strategic decisions and competitive outcomes.
Motivations. Motivational issues in general, and employee motivation in particular, are under-explored research avenues in behavioral strategy (with some exceptions, such as Bridoux, Coeurderoy, & Durand, Reference Bridoux, Coeurderoy and Durand2011; Lindenberg & Foss Reference Lindenberg and Foss2011). However, there are many opportunities for linking motivations at various levels in the firm to key strategic issues. The current dominant motivational theory is self-determination theory (Deci & Ryan, Reference Deci and Ryan2012: 416) which theorizes a spectrum of motivational drivers. Future behavioral strategy research may explore how this fine-grained theory of motivation can be linked to organizational characteristics, different governance instruments and ways of managing, and different aggregate outcomes (e.g., competitive advantage).
Complementing intrinsic and prosocial motivations is “idealism,” that is, the pursuit of lofty, often unbounded goals, unconstrained by conventional notions of practicality. This form of idealism, as Schilling (Reference Schilling2018: 338) notes, can lead to the formation of superordinate goals, driving individuals towards higher aspirations. Such an idealistic pursuit within organizational contexts can, for example, lead to employee resilience, a relatively unexplored but potentially important source of sustained competitive advantage.
Goals. Combining motivation and cognition, goal frames are an important construct for understanding the microfoundations of value creation, a key concept in strategy research. The basic notion is that behavior is influenced by higher-level goals that, when salient, steer an individual’s motivation and cognition. Goal-framing theory proposes different goal frames that are differentially salient to individuals. These goal frames are linked to specific individual behaviors, and also shape firm behaviors in the aggregate (Foss & Lindenberg, Reference Foss and Lindenberg2013; Lindenberg & Foss, Reference Lindenberg and Foss2011).
New research on goal framing may provide more detail on why, how, and when specific goal frames become dominant at the organizational level, fostering collective commitment toward certain choices or actions. Expanding this line of inquiry could involve further exploring the interactions between goal frames and other organizational elements, such as leadership, organizational design, and culture. In particular, in the formation and reinforcement of goal frames that are beneficial to an organization’s performance, the interplay of organizational culture, leadership styles, and broader cultural norms is likely to be crucial. A culture that embodies core values such as justice, equity, and fairness may increase the salience of goal frames conducive to value creation. Leadership styles, particularly those exemplifying servant leadership which focuses on the needs and emotional well-being of employees (cf. Wu et al., Reference Wu, Liden, Liao and Wayne2021) may lead to the same outcome. Yet, there is also a possibility that lower-level employees may adopt and champion beneficial goal frames, independent of direct managerial influence. Here, organizational identification (Section 3) might play a role. Future research should also examine the individual personality traits and attributes that encourage organizational members to support and spread specific goal frames.
Additionally, there has been work on dispositional and situational regulatory focus (Higgins, Reference Higgins1997, Reference Higgins1998) and its impact on interfirm relationships (Weber & Mayer, Reference Weber and Mayer2011), learning (Weber, Reference Weber2017), acquisition decisions (Gamache et al., Reference Gamache, McNamara, Mannor and Johnson2015), and firm stakeholder strategies (Gamache et al., Reference Gamache, Neville, Bundy and Short2020). This research examines how prevention- versus promotion-framed goals impact top management and lower-level managers’ attention, emotions, behaviors, and strategic decisions, which influence firm-level outcomes. Again, this work has only begun to examine the impact of regulatory focus theory on firm performance, creating an opportunity for future research in this area.
Emotions. Despite emotions driving motivation, cognition, and behavior, and acting as a distinct influence in social interaction (Huy, Reference Huy2012; van Knippenberg & van Kleef, Reference Van Knippenberg and Van Kleef2016) that may affect organizational outcomes (Healey & Hodgkinson, Reference Healey and Hodgkinson2017), behavioral strategy research disproportionally focuses on cognition. If emotions are considered, they are typically incorporated as impediments to effective decision-making (cf. Damasio, Reference Damasio1994; Rafaeli & Worline, Reference Rafaeli and Worline2001). However, more recent work showed that emotions may facilitate (interactive) decision-making in some contexts (e.g., Ehrig et al., Reference Ehrig, Manjaly, Singh and Sunder2022; Healey & Hodgkinson, Reference Healey and Hodgkinson2017; Healey et al., 2018; Vuori & Huy, Reference Vuori and Huy2020).
Leadership research shows how leaders’ affective displays – that is, expressions of leader mood or emotion observable to followers – motivate and mobile organizational members through emotional contagion (Elfenbein, Reference Elfenbein2014; Visser et al., Reference Visser, van Knippenberg, Van Kleef and Wisse2013. Besides leaders’ emotions, organizational members’ emotions also play a crucial role in organizational change (Bartunek, Balogun, & Do, Reference Bartunek, Balogun and Do2011). While most of these studies focus on employees’ resistance to change and thus on managing and mitigating such resistance (Ford, Ford, & D’Amelio, Reference Ford, Ford and D’Amelio2008; Kiefer, Reference Kiefer2005; Reger et al., Reference Reger, Mullane and Gustafson1994), recent work provides evidence that more positive emotions (including happiness, enjoyment, and enthusiasm) play a catalytic role in accelerating change (Bartunek et al., Reference Bartunek, Balogun and Do2011; Kiefer, Reference Kiefer2002; Liu & Perrewé, Reference Liu and Perrewé2005).
Imagination. Although behavioral strategy research overlaps with fields like entrepreneurship and innovation, forward-looking, creative, or imaginative thinking tends to lie outside of the main research program (see Gavetti, Reference Gavetti2012 and Winter, Reference Winter2012). The reason arguably is that dominant approaches in behavioral strategy, such as the behavioral theory of the firm (Cyert & March, Reference Cyert and March1963), focus on the role of the past in shaping the future. Thus, the emphasis has been primarily on standard operating procedures, routines, organizational memory, and myopic, local search to explain why past firm behavior is the best predictor of future firm behavior. Another major approach to behavioral strategy, behavioral decision theory, assumes (like standard decision theory) that choice alternatives are essentially given. How actors generate (new) solution spaces under conditions of deficient knowledge and experience has generated less interest (e.g., Feduzi & Runde, Reference Feduzi and Runde2014). This is surprising given that the construction of (new) decision situations is a key aspect of decision-making in March and Simon (Reference March and Simon1958).
The imaginative aspect of strategic decision-making is starting to garner renewed interest (e.g., Alvarez & Porac, Reference Alvarez and Porac2020: 739). However, how decision-makers extract relevant information from the past and use it to predict and evaluate possible futures is not very clear. The emerging theory-based view in behavioral strategy (e.g., Felin & Zenger, Reference Felin and Zenger2017; Rindova & Martins, Reference Rindova and Martins2021) posits that decision-makers form theories much like scientists, which is anticipated in the psychology literature in George Kelly’s “personal construct” theory (Kelly, Reference Kelly1970). The theory-based view characterizes valuable theories as novel, simple, falsifiable, and generalizable (Felin & Zenger, Reference Felin and Zenger2017), but does not offer further insight into how they are generated. The “conviction narrative theory” associated with David Tuckett (e.g., Johnson, Bilovich, & Tuckett, 2023) goes somewhat further. It suggests the psychological foundations of theories are “conviction narratives” that identify beliefs about relevant future variables and the mechanisms that link them. This perspective also shows how such narratives are subject to simulation, affective evaluation, and communication (cf. Rindova & Martins, Reference Rindova and Martins2022). As such, both the theory-based view and conviction narrative theory align with an older “scenario” tradition in strategy (see also Feduzi & Runde, Reference Feduzi and Runde2014), which has made limited contact with behavioral strategy.
Predispositions. The notion of predisposition emphasizes the nonreflective aspect of human agency (Cardinale, Reference Cardinale2018), and refers to the impromptu mobilization of skills in response to evolving situations, which is typically transmitted unconsciously via social practices. Nayak and colleagues further suggest predispositions are microfoundations of firm dynamic capabilities, as they provide a “tacitly honed capacity for improvisatory adaptive action that is unconsciously acquired in situ through extensive immersion in changing environmental conditions” (2020: 282).
The notion of predisposition helps in better understanding how firm constituents perceive and respond to environmental cues, processes that reflect perceptual sensitivities honed through prolonged exposure to both internal organizational dynamics and external environmental factors (Nayak et al., Reference Nayak, Chia and Canales2020). This view also underscores the importance of focusing on interfaces as opportunities for the unconscious transfer and expansion of predispositions. Shedding light on how interfaces facilitate the transfer and adaptation of predispositions can offer profound insights into how firms develop their dynamic capabilities and, thus, sustained competitive advantage.
The Where and When?
Routines. In Section 1, we mentioned a shift in the understanding of organizational routines, moving away from a view of them as static entities to dynamic, evolving processes (e.g., Feldman & Pentland, Reference Feldman and Pentland2003). This evolution underscores the importance of human agency in renewing and adapting routines, challenging earlier notions of routines as mere repetition (Feldman, Reference Feldman, Howard-Grenville, Rerup, Langley and Tsoukas2016; Parmigiani & Howard-Grenville, Reference Parmigiani and Howard-Grenville2011).
While the study of routine dynamics traditionally focused on actions and their associations (Pentland et al., Reference Pentland, Feldman, Becker and Liu2012), actions are inseparable from the agents performing them (D’Adderio & Pollock, Reference D’adderio and Pollock2014). As such, routines and routine dynamics provide fertile ground for behavioral strategy research, as they represent the main locus of interfaces. In this sense, behavioral strategy could both draw from and augment routine dynamics research by delving into routines as points of confluence for multiple agents’ predispositions, cognitions, motivations, and actions (Weick & Roberts, Reference Weick and Roberts1993). Investigating routines as conduits of influence among various agents can clarify the relation between the action networks within routines and the individual actors involved. Furthermore, examining the intrinsic and extrinsic motivational factors, (beyond mere feedback mechanisms) that drive routine (re)production could illuminate when routines are more susceptible to change, which in turn affects organizational performance and adaptability (Abell, Felin, & Foss, Reference Abell, Felin and Foss2008).
Artificial Intelligence. Simon (1995) not only developed the concept of bounded rationality but was also one of the pioneers in AI research in the 1950s. He believed that human behavior should be studied not just with psychology, but also modeled using computers (cf. also Newell & Simon, Reference Simon and Newell1976). Today firms are increasingly using artificial intelligence (AI) – machines that perform cognitive functions typically associated with human minds (Nilsson, Reference Nilsson1971) – across a range of operational and managerial tasks. The integration of AI is ushering in new forms of agency and new interfaces, redefining the boundaries of bounded rationality and transforming firms’ experiential, structural, and relational systems in unprecedented ways (Kemp, Reference Kemp2023; Murray, Rhymer, & Sirmon, Reference Murray, Rhymer and Sirmon2021).
From a cognitive perspective, AI-based algorithms are supercarriers of formal rationality because they can both optimize and improve themselves at an unprecedented speed (Lindebaum, Vesa, & den Hond, Reference Lindebaum, Vesa and Den Hond2020). Delegating decision-making authority to AI can thus reduce firms’ information processing costs resulting from the creation of vertical and horizontal information structures and the incentives to diminish information asymmetries. Moreover, AI has a significantly greater attentional capacity than humans, allowing for the simultaneous pursuit of multiple goals and, thereby, reducing the need to rely on priority rules for attention allocation (von Krogh, Reference Von Krogh2018). On the other hand, AI may exacerbate certain cognitive biases such as myopia (Balasubramanian, Ye, & Xu, Reference Balasubramanian, Ye and Xu2022), and illusory causation (cf. Kiesler & Sproull, Reference Kiesler and Sproull1982). Delegating decision-making authority to AI can also hinder humans’ reliance on perceptual sensitivity for discriminating between environmental stimuli and, thus, their capacity for improvisatory adaptive action (Daugherty & Wilson, Reference Daugherty and Wilson2018).
The evolving role of AI in mediating human interactions within organizations offers a novel area of investigation. AI systems, acting as intermediaries in communication processes, have the potential to significantly influence the flow and interpretation of information. They can also play a crucial role in governing sensemaking and social influence processes. For instance, AI systems can promote high-quality, “heedful” interrelations among firm constituents, fostering a shared understanding and facilitating concerted action (cf. McKee et al., Reference McKee, Tacchetti and Bakker2023; Shirado & Christakis, Reference Shirado and Christakis2020). Additionally, even though AI systems do not possess emotions, their ability to emulate human emotional responses can be instrumental in spreading positive emotions during crisis situations (cf. Han, Yin, & Zang, Reference Han, Yin and Zhang2023; Prinz, Reference Prinz2022). However, there is a risk that AI might lead to increasingly uniform mental representations that suppress the requisite variety needed for adaptive shifts in information processing styles (cf. Steinbach, Gamache, & Johnson, Reference Steinbach, Gamache and Johnson2019), potentially hindering firms’ adaptability and eroding competitive advantage (Kemp, Reference Kemp2023).
Beyond their cognitive influence, AI and related technologies can also serve as motivational drivers. For instance, AI-driven performance monitoring systems can influence employee behavior by providing real-time feedback, thus fostering a more dynamic and responsive work environment (Tong et al., Reference Tong, Jia, Luo and Fang2021). This aspect raises important questions about the potential of AI to facilitate both individual and organizational learning. However, complete delegation to AI systems might lead to reduced employee engagement and participation as well as encourage opportunistic behaviors, as employees could exploit the automated systems for personal gain, potentially at the expense of organizational goals. Such scenarios underscore the importance of maintaining a balance between AI automation and human involvement, ensuring that employees’ accountability is preserved through some level of involvement with and control over relevant tasks (Raisch & Krakowski, Reference Raisch and Krakowski2021).
Network and Connections beyond the Organizational Boundaries. There is increasing recognition of the significant role played by social relationships and interfaces beyond firm boundaries in shaping strategists’ decision-making and actions, and, as a consequence, firm behavior and outcomes (Tasselli et al., Reference Tasselli, Kilduff and Menges2015; Westphal & Zajac, Reference Westphal and Zajac2013). The extensive literature on board interlock ties, where board members concurrently serve on multiple corporate boards, shows that such ties act as conduits for social learning and the diffusion of strategies, practices, and norms between firms (e.g., Haunschild, Reference Haunschild1993; McDonald & Westphal, Reference McDonald and Westphal2003;). Relationships between firm leaders also were found to increase the likelihood of cooperative strategies (Gulati & Westphal, Reference Gulati and Westphal1999).
Furthermore, social networks play a crucial role in shaping individual motivations and emotions (Burkhardt, Reference Burkhardt1994). For instance, individuals who are surrounded by pro-social (self-interested) others are more likely to become pro-social (self-interested) (Christakis & Fowler, Reference Christakis and Fowler2013; Tsvetkova & Macy, Reference Tsvetkova and Macy2015); and individuals who are surrounded by happy others are more likely to become happy (Fowler & Christakis, Reference Fowler and Christakis2008). These networks also contribute to social identity formation, fulfilling fundamental human needs for belonging and serving as a foundation for identification (Walker & Lynn, Reference Walker and Lynn2013).
Recent research also focused on the psychological processes underpinning tie formation and their effective exploitation. Active pursuit or avoidance of certain relationships by individuals (Tasselli et al., Reference Tasselli, Kilduff and Menges2015), and the interplay between network position and motivation, significantly impact both individual and firm-level outcomes (Tasselli et al., Reference Tasselli, Kilduff and Menges2015). For instance, Reinholt, Pedersen, and Foss (Reference Reinholt, Pedersen and Foss2011) found that individuals’ knowledge acquisition and provision were highest when both network centrality and autonomous motivation were high. This indicates that while structural position in a network is crucial, it is motivation that allows for leveraging network positions effectively (cf. Vissa, Reference Vissa2010). Shedding further light on the motivational drivers leading specific firm participants to coalesce may also help to enhance our understanding of whether and how distributed and shared cognition may coexist and interact (Stevenson & Greenberg, Reference Stevenson and Greenberg2000). While we know shared cognitions may not be a necessary condition for coalescence (e.g., Fiol, Reference Fiol1994) (see Section 3), the extent to which mental models need to be shared among participants to allow them to form a coalition has not been examined.
Furthermore, trust, as an output of microlevel interactions within these networks (cf. Emerson, Reference Emerson1976), acts as a resource that can be exchanged to build and modify higher-level structures. Within firms, trust can serve as a complementary or substitute governance mechanism to traditional authority (Adler, Reference Adler2001; Westphal & Zajac, Reference Westphal and Zajac2013). At the same time, it may also undermine authority and reduce monitoring and supervision, particularly when arising from informal ties between superiors and subordinates (e.g., CEO and board members) (Fredrickson, Hambrick, & Baumrin, Reference Fredrickson, Hambrick and Baumrin1988). Overall, by situating interfaces into networks of structural ties beyond firm boundaries, behavioral scholars may gain a better understanding of the origins of strategists’ emotions, motivations, and cognitions and formulate better predictions regarding their subsequent impact on firm behavior and outcomes.
Uncertainty. Much work on behavioral decision theory is predicated on the existence of “uncertainty,” and this is largely true of behavioral strategy. Thus, individuals and firms have to make choices among multiple alternatives with different outcomes (Tversky & Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974; Simon, Reference Simon1955), search “landscapes” they may know little about (Levinthal, Reference Levinthal1997), and construct representations of those landscapes and their decision situations more generally (Levinthal, Reference Levinthal2011). However, it is not always clear what “uncertainty” means in behavioral strategy. One reason is that scholars are often not forthcoming about the kind of uncertainty, or, more broadly, the lack of knowledge assumed. For example, a definition of uncertainty is seldom explicitly mentioned in the search literature derived from the behavioral theory of the firm (e.g., Greve, Reference Greve1998), although models that invoke “novelty” (e.g., Gavetti, Levinthal, & Rivkin, Reference Gavetti, Levinthal and Rivkin2005) seem to implicitly suggest that such search takes place under conditions of partial ignorance about the future as well the present “landscape.”
Indeed, as one surveys the behavioral strategy literature, everything from subjective probability (in Bayesian as well as non-Bayesian forms) to ambiguity to sheer ignorance has been labeled as “uncertainty.” For example, some key contributions to behavioral decision theory (Tversky & Fox, Reference Tversky and Fox1995) explicitly assume or posit conditions of risk. For example, much of the prospect theory literature shows how framing gambles differently (notably, loss versus gain) influences how risks are assessed, impacting choice behavior. Indeed, Gerd Gigerenzer argued that much of the heuristics and biases literature is fundamentally based on standard rational decision-making models, albeit with tweaks and add-ons (e.g., Gigerenzer, et al., Reference Gigerenzer, Hertwig and Pachur2011) Still, many others have used reasoning derived from such models to approach behavior under even radical uncertainty (i.e., decision-makers cannot describe future state spaces) (e.g., Feduzi & Runde, Reference Feduzi and Runde2014; Mousavi & Gigerenzer, Reference Mousavi and Gigerenzer2014).
Perhaps the reason behavioral strategy research has not typically clearly defined uncertainty is that it focuses on behaviors. Thus, it may loosely, but plausibly, assume that ambiguity leads to behaviors that reflect ambiguity, and that uncertainty leads to analogical reasoning in strategy-making (Gavetti et al., Reference Gavetti, Levinthal and Rivkin2005). However, the microfoundations for such assumptions are not always clear. For example, there is much more to know about the psychological mechanisms producing analogies under different circumstances, or the extent to which cognitive bias findings derived in probabilistic settings are transferable to non-probabilistic situations (i.e., identifying decision alternatives and their outcomes is difficult).
These problems in behavioral strategy seem to stem from the lack of a clear understanding of decisions and behaviors under what is often called “Knightian uncertainty.” Of course, behavioral strategy is not alone in lacking a clear understanding of Knightian uncertainty; the problem is a more general one in social science where multiple interpretations of such uncertainty have been proffered (Foss, Reference Foss2023). However, behavioral strategy is championed because it attempts to grapple with real behaviors in realistic decision-making situations in a strategic context. If “Knightian uncertainty” means that our knowledge about the future often, perhaps usually, eludes quantification, it is incumbent upon behavioral strategy scholars to address such uncertainty.
While decision science and economics have developed several models of Knightian uncertainty, many of these are essentially tweaks of the basic Bayesian model of decision-making (Foss, Reference Foss2023). Game theorists are also experimenting with modeling “unawareness” (i.e., there are parts of the state space that decision-makers are initially unaware of). However, none of these approaches make room for the role of imagination, stressed above as an important future research avenue in behavioral strategy. As argued in the section on Imagination (page 63), when the future does not exist, decision-makers exercise their imagination to be able to evaluate the desirability of potential outcomes. Such imagination often emerges as socially embedded narratives that respond to the existence of uncertainty in terms of including sense-making, outlining possible actions, and criteria for evaluating the future (Johnson, Bilovich, & Tuckett, Reference Johnson and Tuckett2023).
The Why and How?
As argued, most research in behavioral strategy is influenced heavily by Simon’s conception of individuals as information processors, emphasizing organizational rules and routines to reduce complexity and treating organizations as unitary entities (e.g., Levinthal, Reference Levinthal1997). This has resulted in a general lack of clarity with respect to the mechanisms that connect microlevel psychological aspects to firm-level behaviors and outcomes (cf. Christensen et al., Reference Christensen, Dahl, Knudsen and Warglien2021). Still, recent work has made significant strides in understanding the aggregation of individual choices and their impact on firm behavior and performance (see Cialdini & Goldstein, Reference Cialdini and Goldstein2004).
Such research largely focuses on intended aggregation mechanisms, explicitly designed to align individual motivations, cognitions, and actions to enhance firm performance and competitive advantage, and including compliance via formal governance structures, social influence via power and communication, and political processes (e.g., Christensen & Knudsen, Reference Christensen and Knudsen2010; Csaszar & Eggers, Reference Csaszar and Eggers2013; Piezunka, Aggarwal, & Posen, Reference Piezunka, Aggarwal and Posen2022). “The basic premise in this line of research is that the organization has a fundamental role in aggregating choice functions, which characterize the organizational members’ ability to pass judgment.” (Christensen et al., Reference Christensen, Dahl, Knudsen and Warglien2021: 2). For instance, some work examines the effectiveness of different governance forms to mitigate the transaction costs ensuing from differences in participants’ mental models as well as participants’ self-interest (e.g., Foss & Weber, Reference Foss and Weber2016) (Section 4). Studies also explore decision structures that promote endogenous adaptation and desired aggregate outcomes (e.g., Piezunka & Schilke, Reference Piezunka and Schilke2023), revealing that decentralized decision structures may engender unintended firm-level consequences and lead to suboptimal firm outcomes, even when individuals are unbiased (Christensen et al., Reference Christensen, Dahl, Knudsen and Warglien2021; Piezunka & Schilke, Reference Piezunka and Schilke2023). Furthermore, certain decision rules, such as averaging participants beliefs, albeit being particularly effective at aggregating individual knowledge into firm decisions, may ultimately be ineffective at fostering individual learning (Piezunka et al., Reference Piezunka, Aggarwal and Posen2022) and participation (Piezunka & Schilke, Reference Piezunka and Schilke2023).
Social norms may also have a role in connecting the micro and macro levels. Individuals often rely on social norms for guidance, especially in ambiguous situations where formal rules are not applicable (Cialdini, Reference Cialdini2001). The influence of norms, ranging from subtly shaping behaviors to driving overt compliance, hinges on two factors: the prominence of these norms in an individual’s consciousness and the alignment between different types of norms (Cialdini, Reference Cialdini2003). Existing studies suggest that norms influence individual behavior when they are the focus of attention (cf. Hargadon, & Bechky, Reference Hargadon and Bechky2006). This happens when individuals are exposed to a certain stimulus for prolonged periods of time (Keizer, Lindenberg, & Steg, Reference Keizer, Lindenberg and Steg2013) and intermittently (Bernstein, Shore, & Lazer, Reference Bernstein, Shore and Lazer2018). For instance, Weber and Murnighan (Reference Weber and Murnighan2008) demonstrate that when a single individual consistently exhibited prosocial behaviors, members came to perceive the norm as cooperative, becoming more willing to contribute themselves. This, however, implies that norms may explain “aggregation” only when they are consciously and prominently considered by individuals (Cialdini & Goldstein, Reference Cialdini and Goldstein2004).
Social psychology literature offers relevant insights into unintended aggregation mechanisms that operate subconsciously, aligning individuals’ motivations, emotions, and behaviors without deliberate design. Mechanisms like social contagion (i.e., the spontaneous distribution of ideas, emotions, attitudes, and behaviors among larger groups of people (Christakis & Fowler, Reference Christakis and Fowler2013)) automatic activation through priming (i.e., information in the environment that makes related mental content accessible in a way that can potentially be used to guide judgment and behavior (Chartrand & Bargh Reference Chartrand and Bargh1999; Chen et al., Reference Chen, Latham, Piccolo and Itzchakov2021; Loersch & Payne, Reference Loersch and Payne2014)), and belief synchronization (i.e., an inherent tendency to select popular alternatives over unpopular ones (Denrell & Le Mens, Reference Denrell and Le Mens2017)) all subtly shape individuals’ decisions and actions in a way that aggregates to organizational-level outcomes. Future research in behavioral strategy could delve into understanding these mechanisms and their interplay, which has often been overlooked. The next step of the behavioral strategy roadmap will consist of linking strategic choices, such as momentum, exploitative and explorative strategies, imitative strategies, and anticipatory strategies (e.g., forbearance) (cf. Greve, Reference Greve2013; Andrevski & Miller, Reference Andrevski and Miller2022), to their performance outcomes and understanding the role played by the aggregation mechanisms as drivers of such relationships.
Method Avenues
Although all empirical strategy research faces the core challenges of construct unobservability, measurement accuracy, and validity, these issues are particularly critical in behavioral strategy, as examining microfoundations of firm-level phenomena requires explicitly addressing these issues. It is imperative for research in behavioral strategy to examine the validity of constructs in foundational theories. A recent paper in the behavioral governance stream noted that asset specificity, the key construct driving holdup in TCE, is often difficult to quantify objectively and tends to be subjectively perceived by involved parties. These perceptions can be biased or even deliberately manipulated, leading to unexpected contractual stipulations that diverge from traditional TCE predictions (Weber & Coff, Reference Weber and Coff2023). This emerging line of inquiry, examining the influence of perceptual factors on core theoretical propositions, underscores the need for a deeper understanding of how subjective interpretations can diminish construct validity.
Additionally, given the microfoundational nature of behavioral strategy research, another significant challenge is precisely defining both the level and unit of analysis in these studies. A recurrent theme has been the pursuit of both accuracy and depth in our understanding, coupled with the essential requirement for methodologies that are both reliable and consistent. We have also mentioned the importance of focusing on interfaces and context, advocating for empirical approaches that capture and account for the complex dynamics of real organizational settings as closely as possible. In the next section, our attention turns towards the potential of methodological and data pluralism. We will illustrate how this pluralism cannot only help address some of the existing challenges but also pave the way for progress in the field of behavioral strategy. We introduce a range of promising methods, followed by suggestions for their effective combination.
Multi-agent Experiments
Behavioral strategy scholars are increasingly adopting experimental methods as primary data-gathering and analysis techniques (Levine et al., Reference Levine, Schilke, Kacperczyk and Zucker2023). Experiments offer multiple advantages, as they (1) are highly complementary to traditional modeling techniques in behavioral strategy (Billinger et al., Reference Billinger, Stieglitz and Schumacher2014); (2) provide evidence of causal relationships (Greenberg & Tomlinson, Reference Greenberg and Tomlinson2004); and (3) explicate materials and instructions, easing replication (Croson, Anand, & Agarwal, Reference Croson, Anand and Agarwal2007). Furthermore, with the growth of online crowdsourcing sites, such as Amazon Mechanical Turk and Prolific, conducting experiments has become more scalable. Many consider online experiments just as valid as lab experiments, even offering advantages such as subject diversity, market-like conditions, and the feasibility of longitudinal studies (Horton, Rand, & Zeckhauser, Reference Horton, Rand and Zeckhauser2011; Paolacci, Chandler, & Ipeirotis, Reference Paolacci, Chandler and Ipeirotis2010; Rand, Reference Rand2012). Yet, most online experiments involve very simple and often noninteractive tasks done independently (Giamattei et al., Reference Giamattei, Yahosseini, Gächter and Molleman2020), raising concerns about the generalizability of findings to real-world settings (Levitt & List, Reference Levitt and List2008).
New platforms allowing for synchronous and longitudinal experiments may address this issue (e.g., Mao et al., Reference Mao, Chen and Gajos2012), particularly when tasks and interactions are designed to enable participants’ socialization, thus mimicking virtual work in actual organizations. Despite some criticism regarding the lack of realism and fidelity, virtual reality also has the potential to augment experimental settings, aligning them more closely with the organizational context under study (Brookes et al., Reference Brookes, Warburton, Alghadier, Mon-Williams and Mushtaq2020; Hubbard & Aguinis, Reference Hubbard and Aguinis2023).
In choosing the experimental approach, behavioral scholars must carefully consider the trade-offs between accuracy and generalizability. This decision is compounded by the need to assess the applicability of findings on bounded rationality in strategic decision-making, particularly outside the controlled confines of laboratory settings (see Jussim, Reference Jussim2012). Field experiments may offer greater generalizability, especially when participant sampling allows for broader extrapolation. On the other hand, complementing online experiments with field-based case studies or subsequent firm-level data can complement the advantages of experiments with the richness of field data, offering realistic insights into the psychological underpinnings of firm competitive advantage.
Conversations, Narratives, and Natural Language Processing
The study of interaction and what we call “interfaces” above in behavioral strategy may also be furthered by conversation analysis, which uses management meeting textual data to analyze the situated processes of decision-making (Cooren, Reference Cooren2013; Cooren et al., Reference Cooren, Vaara, Langley and Tsoukas2014). This methodology hinges on the intertextual relationships between utterances (i.e., who says what, when, and how), in terms of such aspects as topic continuity, argumentative progression, and rhetorical devices, to gain a better understanding of what happens at the interface (e.g., König et al., Reference König, Mammen, Luger, Fehn and Enders2018; Tuggle, Schnatterly, & Johnson, Reference Tuggle, Schnatterly and Johnson2010). For instance, the application of conversation analysis has uncovered multiple discursive tactics that strategists employ to drive decision-making (Wodak et al., Reference Wodak, Kwon and Clarke2011).
Although this method has been largely adopted from a qualitative (ethnographic) perspective, the burgeoning field of computational linguistics – particularly machine learning and deep learning techniques for the analysis of textual data – presents opportunities to extend the scope and enhance the inferential reproducibility of conversation analysis. This expansion into computational techniques allows for scaling up the analysis to include a broader range of textual data beyond management meetings, such as text messages, emails, memos, presentation slides, etc. By incorporating interactions with organizational members at various hierarchical levels, this approach can provide a more comprehensive understanding of interactive processes at all organizational tiers and their cumulative impact on strategic decisions. Moreover, sentiment analysis of these conversations is an essential addition. By evaluating the emotions behind individual utterances, the combination of conversation and sentiment analysis can provide rich insights into firm-level implications of the interplay between participants’ affective states, discursive tactics, and linguistic devices.
Earlier in this section, we pointed to the importance of narratives as key mental representations to imagine plausible futures and, thus, as means for sensemaking and decision-making under radical uncertainty (Chong & Tuckett, Reference Chong and Tuckett2015). Topic modeling is a promising method to augment traditional narrative analysis, treating stories as the main unit of analysis (Riessman, Reference Riessman1993), and aiming at uncovering “semantically cohesive topics and their combination across document collections.” (Evans & Aceves, Reference Evans and Aceves2016: 32). Algorithmically derived topic structures tend to be more transparent, reproducible, and less biased than pure qualitative analyses based on individual researchers’ reading. Nevertheless, the structures generated by topic modeling are not self-explanatory and require careful interpretation. To enhance both reproducibility and interpretability, a promising approach is to present selections of prototypical text from the corpus corresponding to each identified topic, which may allow them to engage directly with the language used by individuals, facilitating a deeper understanding and a form of triangulation (Marchetti & Puranam, Reference Marchetti and Puranam2023). Additionally, integrating sentiment analysis into topic modeling could further refine the understanding of narratives. Sentiment analysis helps detect the emotional underpinnings within the narratives, offering insights into the mood and attitudes of the narrators. This combination can be especially powerful in understanding how strategists’ narratives express more or less positive futures, shape organizational culture, and, in turn, influence decision-making processes.
Finally, algorithmic-aided text analysis is now regularly used in measuring various psychological constructs such as CEO motivation (regulatory focus) (Gamache et al., Reference Gamache, McNamara, Mannor and Johnson2015), temporal focus (Nadkarni & Chen, Reference Nadkarni and Chen2014), justification content (Wade, Porac, & Pollock, Reference Wade, Porac and Pollock1997), and attention (Cho & Hambrick, Reference Cho and Hambrick2006), primarily through the analysis of letters to shareholders in annual reports of publicly traded companies. The advent of sophisticated unsupervised machine learning techniques, including word embeddings and large language models, heralds new possibilities for measuring socio-cognitive constructs with greater reliability and accuracy. Word embeddings, which include methods like bag-of-words models, enable the extraction of semantic patterns from large text corpora, potentially revealing relationships between the cognitive frameworks of different organizational members (cf. Piezunka & Dahlander, Reference Piezunka and Dahlander2015). By quantitatively analyzing word relationships in vector spaces, word embeddings can uncover implicit cognitive maps that guide organizational decision-making and strategy formulation, as well as provide insights into the collective cognitive alignment or divergence within an organization (cf. repertory grid techniques in Hodgkinson, Wright, and Anderson (Reference Hodgkinson, Wright and Anderson2015)). Furthermore, large language models, such as GPT-4, are now capable of generating measures of semantic typicality (i.e., the degree of similarity of a text document to a concept) that closely mirror human judgment, which allows for considerable refinement with respect to measuring concepts like ambiguity, diversity, extremity, and polarization (Le Mens et al., Reference Le Mens, Kovács, Hannan and Pros2023).
Visual Methods and Image Recognition
Nonparticipatory observation has been one of the most widely adopted methods in behavioral and social sciences where systems of categories have been developed to interpret and classify vocal, verbal, and nonverbal aspects of behaviors in social contexts, including static visual characteristics (e.g., race, sex, and facial appearance) and dynamic ones (e.g., gestures, facial expressions, and body language). Research suggests that visual cues significantly influence individual attention allocation, memory encoding, and decision-making processes (Mehta & Zhu, Reference Mehta and Zhu2009; Tsay, Reference Tsay2021; Tversky, Reference Tversky1974), and that affective displays and subsequent emotional contagion were typically more salient through sight than other senses (Jack et al., Reference Jack, Sun, Delis, Garrod and Schyns2016).
Nevertheless, compared to textual data analysis methods, approaches to analyze and interpret visual content are relatively less developed (Bell & Davison, Reference Bell and Davison2013). Traditional visual content analysis relies on manual coding, leading to scalability and reliability issues. The advent of deep learning techniques in image processing and recognition presents opportunities for using visual data in behavioral strategy research. These advanced algorithmic methods offer scalability and reproducibility in analyzing visual content, surpassing the limitations of manual coding. Future studies in behavioral strategy could rely on these techniques to understand the types of visual cues that may provide information to facilitate effective decisions versus those that introduce errors in decision-making, as well as when these effects occur. Also, scholars could combine image and language processing models to investigate the salience of different sensory cues in judgment and decision-making processes under various situational circumstances (e.g., radical uncertainty) and whether primes or formal mechanisms can alter such salience (cf. Tsay, Reference Tsay2021). Another interesting avenue involves exploring how inconsistencies between different verbal and visual cues may influence dynamics at the interfaces. Such discrepancies can provide unique insights into the perceived authenticity and reliability of communicated messages, either facilitating or hindering organizational change. Thus, these methods offer a new approach to examining behavioral strategy questions that address some of the main issues typically faced in these studies.
Cognitive Maps and Geometric Spaces
In the late 1940s, Tolman discovered that animals assign locations to objects of experience in memory creating relationships between them in the form of a spatial maze (Tolman, Reference Tolman1948). Recent advancements show that similar map-like encoding mechanisms apply to nonspatial conceptual relationships, extending to imagination and abstract thinking (Horner et al., Reference Horner, Bisby, Zotow, Bush and Burgess2016; Kaplan, Schuck, & Doeller, Reference Kaplan, Schuck and Doeller2017; Schiller et al., Reference Schiller, Eichenbaum and Buffalo2015). The hippocampal-entorhinal complex plays a key role in the organization of memory and the formation and navigation of such cognitive maps (Stoewer et al., Reference Stoewer, Schilling, Maier and Krauss2023). These recent discoveries underscore the legitimacy and validity of geometric spaces and Euclidean distances to represent individual mental models and relationships between states in both empirical and computational studies in behavioral strategy (Hodgkinson et al., Reference Hodgkinson, Wright and Anderson2015). Intriguingly, this stream of work suggests mental maps are predictive: they represent each state in terms of its successor states (Stachenfeld et al., Reference Stachenfeld, Botvinick and Gershman2017). “Two states that predict similar future states will have similar representations, and two physically adjacent states that predict divergent future states will have dissimilar representations.” (Stachenfeld et al., Reference Stachenfeld, Botvinick and Gershman2017: 1). This raises some crucial questions about how, for instance, decision-makers navigate solution spaces. Indeed, the focus of traditional NK models has been on similarity in terms of spatial proximity, whereby decision-makers progress through solution spaces by making incremental changes to current alternatives, often varying only one dimension at a time (Section 2). The novel perspective provided by contemporary neuroscience suggests a notion of similarity that aligns more closely with the notion of equifinality; with important implications for our traditional understanding of attention allocation and search (cf. Parker & Witteloostuijn, Reference Parker and Witteloostuijn2010).
Conclusion
Behavioral strategy has emerged as an increasingly influential voice in strategic management research as well as in the practice of strategy, with many consulting boutiques including behavioral strategy competencies in their skill sets. However, the field has been hampered by disconnected theorizing and by extremely broad definitions of the field, its explanatory mechanisms, and its scope. The main purpose of this Element is to renew the debate about these issues (beyond Powell et al., Reference Powell, Lovallo and Fox2011) and to anchor behavioral strategy firmly in the bounded rationality microfoundations that gave initial impetus to the emerging field.
Thus, behavioral strategy falls at the intersection of typical strategic phenomena and an expanded set of psychological concepts, moving beyond just cognition to include elements such as intrinsic motivation, goals, and emotions. However, not all work at this intersection is behavioral strategy research, as a second requirement is that the approach is microfoundational. Furthermore, in this pursuit of microfoundations, we push researchers to move beyond psychological influences on just the CEO and top management team to examine psychological concepts in lower-level employees, which may impact their behavior and therefore firm performance.
We further emphasize the need for a better balance between generalizability and accuracy in behavioral strategy research. Central to this endeavor is the integration of social contextualization – encompassing the who, what, where, when, why, and how – into both theorizing and empirical analysis. Such an approach aims to develop theories with greater explanatory power of actual organizational behaviors and outcomes. It also requires a shift from perceiving firms as monolithic, often anthropomorphized, entities to adopting psychology-informed assumptions that emphasize individual motivations, cognitions, emotions, and behaviors and how these are altered via social interaction. This perspective will deepen our understanding of how situated social interactions among both intra- and interorganizational actors function as pivotal aggregation points and conduits between micro and macro levels. As a result, the thoughtful incorporation of psychological theories, constructs, and mechanisms into established strategy theories holds the potential to be theoretically generative, fostering novel predictions. These advancements pave the way for a more distinct characterization of the behavioral strategy subfield, simultaneously opening avenues for future research endeavors.
J.-C. Spender
Kozminski University
J.-C. Spender is a research Professor, Kozminski University. He has been active in the business strategy field since 1971 and is the author or co-author of 7 books and numerous papers. His principal academic interest is in knowledge-based theories of the private sector firm, and managing them.
Advisory Board
Jay Barney, Eccles School of Business, The University of Utah
Stewart Clegg, University of Technology, Sydney
Thomas Durand, Conservatoire National des Arts et Métiers, Paris
CT Foo, Independent Scholar, Singapore
Robert Grant, Bocconi University, Milan
Robin Holt, Copenhagen Business School
Paula Jarzabkowski, Cass School, City University, London
Naga Lakshmi Damaraju, Indian School of Business
Marjorie Lyles, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University
Joseph T. Mahoney, College of Business, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign
Nicolai Foss, Bocconi University, Milan
Andreas Scherer, University of Zurich
Deepak Somaya, College of Business, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign
Eduard van Gelderen, Chief Investment Officer, APG, Amsterdam
About the Series
Business strategy’s reach is vast, and important too since wherever there is business activity there is strategizing. As a field, strategy has a long history from medieval and colonial times to today’s developed and developing economies. This series offers a place for interesting and illuminating research including industry and corporate studies, strategizing in service industries, the arts, the public sector, and the new forms of Internet-based commerce. It also covers today’s expanding gamut of analytic techniques.