Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-29T05:15:19.025Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A defined benefit pension plan model with stochastic salary and heterogeneous discounting

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2022

Ricardo Josa-Fombellida*
Affiliation:
Dpto. de Estadística e Investigación Operativa and IMUVa, Universidad de Valladolid, Valladolid, Spain
Paula López-Casado
Affiliation:
Universidad de Valladolid, Valladolid, Spain
Jorge Navas
Affiliation:
Dpt. de Matemàtica Econòmica, Financera i Actuarial and BEAT, Universitat de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We study the time-consistent investment and contribution policies in a defined benefit stochastic pension fund where the manager discounts the instantaneous utility over a finite planning horizon and the final function at constant but different instantaneous rates of time preference. This difference, which can be motivated for some uncertainties affecting payoffs at the end of the planning horizon, will induce a variable bias between the relative valuation of the final function and the previous payoffs and will lead the manager to show time-inconsistent preferences. Both the benefits and the contribution rate are proportional to the total wage of the workers that we suppose is stochastic. The aim is to maximize a CRRA utility function of the net benefit relative to salary in a bounded horizon and to maximize a CRRA final utility of the fund level relative to the salary. The problem is solved by means of dynamic programming techniques, and main results are illustrated numerically.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of The International Actuarial Association

1. Introduction

In this paper, we consider a defined benefit (DB) pension plan with stochastic salary, correlated with the financial market and proportional to the benefit. The objective of the manager is to maximize a utility function of the net benefit relative to the salary along a finite planning horizon, discounted at a constant rate of time preference, and also to maximize a utility of the fund relative to the salary at the end of the planning horizon, but discounted at a different constant rate. In this setting, known as heterogeneous discounting, the difference in the rates of time preference can be motivated, for instance, because of some uncertainties affecting the payoff or utility at the end of the planning horizon (or, equivalently, from that moment on for an infinite time horizon) but not to the previous ones. This difference in the discount rates generates a changing relative valuation, increasing or decreasing, depending on the discount rates applied to the final utility with respect to instantaneous utility along the planning horizon. For instance, in the former case, when the time horizon faced by the decision maker is long enough, not too much attention is paid to the consequences of her or his current actions on the final fund wealth, but an increasing concern arises as she approaches the end of it, affecting non only quantitatively optimal decisions in absence of this temporal bias.

Since the work of Haberman and Sung (Reference Haberman and Sung1994), and later of Cairns (Reference Cairns2000), the study of optimal policies in pension plan models from the perspective of dynamic programming has become increasingly important. In these papers, two different types of pension plans have been considered, DB and defined contribution (DC) pension plans. In a DB pension plan, the benefit, which is generally based on the salary of the employee, is fixed in advance and the manager of the plan seeks to ensure that benefit by the end of the plan by using two instruments: the contributions and the investment of the fund assets in the financial market. Because of this, a DB plan is more attractive for the employees, since the risk is entirely assumed by the manager. However, a DC pension plan is funded primarily by the employee, with the employer matching contributions to a certain amount. Here, the employee must adapt her contributions to the dynamics of the fund in order to obtain an adequate wealth for retirement, thus assuming the risk. In DC pension plans, the benefit depends entirely on the performance of the plan in the financial market.

The study of DB pension plans is relevant since they continue to be important in the OCDE countries. Their pension systems are of DB type, see Table 2 in Urbano et al. (Reference Urbano, Jurado and Rosado-Cebrián2021). These plans are advantageous for workers, because they do not take the risk, and therefore are an incentive to take advantage of them. On the other hand, with respect to the size of the pension plan, according to the Thinking Ahead Institute, in 2020, DB funds account for 63.4% of the total assets under management of the world’s largest pension funds, as shown in Hodgson et al. (Reference Hodgson, Hall, Urwin, Gao and Khanna2021).

Other previous works on pension funding, optimal portfolio and stochastic dynamic programming are Battochio and Menoncin (Reference Battocchio and Menoncin2004), Battochio et al. (2007), Cairns et al. (Reference Cairns, Blake and Dowd2006), Chang et al. (Reference Chang, Tzeng and Miao2003), Chen and Hao (Reference Chen and Hao2013), Chen and Delong (Reference Chen and Delong2015), Delong et al. (Reference Delong, Gerrard and Haberman2008), Devolder et al. (Reference Devolder, Bosch and Domínguez2003), Gao (Reference Gao2009), Gerrard et al. (Reference Gerrard, Haberman and Vigna2006), Josa-Fombellida et al. (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2018), Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero2004, Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2008a, Reference Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero2008b, Reference Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero2019) and Le Cortois and Menoncin (Reference Le Cortois and Menoncin2015). Some of them have included the salary as an exogenous element of the mathematical model. For instance, in Battochio and Menoncin (Reference Battocchio and Menoncin2004), the authors consider a DC stochastic pension fund model in continuous time where the manager maximizes the expected exponential utility of her terminal wealth in a complete financial market with stochastic interest rate, and where contributions are proportional to the labor income, which is given by a geometric Brownian motion (henceforth GBM) process. Also, in Cairns et al. (Reference Cairns, Blake and Dowd2006), the authors study a DC pension plan model with a stochastic rate of interest that incorporates the salary as a GBM, and the aim of the manager is to maximize a terminal expected isoelastic utility of the fund relative to salary.

With relation to the study of biases in the decision processes leading to decisions not totally rational from an axiomatic point of view, behavioral finance studies have been receiving increasing attention in the last years. While initially the focus of attention was put on individual decision biases, there is an increasing evidence that more sophisticated or institutional investors can also be affected by some of these biases. For instance, Ahmad et al. (Reference Ahmad, Ibrahim and Tuyon2017) review the theory and empirical evidence of institutional investor behavioral, and Weiss-Cohen et al. (Reference Weiss-Cohen, Ayton, Clacher and Thoma2019) and the report by Ayton et al. (Reference Ayton, Clacher, Strong, Thoma and Weiss-Cohen2021) study behavioral biases in pension fund trustees’ decisions.

In the particular case of intertemporal decisions, recent years have witnessed an increasing interest in the study of deviations from standard discounting, supported by empirical evidence on intertemporal choice decisions (see, e.g., Frederick et al., Reference Frederick, Loewenstein and O’Donoghue2002 for a survey). Within this research line, we find generalizations of the Standard Discounted Utility Model introduced by Paul Samuelson, both in discrete and continuous time, which aims to explain observed biases in the decisions over time. A common feature of some of these extensions is that time preferences become time-inconsistent, as they will depend on the instant of time the decision maker is, and consequently standard optimization techniques fail to characterize time-consistent solutions.

At a theoretical level, even in the case that members of a decision group are assumed to be individually fully rational, collective behavior can show some decision biases, for instance derived from some heterogeneities in the individual preferences, or in the payoffs or utilities considered. In the first case, it is well known that to aggregate temporal decisions for agents with different rates of time preference lead to time-inconsistent joint temporal preferences (Jackson and Yariv, Reference Jackson and Yariv2015) in the form of non-constant discounting. In the second case, a similar situation arises, now in the form of heterogeneous discounting introduced at Marín-Solano and Patxot (Reference Marín-Solano and Patxot2012). Here, one agent (or one group of symmetric agents, as it can be the board of trustees responsible for the management of a pension plan) has to decide between goods or payments over which the decision maker applies different rates of time preference. Time inconsistency arises because of the difference in the discount rates applied to payoffs at different instants of time and not because of aggregating different individual time preferences as in Jackson and Yariv (Reference Jackson and Yariv2015). This second case is the one that we study and motivates this work.

In the continuous time case and non-constant discounting, Karp (Reference Karp2007) characterized time-consistent solutions in a deterministic setting, while Ekeland and Pirvu (Reference Ekeland and Pirvu2008) and Marín-Solano and Navas (2010) faced the stochastic case. By applying time-consistent strategies, we will guarantee that the decision maker will have no incentives to deviate from them at any point over the time horizon. Non-constant discounting captures the effect of a higher impatience for short-term decisions compared with similar long-term choices, presenting a constant bias to the short run. Josa-Fombellida and Navas (Reference Josa-Fombellida and Navas2020) considered the non-constant discount in a DB pension fund model where the aim of the manager is the minimization of the contribution and solvency risks in a infinite horizon.

As mentioned before, Marín-Solano and Patxot (Reference Marín-Solano and Patxot2012) introduced and studied the heterogeneous discounting in a deterministic setting. Here, instantaneous payoffs or utilities and the final function are discounted at different rates of time preference (the discount factor being a standard exponential). Consider, for instance, a pension fund manager placed at time 0, individual or collective, who faces an infinite time horizon. Payoffs between 0 and a given finite time T are discounted at a rate of $\rho_1$ , while payoffs from T on are discounted at a different rate $\rho_2$ . This can be motivated for instance because of the existence of some uncertainty affecting this second stream (e.g., a change in regulation, a transition to a DC plan, etc.), and this uncertainty is internalized by the fund manager at 0 as an increase of the initial discount rate, representing a higher impatience with respect to these payoffs. In our case, we will represent this second stream in the form of a final function but the reasoning applies similarly. This heterogeneity in the discount rates induces a bias by which, as the decision maker moves along the time horizon, the initial gap between the valuation of the instantaneous payoffs along [0, T) and the final function decreases, and consequently, the relative valuation of this final function increases as long as $\rho_2>\rho_1$ . When $\rho_1>\rho_2,$ the effect is the opposite. For instance, this setting has been applied to the study of an individual consumption-investment problem in de-Paz et al. (Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano and Navas2013) and later extended with a life insurance in de-Paz et al. (Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano, Navas and Roch2014), where the effect of the increasing concern for the final function captured the agent’s increasing concern for wealth as she approached her retirement date or for the bequest left to her descendants when approaching the end of life. Finally, a different setting with time-inconsistent preferences has been analyzed in Zou et al. (Reference Zou, Chen and Wedge2014), where the authors study a finite horizon consumption-portfolio model with stochastic hyperbolic discounting.

In this paper, we consider an heterogeneous discounting model where the manager can invest the fund in a portfolio with several risky assets and one riskless asset, as in Merton (Reference Merton1971). The pension model is based in Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2008a), where a DB stochastic pension plan with stochastic salaries for several groups of workers is considered. Later, Chen and Hao (Reference Chen and Hao2013), also based on this first paper, under homogeneous discounting, study a DB stochastic pension plan with stochastic salary for only one group of workers, but with regime economic switching modeled by a Markov chain process. Note that other papers, such as Josa-Fombellida et al. (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2018) and Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero2019), also analyze pension plan models where utility functions of the fund or of the benefit are maximized, which is very interesting for the workers in both cases.

The main novelty of our model with respect to previous literature on pension plans is the generalization of the temporal preferences of the decision maker, now in the form of heterogeneous discounting. To our knowledge, in the literature of pension funding, heterogeneous discounting has not appeared yet. As mentioned above, this introduces a bias in the temporal decisions that leads to time-inconsistent temporal preferences. In this case, the characterization of time-consistent solutions requires to solve a modified HJB equation that, in general, increases the difficulty of the resolution compared with the standard discounting case. With regard to other models with time-inconsistent temporal preferences, as for instance de-Paz et al. (Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano and Navas2013), while we share the basic structure of the Merton model, we introduce an additional state variable, the salary. This allows us to adapt the model to the study of a DB pension plan where the fund manager has as objective to maximize a utility of the liquid benefit relative to salary over a planning horizon together with the relative value of the fund at the end.

As a result of the research, we obtain that the time-consistent net benefit and investment strategies are proportional to the fund wealth and depend on the heterogeneous form of the preferences, instantaneous and final. Moreover, under an exponential specification of the salary process, the investment strategy does not depend on the rates of time preference while the fund is an extended GBM where the drift coefficient depends on time and on the time preference rates. Moreover, an increasing concern when the end of the planning horizon approaches will be reflected in a higher contribution intensity, since this is the only way the fund manager can increase the value of terminal fund wealth. However, this remaining time will be not enough to compensate the initial lower contributions, and consequently, the terminal fund will decrease compared with the case of homogeneous discounting.

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we define the elements of the pension scheme, describe the financial market where the fund operates and establish the management problem of the pension plan. The problem is formulated as a stochastic control problem with heterogeneous discounting, where the fund is invested in a portfolio with several risky assets and one riskless asset, and the exogenous salary is stochastic. The objective is to maximize, on a finite horizon, a utility function of the net benefit and maximize a final utility of the fund assets. In Section 3, the time-consistent strategies are obtained, from the corresponding dynamic programming equations to the heterogeneous discounting setting. We study some properties of the time-consistent contributions and investments. Section 4 analyzes the problem for an exponential specification of the salary process. Section 5 includes a numerical illustration of the dynamics of the time-consistent strategies and the fund evolution of the pension plan, as well as a sensibility analysis with respect to the discount rate applied to the terminal utility, the risk aversion and two economic regimes of the financial market. Finally, Section 6 establishes some conclusions.

2. The pension model

We consider a DB pension plan of aggregated type with continuous entrance and retirement of members in such a way that the pension population remains stable at every time. Active participants coexist with retired participants at every time. It is supposed that every participant enters the plan at the same age l and retires at age l , that is, she remains $l'-l$ years. Since this takes place along time, we need to consider both the time elapsed since the plan started and the age of the participants. The benefits promised to the workers at the age of retirement are established in advance by the manager and are directly related with the salary. At each instant of time t, the benefits of the departing members, with age l , and the contributions of the members, with age between l and l , are accumulated, because the plan is aggregated. The pension fund has a finite planning horizon T. This final time can be thought of as the time at which some additional, and known in advance, uncertainty will affect the plan as for instance the transition to a new plan. This fact is interiorized by the fund manager by discounting the utility from the fund wealth at T at higher rate of time preference than the applied to instantaneous utilities obtained along the time horizon. Workers not retired at this final date receive compensation from the surplus obtained in the process of management of the fund assets.

The principal elements intervening in the funding process and the essential hypotheses allowing its temporary evolution to be determined are as follows. The value of fund assets at time t is denoted by F(t). The benefit promised to the participants at time t is B(t) and is a percentage of the total salary of the workers at the moment t. C(t) is the contribution rate made by the sponsor at time t to the funding process. The total salary of the plan members at time t is denoted by s(t) and is a stochastic process correlated with the financial market. u(t) is the percentage of salary contributed to plan at time t. To avoid confusion of u(t) with the contribution rates, we will refer to C(t) as simply contributions. The constant discount rate associated with the instantaneous utility is $\rho_1,$ and the constant discount rate associated with the final utility is $\rho_2$ .

In order to ensure the standard of living of the participants, the manager of the pension plan assumes that benefit and rate of contribution are related with salary. We suppose that the benefit and the contribution are proportional to the total salary,

(2.1) \begin{align} B(t)=&\,k s(t), \end{align}
(2.2) \begin{align}C(t)= &\,u(t) s(t) ,\end{align}

where the constant k is positive and $k\geq u(t)$ for every $t\in[0,T]$ .

The difference between benefit and contribution is the net benefit. From (2.1) and (2.2), it can be obtained as

(2.3) \begin{equation} B(t)-C(t)= (k-u(t))s(t).\end{equation}

Note that the explicit appearance of the salary constitutes a novelty compared with the model in Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero2004), which studies a dynamic mathematical model for a stochastic DB pension plan. While the relationship between the actuarial functions is maintained, now a spread method of amortization is not longer used. See Remark 5.2 in Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2008a).

2.1. The financial market, the salary process and the fund wealth

In this section, we describe the financial market where the fund operates and the salary process. The randomness involved in the financial market is given by the standard Brownian motion n-dimensional, $z=(z_{1},\ldots,z_{n})^{\top}$ , where ${}^{\top}$ denotes transposition. We assume the total salary is a stochastic process built from the d-dimensional Brownian motion $w=\left(w_{1},\ldots,w_{d}\right)^{\top}$ and influenced by the financial market. We consider the complete probability space $(\Omega,\mathcal{F},\mathrm{P})$ , generated by z ad w, that is to say, $\mathcal{F}$ is the filtration containing the information available to the sponsor plan, $\left\{ \mathcal{F}_{t}\right\}_{t\in[0,T]},$ with $\mathcal{F}_{t}=\sigma\! \left\{(z(\nu) ,w(\nu));\,0\leq \nu\leq t\right\}.$

The financial market consists of a portfolio with n risky assets $\left\{ P^{i}\right\} _{i=1}^{n}$ , which are correlated GBMs generated by z, and a riskless asset $P^{0}$ , whose evolution, as proposed in Merton (Reference Merton1971), is given by

(2.4) \begin{align}dP^{0}(t) &=rP^{0}(t)dt,\quad \text{with }r>0, \qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\quad\end{align}
(2.5) \begin{align}dP^{i}(t) &=P^{i}(t)\left( \mu_{i}dt+\sum_{j=1}^{n}\sigma_{ij}dz_{j}(t)\right), \quad \text{with }\mu_{i}>0,\quad i=1,2,...,n, \end{align}

where $r>0$ is the risk-free rate of interest, $\mu_i$ the mean rate of return of the risky asset $P^i$ , and $\sigma_{ij}$ its volatility or uncertainty parameters. We assume that $\mu_{i}>r$ for all i, so the manager has incentives to invest with risk. The amount of fund invested at time t in the risky asset $P^{i}$ is denoted by $\lambda_{i}(t)$ , $i= 1,2,\ldots,n$ . The remainder, $F(t)-\sum_{i=1}^{n}\lambda_{i}(t)$ , is invested in the bond. Borrowing and short selling is allowed. A negative value of $\lambda_{i}$ means that the sponsor sells a part of his risky asset $S^{i}$ short while, if $\sum_{i=1}^{n}\lambda_{i}$ is larger than F, he or she then gets into debt to purchase the stocks, borrowing at rate of interest r.

We suppose $\{\boldsymbol{\Lambda}(t)\,:\, t\geq0\}$ , with $\boldsymbol{\Lambda}(t) = (\lambda_{1}(t), \lambda_{2}(t),\ldots,\lambda_{n}(t))^{\top}$ , is a control process adapted to the filtration $\{\mathcal{F}_{t}\}_{t\ge 0}$ , $\mathcal{F}_{t}$ -measurable, Markovian and stationary, satisfying

(2.6) \begin{equation} \int_{0}^{T}\boldsymbol{\Lambda}(t)^{\top}\boldsymbol{\Lambda}(t)dt<\infty,\,\, \mathrm{P}\text{-a.s.,}\end{equation}

and the contribution relative to salary, u, is a non-negative measurable adapted process with respect to $\left\{\mathcal{F}_{t}\right\}$ satisfying

(2.7) \begin{equation} \int_0^T u(t) s(t) dt <\infty,\,\, \mathrm{P}\text{-a.s.}\end{equation}

The salary process is given by the general stochastic differential equation (SDE)

(2.8) \begin{equation} d s(t)=\eta(s(t)) dt +\sum_{j=1}^n \beta_{j}(s(t)) dz_j(t)+\sum_{j=n+1}^{n+d} \beta_{j}(s(t)) d w_{j-n}(t),\end{equation}

with initial conditions $s(0)= s_0>0$ , and where $\eta(s)$ is the mean rate of growth of the salary s, and $\beta(s)$ its volatility. We assume $s>0$ a.s. This is satisfied if the salary is a GBM as in Section 4. Note that Brownian motion z also appears in expression (2.8) because the salary is correlated with the financial market.

The manager uses the contribution to increase the fund wealth. The fund not devoted to the net benefit is invested in the financial market. Therefore, the fund’s dynamic evolution under the investment policy $\boldsymbol{\Lambda}$ is:

(2.9) \begin{equation} dF(t)=\sum_{i=1}^{n}\lambda_i(t)\frac{dP^{i}(t)}{P^{i}(t)} + \left(F(t)-\sum_{i=1}^{n}\lambda _{i}(t)\right) \frac{dP^0(t)}{P^0(t)} +(C(t)-B(t))\, dt,\end{equation}

with the initial condition $\,F(0)=F_0>0$ . By substituting (2.3), (2.4) and (2.5) in (2.9), we obtain:

(2.10) \begin{equation}dF(t) = \left( rF(t)+\sum_{i=1}^{n}\lambda_i(t)(\mu-r)+ (u(t)-k)s(t)\right) dt + \sum_{i=1}^{n}\sum_{j=1}^{n}\lambda_i(t) \sigma_{ij}\,dz_{j}(t),\end{equation}

that, with the initial condition and (2.8), determines the fund evolution. We assume the notation: $\boldsymbol{\mu}=(\mu_{1},\mu_{2},\ldots,\mu_{n})^{\top}$ , $\textbf{1} =(1,1,\ldots,1)^{\top}$ , $\sigma=(\sigma_{ij})$ and $\Sigma=\sigma\sigma^{\top}$ . We suppose the existence of $\Sigma^{-1}$ , that is, the existence of $\sigma^{-1}$ . The market price of risk is denoted by $\boldsymbol{\theta}=\sigma^{-1}\!\left(\boldsymbol{\mu}-r\textbf{1}\right).$ Finally, in matrix notation, the diffusion term of the salary process is $\beta(s)=(\beta^{z}(s)\,|\, \beta^{w} (s))$ , with $\beta^{z}(s)=(\beta_{j})_{j=1,\ldots,n}$ and $\beta^{w}(s)=(\beta_{j})_{j=n+1,\ldots,n+d}$ row vectors.

The fund and the salary processes, (2.10) and (2.8), in vectorial notation are

(2.11) \begin{align} dF(t)= \left(rF(t)+\boldsymbol{\Lambda}^{\top}(t)(\boldsymbol{\mu}-r\textbf{1})+(u-k) s(t)\right)dt +\boldsymbol{\Lambda}^{\top}(t)\sigma dz(t),\end{align}
(2.12) \begin{align} d s(t)=& \eta(s(t)) dt + \beta^{z}(s(t)) dz(t) +\beta^{w}(s(t)) dw(t), \end{align}

with initial condition $(F_0, s_0)$ .

2.2. The optimization problem

In the following, we will consider the new control variable $v(t)=(k-u(t)) s(t)$ , which is the liquid or net benefit for the participants at time t. The plan manager wishes to minimize the contributions or equivalently the relative contribution payments u, in [0, T]. Following the idea of Berkelaar and Kouwenberg (Reference Berkelaar and Kouwenberg2003) for a retirement-saving model for a single individual, and later Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2008a) and Chen and Hao (Reference Chen and Hao2013) for a pension plan manager, we suppose that higher contributions payments decrease the utility of the manager and increase the marginal utility of reduction in payments. Thus, it is minimizing the possibility that an increase in the contribution rates will probably lead to the plan manager to pay the workers higher salaries in order to hire them originally or to keep them. On the other hand, the pension plan is more attractive for the workers by the aim of minimize contributions.

We suppose that higher contribution payments decrease the utility of the manager and increase the marginal utility of reduction in payments. Hence, the running utility function, $U(v/s)$ , is increasing and concave with respect to the liquid benefit relative to salary, $v/s=k-u;$ thus, a higher relative contribution implies lower utility. Additionally, the sponsor’s goal is to maximize the same increasing and concave utility function, U, of the final level at fund assets relative to the salary s, $U(F/s)$ . The CRRA (constant relative risk averse) utility functions, namely the logarithmic and power functions and the exponential CARA (constant absolute risk averse) utility function, are suitable for the purposes of the manager and allow explicit solutions. Power and logarithmic utility functions make that $B-C=(k-u)s>0;$ therefore, the risk is transferred to the evolution of the fund. Thus, the model is established for not shifting the risk to the employees but the fund evolution could be with moderate or bearish growth, depending on the financial market, and as a consequence, the manager may have an unsatisfactory low level of the fund on the end date of the plan.

Given initial values of time, $t_0$ , fund assets, $F_0$ , and salary, $s_0$ , we denote by ${\mathcal{A}}_{t_0,F_0,s_0}$ the class of admissible controls, that is to say, the set of measurable processes $(u,\boldsymbol{\Lambda})$ satisfying (2.6) and (2.7), and where F and s satisfy (2.11) and (2.12), respectively. The objective functional to be maximized over the class of admissible controls, ${\mathcal{A}}_{t_0,F_0,s_0}$ , is given by

(2.13) \begin{align} J((t_0,F_0,s_0);\, (v,\boldsymbol{\Lambda}))= \mathbb{E}_{t_0,F_0,s_0}\left\{\int_{t_0}^{T } e^{-\rho_1(t-t_0)}\,U\left(\frac{v(t)}{s(t)}\right)\,dt+ e^{-\rho_2(T-t_0)} \alpha U\left(\frac{F(T)}{s(T)}\right)\right\},\end{align}

where $\mathbb{E}_{t_0,F_0,s_0}$ denotes conditional expectation with respect to the initial conditions $(t_0, F_0,s_0)$ , and $\alpha>0$ is a weighting factor indicating the importance of maximizing the final utility. The imposed admissibility conditions, (2.6) and (2.7), guarantee that the system of SDEs defining the fund, (2.11) and (2.12), has a unique solution for each initial value of the fund and of the salary.

By the so-called heterogeneous discounting, in expression (2.13), the manager discounts differently the instantaneous utility over the planning horizon and the final utility captured by the final function. Under the assumption that $\rho_2>\rho_1$ , two effects arise from this setting. The first is that now the manager’s time preferences become time-inconsistent, in the sense that they will be different at different instants of time along the planning horizon $[t_0,T]$ . Because of this, standard dynamic optimization techniques fail to characterize time-consistent solutions, and it is necessary to adapt the usual dynamic programming equation in the search of time-consistent solutions (see, e.g., Marín-Solano and Patxot, Reference Marín-Solano and Patxot2012 for the deterministic problem, or de-Paz et al., Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano and Navas2013 for the stochastic case). In this context, with the term “time-consistent” we refer to the usual meaning in the sense that, for a given planning horizon $[t_0,T]$ , if at any time $t'>t$ , $t'\in (t,T]$ , the decision maker decides to reoptimize and solves the truncated problem from t until the end of the planning horizon T, taking as initial conditions for the state variables their values at t resulting from strategies applied over [t, t ], the new solution will coincide with the one initially computed at time t for [t , T]. Because of this, the decision maker will have no incentives to deviate from the original strategies. In fact, what we are obtaining is the Markov Perfect equilibrium (MPE) between the current manager, the manager with time preferences at moment t or t-agent, and her future selves, the t -agents, with $t'\in (t,T]$ for any $t\in [t_0,T]$ (see, e.g., Karp, Reference Karp2007), who decide optimally for an infinitesimal amount of time. In this sense, when alluding to the obtained controls, from a formal point of view they should just be named time-consistent strategies, as there is not a unique decision maker for whom the solution is optimal but an infinite number of them, one for any instant of time, that is, we characterize the MPE for the constrained (sequential game) problem between the t-agent and her future selves.

The other effect, which is specific to the heterogeneous discounting model and a consequence of the assumption that $\rho_2>\rho_1$ , is that the relative valuation of the final function increases as we approach the end of the planning horizon. This can be easily seen by rewriting the final function at (2.13) as

\begin{equation*}e^{-\rho_1 (T-t)} e^{-(\rho_2-\rho_1)(T-t)} U(F(T)/s(T))\end{equation*}

for $t\in[t_0,T]$ . Note that now, the problem can be interpreted as a problem with standard discounting (at rate $\rho_1$ ), but with a modified final function equal to $e^{-(\rho_2-\rho_1)(T-t)}U(F(T)/s(T))$ . It is clear that, abstracting from the standard discount at rate $\rho_1$ , an t -agent will give a higher valuation to an additional utility unit than the one given by a t-agent, as long as $t'>t$ . Moreover, this valuation is increasing the closer to T the t -agent is (note that under the assumption of $\rho_2<\rho_1$ the effect would be the contrary).

The dynamic programming approach is used to solve the problem. The value function is defined as

\begin{equation*}\widehat{V}(t,F,s) =\max_{(v,\boldsymbol{\Lambda})\in {\mathcal{A}}_{t,F,s}}\big\{ J((t,F,s);\,(v,\boldsymbol{\Lambda})) \,|\, \mbox{ s.t. }(2.11),(2.12)\big\}.\end{equation*}

The connection between value functions and time-consistent feedback strategies in stochastic control theory with heterogeneous discount is accomplished by a modified Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation; see Corollary 1 in de-Paz et al. (Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano and Navas2013) and Proposition 1 in de-Paz et al. (Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano, Navas and Roch2014). The value function $\widehat{V}$ satisfies the modified HJB equation

(2.14) \begin{align}-\rho_2 V & +K+V_t+ \max_{v,\boldsymbol{\Lambda}}\!\left\{U\left(\frac{v}{s}\right)+ \left(rF +\boldsymbol{\Lambda}^{\top}(\boldsymbol{\mu}- r\textbf{1})-v\right) V_{F}+\eta V_s\right.\nonumber\\[5pt]& \left.+ \frac{1}{2} \boldsymbol{\Lambda}^{\top}\Sigma\boldsymbol{\Lambda}V_{FF}+ \boldsymbol{\Lambda}^{\top} \sigma(\beta^z)^{\top} V_{Fs}+\frac{1}{2} \mathop{\rm tr}\nolimits\left\{\beta\beta^{\top}V_{ss}\right\} \right\}=0, \end{align}

where K(t, F, s) solves the auxiliary PDE

(2.15) \begin{align}\nonumber-\rho_1 K+K_t\,+\, &(\rho_2-\rho_1)U\left(\frac{\widehat{v}}{s}\right)+ \left(rF+\widehat{\boldsymbol{\Lambda}}^{\top}(\boldsymbol{\mu}- r\textbf{1})-\widehat{v}\right) K_{F}+\eta K_s\\[5pt]&\quad + \frac{1}{2} \widehat{\boldsymbol{\Lambda}}^{\top}\Sigma\widehat{\boldsymbol{\Lambda}} K_{FF}+ \widehat{\boldsymbol{\Lambda}}^{\top}\sigma (\beta^z)^{\top} K_{Fs}+\frac{1}{2} \mathop{\rm tr}\nolimits\left\{\beta\beta^{\top}K_{ss}\right\}=0, \end{align}

where $\widehat{v},\widehat{\boldsymbol{\Lambda}}$ are the arguments maximizing in (2.14). The final conditions are $V(T,F,s)=\alpha U(F/s)$ and $K(T,F,s)=0$ , for all F, s.

Remark 2.1. The model considers that the benefits and the contributions are indexed by the salary process. Thus, we assume the modeling approach in Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2008a), but only considering one group of workers, in order to facilitate the development. An alternative model could be considered, as further research, without taking into account the salary, but considering a specification for the benefit as a geometric Brownian motion, as in Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero2004). Then, other actuarial elements, such as the actuarial liability AL, could be included in the model. The heterogeneous discount would appear in the objective functional as follows

\begin{align*}& J((t_0,F_0,AL_0);\, (v,\boldsymbol{\Lambda}))= \mathbb{E}_{t_0,F_0,\mbox{{A L}}_0}\left\{\int_{t_0}^{T} e^{-\rho_1(t-t_0)}\,U\!\left(B(t)-C(t)\right)\,dt+ e^{-\rho_2(T-t_0)}\alpha U\left(F(T)\right)\right\}.\end{align*}

3. The time-consistent strategies

In this section, we analyze how the manager may select the time-consistent relative contribution rate and the investment strategies of the fund put into the risky assets, as well as some properties of these policies.

Though explicit solutions could be obtained with several utility functions such as the exponential CARA utility function, we consider a power CRRA utility function as in Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2008a) and in Josa-Fombellida et al. (Reference Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero2018).

Assumption A. The utility function is given by $ U(x)= \dfrac{x^{1-\gamma}}{1-\gamma}$ , where $\gamma>0$ and $\gamma\neq 1$ .

When $\gamma=1,$ we consider the logarithmic utility, $U(x)=\ln x$ . The parameter $\gamma$ is the risk aversion. The manager has high-risk aversion for $\gamma>1$ , moderate for $\gamma=1$ and low for $\gamma<1$ .

We have the following result:

Theorem 3.1. Suppose that Assumption A holds. Then, the time-consistent relative contribution rate and the investments in the risky assets are given by

(3.1) \begin{align} u(t,F,s)&= k - s^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}} {g^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t,s)} F,\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad \end{align}
(3.2) \begin{align} \Lambda(t,F,s)&= \frac{1}{\gamma}\left ( \Sigma^{-1} (\boldsymbol{\mu}-r \textbf{1})+\frac{g_{s}(t,s)}{g(t,s)} \sigma^{-\top} (\beta^{z}(s))^{\top}\right)\! F \end{align}

respectively, where $g\,:\,[0,T] \times \mathbb{R}^n \longrightarrow \mathbb{R}$ is a positive solution of the non-linear system of PDEs (partial differential equations)

(3.3) \begin{align}g_t(t,s) & + h(t,s) + \left(-\rho_2 + r(1-\gamma) -\frac{1}{2}\left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right)\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} \boldsymbol{\theta} \right ) g(t,s)\nonumber\\[5pt] & + \left(-\left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right)\beta^z(s)\boldsymbol{\theta} +\eta(s)\right) g_s(t,s)+\gamma s^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}} {g^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t,s)}\\[5pt] & -\frac{1}{2}\left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right)\frac{{g_s^2(t,s)}}{g(t,s)} \beta^{z}(s)(\beta^{z}(s))^{\top}+\frac{1}{2} \mathop{\rm tr}\nolimits\! \left\{ \beta(s)\beta(s)^{\top}\right\} g_{ss}(t,s)=0, g(T,s) = \alpha s^{-(1-\gamma)},\nonumber \end{align}
(3.4) \begin{align} h_t(t,s) &\, +\left( -\rho_1 +r(1-\gamma) -\frac12 \left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right) \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top}\boldsymbol{\theta}\right.\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad \qquad \nonumber\\[5pt]& \left. +\frac{1}{2} \left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right)\beta^z(s) \beta^z(s)^{\top}{\frac{g_s^2(t,s)}{g^2(t,s)}} - (1-\gamma)s^{1-\frac1\gamma}{g^{-\frac1\gamma}(t,s)} \right) h(t,s)\nonumber\\[5pt] & \,+(\rho_2-\rho_1) s^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}{g^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t,s)}+ \left(\eta(s)-\left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right)\beta^{z}(s)\boldsymbol{\theta}\right.\nonumber\\[5pt]& \left. -\left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right)\beta^z(s)\beta^z(s)^{\top} \frac{g_s(t,s)}{g(t,s)} \right) h_s(t,s) +\frac{1}{2} \mathop{\rm tr}\nolimits \left\{ \beta(s) \beta(s)^{\top}\right\} h_{ss}(t,s)=0,\nonumber\\[5pt]h(T,s) & = 0,\quad \forall (t,s).\end{align}

Proof. For the problem of Section 2.2, the modified HJB equation is given by the system (2.14), (2.15), but with U given by the Assumption A .

If there is a smooth solution V of the Equation (2.14), strictly concave, then the maximizers values of the liquid benefit and the investment rates are given by

(3.5) \begin{align}\widehat{v}(V_F) =\,& s^{1-\frac1 \gamma}V_{F}^{-\frac1\gamma}, \qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad\qquad \end{align}
(3.6) \begin{align}\widehat{\Lambda}(V_{F},V_{FF},V_{Fs}) =\,&{-}\Sigma ^{-1} (\boldsymbol{\mu}-r\textbf{1}) \frac{V_{F}}{V_{FF}} - \sigma^{-\top}(\beta^z(s))^{\top} \frac{V_{Fs}}{V_{FF}},\end{align}

respectively. The system (2.14), (2.15) obtained once we have substituted these values for $\widehat{v}$ and $\widehat{\Lambda}$ is

(3.7) \begin{align}-\rho_2 V&+K+V_t+ \frac{\gamma}{1-\gamma} s^{1-\frac1\gamma} V_F^{1-\frac1\gamma} +rFV_F-\frac12 \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top}\boldsymbol{\theta} \frac{V_F^2}{V_{FF}} -\beta^z(s) \boldsymbol{\theta} \frac{V_F V_{Fs}}{V_{FF}}\nonumber\\[5pt] & +\eta V_s -\frac12 \beta^z(s)\beta^z(s)^{\top} \frac{V_{Fs}^2}{V_{FF}}+\frac{1}{2} \mathop{\rm tr}\nolimits\left\{\beta\beta^{\top}V_{ss}\right\} =0, \end{align}
(3.8) \begin{align}&\quad -\rho_1 K+K_t+\frac1{1-\gamma}(\rho_2-\rho_1)s^{1-\frac1\gamma}V_F^{1-\frac1\gamma} +rF K_F -\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top}\boldsymbol{\theta}\frac{V_F}{V_{FF}} K_F\nonumber\\[5pt]& \quad - \beta^z(s) \boldsymbol{\theta} \frac{V_{Fs}}{V_{FF}}K_F- s^{1-\frac1\gamma} V_F^{-\frac1\gamma} K_F+\eta K_s+\frac12 \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} \boldsymbol{\theta}\frac{V_F^2}{V^2_{FF}}K_{FF}\nonumber\\[5pt]& \quad + \frac12 \beta^z(s)\beta^z(s)^{\top}\frac{V_{Fs}^2}{V^2_{FF}} K_{FF} +\beta^z(s)\boldsymbol{\theta} \frac{V_F V_{Fs}}{V^2_{FF}}K_{FF}-\beta^z(s)\boldsymbol{\theta} \frac{V_F}{V_{FF}} K_{Fs}\nonumber\\[5pt]& \quad -\beta^z(s)\beta^z(s)^{\top} \frac{V_{Fs}}{V_{FF}}K_{Fs} +\frac{1}{2} \mathop{\rm tr}\nolimits\left\{\beta\beta^{\top} K_{ss}\right\}=0, \end{align}

with the final conditions $V(T,F,s)=\frac{\alpha}{1-\gamma}(F/s)^{1-\gamma}$ and $K(T,F,s)=0$ . The structure of these equations suggests the solutions $ V(t,F,s) =\frac1{1-\gamma}g(t,s) F^{1-\gamma}$ and $K(t,F,s)=\frac1{1-\gamma}h(t,s)F^{1-\gamma}$ . Imposing these solutions in (3.7), (3.8), we obtain the PDEs (3.3), (3.4) for the functions g and h. Substituting in (3.6), we obtain (3.2), and in (3.5), we obtain $v=s^{1-\frac1\gamma} g^{-\frac1\gamma} F$ , which in terms of $u=k-v/s$ is (3.1). Finally, applying a verification theorem in de-Paz et al. (Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano and Navas2013), Corollary 1, we deduce that $\hat{V}$ is the value function and u and $\Lambda$ are the time-consistent strategies.

The time-consistent relative contribution, u, given by (3.1), is the difference between the associated relative benefit, k, and a percentage of the fund, F, that also depends on the salary and the other parameters of the model, such as the risk aversion and the heterogeneous rates of discount, although through the time and salary depending function g. The contribution is the difference between the benefit and a variable percentage of the fund depending on the salary and discounts

\begin{equation*} C=B-s^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}} g^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t,s) F.\end{equation*}

Thus, the net benefit $B-C$ is proportional to the fund level and has the same monotony as the time function F. In terms of expected values, as the benefit is increasing, if the expected fund $\mathbb{E} F$ decreases, then the expected contribution $\mathbb{E} C$ increases. The proportionality factor depends on the salary of the workers and, through the function g and h, on several parameters considered as the difference between the rates of discount, $\rho_2-\rho_1$ . Another interesting observation is that, at terminal time T, when $\alpha=1$ the net benefit coincides with the terminal fund, $(B-C)(T)= s^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}\alpha^{-\frac1{\gamma}}g^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(T,s)F(T)=F(T)$ .

The vector of investments in the risky assets, (3.2), is the sum of two terms, both homogeneous linear functions of the fund F. The first is the constant of proportionality, $\Sigma^{-1}(\boldsymbol{\mu} - r\textbf{1})$ , called the optimal growth portfolio strategy (see Merton, Reference Merton1971), but modified by the constant factor $1/\gamma$ . The second depends on the correlation parameters between risky assets and the salary and also on time, and implicitly depends on other parameters such as the discount rates, risk aversions, market price of risk and the riskless rate of interest. Notice that it does not depend on the relative benefits, and that when $\beta^{z}(s)=\overline{0}$ , that is, the growth rate of the salary is not correlated with the returns on financial assets, this second term does not appear. In an extreme case, if the wage income is deterministic, $\beta(s)=\overline{0}$ , the randomness source only comes from the assets prices and the evolution of the salaries given by (2.12) is now an ordinary differential equation. Moreover, in this case (3.3), (3.4) is a system of PDEs of first order.

Substituting $u,\, \Lambda$ , from (3.1), (3.2) into (2.11), the fund evolution is given by the SDE

(3.9) \begin{equation} \begin{aligned}dF(t)=&\left(r-{s^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t)g^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t,s(t))} +\frac{1}{\gamma}\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} \boldsymbol{\theta} +\frac{1}{\gamma} \frac{g_{s}(t,s(t))} {g(t,s(t))} \beta^{z}(s(t))\boldsymbol{\theta} \right)\! F(t) dt \\[1ex]&\quad + \frac{1}{\gamma} \left( \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} +\frac{g_s(t,s(t))}{g(t,s(t))}\beta^{z}(s(t)) \right) F(t) dz(t),\end{aligned}\end{equation}

where s satisfies (2.12). Thus, the SDE (3.9), satisfied by the fund, is coupled with the SDE of the salary (2.12), so it is very difficult to obtain analytical solutions. In the next section, we consider a specification of the salary process, supposing that it is a geometric Brownian motion.

Remark 3.1. (Homogeneous discounting) When $\rho_1=\rho_2$ , the rate of discount is homogeneous and the model is analyzed in Josa-Fombellida and Rincón-Zapatero (Reference Josa-Fombellida, López-Casado and Rincón-Zapatero2008a) but with several groups of workers. In this case $h=0$ , by (3.4). If, moreover, $\eta=0$ and $\beta=\overline{0}$ , then we obtain the Merton model.

Remark 3.2. (Logarithmic utility) The case where $U(x)=\ln x$ can be analyzed with the same methodology. We obtain the same results as with the isoelastic utility when $\gamma$ goes to 1. The contribution and investments are given by

\begin{align*}u(t,F,s)&= k - s^{-1} {g^{-1}(t,s)} F,\\[1ex]\Lambda(t,F,s)&= \left ( \Sigma^{-1} (\boldsymbol{\mu}-r \textbf{1})+\frac{g_{s}(t,s)}{g(t,s)} \sigma^{-\top} (\beta^{z}(s))^{\top}\right) F,\end{align*}

and the fund evolution by the SDE

\begin{equation*}\begin{aligned}dF(t)=&\left(r-{g^{-1}(t,s(t))}+\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} \boldsymbol{\theta} + \frac{g_{s}(t,s(t))}{g(t,s(t))} \beta^{z}(s(t))\boldsymbol{\theta} \right) F(t) dt \\[1ex]&\quad + \left( \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} +\frac{g_s(t,s(t))}{g(t,s(t))}\beta^{z}(s(t)) \right) F(t) dz(t),\end{aligned}\end{equation*}

with $F(0)=F_0$ and where g satisfies (3.3), (3.4), but with $\gamma=1$ .

4. Time-consistent strategies when the salary is a geometric Brownian motion

In this section, we obtain and analyze the manager strategies for a specification of the salary process. It will allow Equation (3.3) to be solved analytically, and then the system (2.12), (3.9).

Assumption B. The salary process satisfies

\begin{equation*}\eta(s)=\eta s,\qquad \beta_{j}(s)=\beta_{j} s,\end{equation*}

with $\eta,\, \beta_{j} \in \mathbb{R}^{+}$ for all $j=1,\ldots,n+d$ . We suppose $\eta \geq r$ , that is to say, the salary growth is at least the market risk-free rate of interest.

The previous assumption, together with (2.8), means that the salary s is a GBM with SDE

\begin{equation*}d s(t)=s(t) \left( \eta dt +\sum_{j=1}^n \beta_{j} dz_j(t)+\sum_{j=n+1}^{n+d} \beta_{j}d w_{j-n}(t)\right),\end{equation*}

with $s(0)=s_0>0$ . In the following, we will employ the same notation $\eta,\,\beta,$ eliminating the dependence with respect to s. By (2.1), the benefit B satisfies the same SDE as the salary process, but with initial condition $B(0)=ks_0$ .

The assumption of exponential salary allows us to solve analytically the non-linear system (3.3), (3.4). The following result shows some conclusions about manager policies.

Proposition 4.1. Suppose that Assumptions A and B hold. Then, the time-consistent relative contribution rates and the investment in the risky assets are given by

(4.1) \begin{align} u(t,F,s)&= k-{a^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t)} \frac{F}{s}, \end{align}
(4.2) \begin{align}\Lambda(t,F,s)&=\frac{1}{\gamma} \left ( \Sigma^{-1} (\boldsymbol{\mu}-r \boldsymbol{1}) -(1-\gamma)\sigma^{-\top} (\beta^{z})^{\top} \right) F, \end{align}

respectively, where a is a positive solution of the system of differential equations

(4.3) \begin{align}\dot{a}(t)+b(t)+(\epsilon-\rho_2) a(t)+\gamma {a^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t)}=0,\qquad a(T)=\alpha, \end{align}
(4.4) \begin{align}\dot{b}(t)+(\epsilon-\rho_1) b(t)+(\rho_2-\rho_1){a^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t)} -(1-\gamma) {a^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}}(t)}b(t)=0,\qquad b(T)=0, \end{align}

with $\epsilon$ the constant

\begin{align*}\epsilon=& (1-\gamma)\left( r +\frac12\frac{1}{\gamma} \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} \boldsymbol{\theta} -\eta +\left(1-\frac1\gamma\right)\beta^z \boldsymbol{\theta} + \frac12 (1-\gamma)^2 \frac1\gamma \beta^z(\beta^z)^{\top} +\frac12 (2-\gamma)\mathop{\rm tr}\nolimits \left\{\beta\beta^{\top}\right\}\right).\end{align*}

Proof. Under Assumption B, it is not difficult to check that functions g and h of Theorem 3.1 are given by

(4.5) \begin{align}g(t,s)=&\,a(t) s^{-(1-\gamma)},\end{align}
(4.6) \begin{align}h(t,s)=&\,b(t) s^{-(1-\gamma)},\end{align}

where a, b satisfy (4.3) and (4.4), respectively. Substituting (4.5) in (3.1) and (4.6) in (3.2), we get the time-consistent strategies given by (4.1) and (4.2).

Concerning the functions a and b, solutions of the system (4.3)–(4.4), global existence and uniqueness is proved in Appendix A.

From (4.1), the net benefit relative to salary $k-u(t,F,s)$ is a percentage of the ratio fund/salary, $a^{-1/\gamma}$ . The proportionality function on time, ${a^{-1/\gamma}(t)}$ , depends on the rates of discount and the other parameters of the model. For a high-risk aversion ( $\gamma$ goes to infinite) the percentage goes to 1; for low-risk aversion ( $\gamma$ goes to 0) the percentage goes to 0; and for a moderate risk aversion ( $\gamma=1$ ) as shown in Remark 4.2.

Again, from (4.1), the contribution is now given by

(4.7) \begin{equation}C= B-{a^{-\frac1\gamma}(t)} F,\end{equation}

hence the difference between benefits and contributions, $B-C$ , does not depend directly on salary, that is, at every instant of time t, is given by the aforementioned percentage of the fund’s level that depends on the discounts and other parameters, ${a^{-\frac1\gamma}(t)} F(t)$ .

The vector of investments depends only linearly on the fund, but not on time or salary. Now the investments do not depend on the discount rates. The vector of investments is composed by two terms. The first is the optimal growth portfolio strategy and the second only depends on the correlation between salary and the financial market, the risk aversion parameter and the diffusion terms of the risky assets. Depending on some parameter values of the model, the investment policy can require short selling of the risky assets or borrowing to invest with risk. With high-risk aversion, more risk must be assumed if the correlations between the financial market and the salary, $\beta^z$ , are high. With low-risk aversion, the opposite with respect to the coefficient $\beta^z$ holds.

Assumption B leads to the SDE for the fund

(4.8) \begin{equation}d F(t)= \left( r +\frac1\gamma \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top}\boldsymbol{\theta} +\left(1-\frac1\gamma\right)\beta^z \boldsymbol{\theta} -{a^{-\frac1\gamma}(t)} \right) F(t) dt + \frac1\gamma \left(\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} - (1-\gamma) \beta^{z} \right) F(t) dz (t),\end{equation}

with $F(0)=F_0$ . The fund evolution does not depend on the fixed percentage of salary devoted to the benefit, k. It does, however, depend on the salary growth rate $\eta$ and the randomness parameters of the salary $\beta^z$ and $\beta^w$ . The SDE of the fund process is uncoupled with the SDE of the salary process and is in fact also a GBM. Thus, it is possible to explicitly obtain the expected value of the fund at every final instant $t\in [0,T]$ . By Arnold (Reference Arnold1974), p. 140, the expected terminal fund is

\begin{equation*} \mathbb{E}_{F_0} F(T)= F_0 \exp \left\{ \left(r +\frac1\gamma\left(\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top}\boldsymbol{\theta} - (1-\gamma)\beta^{z} \boldsymbol{\theta}\right)\right)T-\int_{0}^{T}{a^{-\frac1\gamma}(t)}dt\right\}.\end{equation*}

From (4.7), as in the previous section, it coincides with the expected value of the difference between the terminal benefit and the terminal contribution:

\begin{equation*}\mathbb{E}_{F_{0}} \{B(T)-C(T)\} = {a^{-\frac1\gamma}(T)} \mathbb{E}_{F_0} F(T)=\mathbb{E}_{F_0}F(T).\end{equation*}

Remark 4.1. (Deterministic salary) When the salary s is deterministic, the vector of investments in the risky assets is proportional to $\Sigma^{-1} (\mu-r \textbf{1}) F$ , as when s is stochastic, but uncorrelated with the assets. The structure of the contributions is the same, but now

\begin{equation*}\epsilon= (1-\gamma)\left( r +\frac12\frac1\gamma \boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top}\boldsymbol{\theta} -\eta \right).\end{equation*}

A sensibility analysis regarding the dynamics of the stock market reveals an impact over the manager’s contribution and investment strategies. A higher variability in the market implies a decrease of the expected fund values. So the agent should be aware about the risk in the markets since the wealth at the end of the plan could be affected by this risk.

Remark 4.2. (Logarithmic utility) When $U(x)=\ln x$ , the contribution and investments are given by

\begin{align*}u(t,F,s)&= k - s^{-1} {a^{-1}(t)} F,\\[1ex]\Lambda(t,F,s)&= \Sigma^{-1} (\boldsymbol{\mu}-r \textbf{1}) F,\end{align*}

where a satisfies the linear system of differential equations

\begin{align*}\dot{a}(t)+b(t)-\rho_2 a(t)+ 1=0,\qquad a(T)=\alpha, \\[1ex]\dot{b}(t)-\rho_1 b(t)+\rho_2-\rho_1 =0,\qquad b(T)=0.\end{align*}

Thus,

\begin{equation*}b(t)=\left(\frac{\rho_2}{\rho_1}-1\right)\left(1-e^{-\rho_1(T-t)}\right)\end{equation*}

and then

\begin{equation*}a(t)=\alpha e^{-\rho_2 (T-t)} +\frac{1-e^{-\rho_1 (T-t)}}{\rho_1}.\end{equation*}

The fund evolution is given by the SDE

\begin{equation*}dF(t)=\left(r+\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} \boldsymbol{\theta} - {a^{-1}(t)}\right) F(t) dt +\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top} F(t) dz(t), \qquad F(0)=F_0,\end{equation*}

and then

\begin{equation*}\mathbb{E}_{F_0}(B-C)(T) = \mathbb{E}_{F_0} F(T)= F_0 \exp \left\{ \left(r+\boldsymbol{\theta}^{\top}\boldsymbol{\theta} \right)T- \int_{0}^{T}{a^{-1}(t)}dt\right\}.\end{equation*}

5. A numerical illustration

In this section, we realize a numerical application to illustrate the dynamic behavior of the fund, the time-consistent contribution rate and the portfolio strategies, for several values of the rate of discount of the bequest function $\rho_2$ and the parameter $\gamma$ of the utility function.

We consider two economic regimes, bear and bull. In the bull regime, the economy is booming, and in the bear regime, it is in recession. We select the data characterizing both regimes, following the recommendations in Zou and Cadenillas (Reference Zou and Cadenillas2017). The risk premium is greater in booming periods than in recession periods, $\mu_1-r_1 > \mu_2-r_2$ , and the stock volatility is greater when the economy is in recession, $\sigma_2 >\sigma_1$ , and we assume that the risk premium by unit of volatility is higher in the booming periods than under recession, $\frac{\mu_1-r_1}{\sigma_1^2}>\frac{\mu_2-r_2}{\sigma_2^2} $ . We have denoted bull regime with subscript 1 and bear regime with 2. A bear market is considering in the baseline model, in order to study the less favorable situation for the fund. Later, we analyze some parameter variations, including the bull market and a comparison of the time-consistent solutions under the both regimes.

We have used the following packages of the R environment: “yuima” to compute the simulations from the SDEs, “deSolve” for the numerical resolution of the ODEs and “ggplot2” to build the figures.

We consider a portfolio with one riskless asset and one risky asset, $n=1$ . The values of the parameters we consider are the following:

  • the planning horizon is $T=10$ years;

  • the weight of the final utility in the objective function is $\alpha=5$ ;

  • the risk-free rate of interest is $r=0.01$ ;

  • the risky asset is a GBM with parameters $\mu=0.02$ and $\sigma= 0.1$ ; this implies a Sharpe ratio $\theta=0.1$ ;

  • the drift parameter of the salary process is $\eta=0.03$ , and the diffusion terms are $\beta^z=0.02$ and $\beta^w=0.01$ ;

  • the initial fund is $F_0=220,$ and the initial salary is $s_0=1000$ ;

  • the benefit is proportional to the salary. The percentage of salary devoted to benefit is 40%, $k=0.4$ . A path of the salary process and another of the benefit process along the planning horizon [0, 10] is plotted in Figure 1;

    Figure 1. Evolution of salary and benefit over time.

  • in order to study the sensitivity with respect to the relative risk aversion parameter, we consider values $\gamma=0.5, 0.75, 1, 2$ , indicating low, moderate or high-risk aversion for the manager; for the standard case, we fix $\gamma=1$ ;

  • the instantaneous rate of time preference is $\rho_1=0.05$ ; in order to study the sensitivity with respect to the discount factor associated with the terminal utility function, we consider values $\rho_2=0.05,0.15,0.25$ , that include the homogeneous case and two heterogeneous cases. $\rho_2=0.05$ will be the standard case.

The manager’s aim is to maximize an isoelastic utility function of the net benefit along the time horizon [0, T], discounted at a rate of time preference $\rho_1$ and an isoelastic utility function of the terminal fund surplus relative to salary, discounted at rate $\rho_2$ , $\rho_2\geq \rho_1$ .

Figure 2 shows a realization of the fund $F^*$ and the expected fund $\mathbb{E} F^*=\mathbb{E}_{F_0,s_0} F^*$ for several values of the risk aversion and the rate of discount of the bequest function. As the drift of the SDE (4.8) satisfied by the fund $F^*$ is negative, the graphs show a decreasing trend. A higher risk aversion implies a higher fund. A sensitivity analysis of the fund according to the rate of discount shows that the fund decreases more slowly with a smaller rate of discount. With high-risk aversion, the dependence of the fund with respect to the rate of discount is smaller.

Figure 2. Evolution of the fund and expected fund over time for different values of $\gamma$ and $\rho_2$ .

The contributions are increasing throughout almost all the planning interval. At the first instants of time, more risk aversion implies more contribution and a higher terminal rate of preference implies a lower contribution. At the last instants of time, the trend is the opposite, that is to say, a more terminal rate of preference or less risk aversion increases the contributions. Figure 3 shows a realization of the contribution $C^*$ and the expected relative contribution $\mathbb{E} C^*$ for several values of the risk aversion and the rate of discount of the bequest function.

Figure 3. Evolution of the contribution and the expected contribution over time for different values of $\gamma$ and $\rho_2$ .

An interesting question is to analyze the accumulated expected time-consistent contribution made to the funding process by the participants through the manager, $\int_0^T \mathbb{E} C^*(t) dt$ . Figure 4 shows the total expected contribution as a function of $\rho_2$ for several values of the risk aversion. More risk aversion implies more total contribution. We observe an almost constant trend. Note that for low or moderate risk aversion, it is an decreasing function, but the gap between the lowest value of $\rho_2$ , $0.05$ , and the highest value, $0.15$ , is smaller than $0.05$ . As a conclusion, the rate of discount does not influence the total quantity contributed to the pension plan.

The proportion of the fund invested in the risky asset does not depend on the rate of discount and is constant along time. More risk aversion diminishes the investment. A value of $\gamma$ below $0.99$ makes it necessary to borrow to reach the time-consistent policies. However, short selling is not necessary. Figure 5 shows a realization of the time-consistent investment relative to the fund, $\lambda^*/F$ , for several values of the risk aversion.

A sensitivity analysis of the expected terminal fund value, $\mathbb{E}F^*(T)$ , with respect to the risk aversion and the terminal rate of time preference can be obtained from Table 1. The terminal fund diminishes if the heterogeneity degree increases; in particular, it is higher with homogeneous discounting than with heterogenous discounting. To understand this negative effect on the terminal fund wealth, note that, from the bias generated by the heterogeneous discounting (for $\rho_2>\rho_1$ ), the decision maker initially overweights instantaneous payoffs with respect to the payoff at the end of the planning horizon, but as she moves along time this overweight decreases as the relative valuation of the final function increases. Because of this, in the case of the largest bias ( $\rho_2=0.25$ ), at the beginning of the planning horizon contributions are the lowest of the considered cases, but after some point, once the final function proportionally becomes more important, they beat contributions for the cases with a lower $\rho_2$ , as it can be observed at Figure 3. However, despite this increasing concern reflected in a higher contribution intensity, since this is the only way that the fund manager has to increase $\mathbb{E} F^*(T)$ , there is not enough remaining time to T to compensate the initially lower contributions. Consequently, $\mathbb{E} F^*(T)$ decreases when $\rho_2$ increases. A direct policy implication is that any measure oriented to reduce this bias will affect positively the value of the terminal fund. This decrease is less pronounced with high-risk aversion than with moderate or low-risk aversion. In particular, the expected terminal fund diminishes $63.5$ % in the heterogeneous case, $\rho_2=0.25$ , respect to the homogeneous case $\rho_2=0.05$ when the risk aversion is $\gamma=0.5$ ; however, the decrease is just $15.2$ % with moderate risk aversion. The terminal fund is lower when the risk aversion increases.

Table 1. Expected terminal fund for different values of $\gamma$ and $\rho_2$ .

Figure 4. Evolution of the total expected rate of contribution over $\gamma$ .

Figure 5. Evolution of the proportion invested in the risky asset over time for different values of $\gamma$ .

Previous analysis has been realized under a bear economic regime. An interesting question is to compare the fund evolution and the time-consistent strategies with a bull financial market. Specifically, we also now consider $\mu=0.05$ , $r=0.03$ and $\sigma=0.05$ ( $\theta=0.4$ ), for the bull regime. We keep the baseline data for the bear regime. Figure 6 shows a realization of the fund $F^*$ and the expected fund $\mathbb{E} F^*$ for the two economic regimes with moderate risk aversion ( $\gamma=1$ ). The graphs indicate a more decreasing trend with bear market than with bull market. In fact the fund is increasing in this concrete bull market. The fund diminishes from $F_0=220$ to $\mathbb{E} F(T)=74.788$ (66%) in the bear case and increases from $F_0=220$ to $\mathbb{E} F(T)=409.385$ (86%) in the bull case. We observe similar results with other values of the risk aversion parameter $\gamma$ and the market price of risk $\theta$ .

Figure 6. Evolution of the fund and the expected fund over time for two financial markets.

We also find a higher risky investments and contribution with the bull regime. We have also considered cases with $\rho_2<\rho_1$ . In particular, for an example of this scenario $\rho_1=0.1, \rho_2=0.05$ , the final fund value increases 22.2%. In absolute terms, 161.604 in the new scenario, versus 132.204 in the old scenario.

6. Conclusions

In this paper, we have considered the management of a DB pension plan with different constant rates of time preference associated with the instantaneous utility, as a function of the net benefit relative to salary, and with the final utility, as a function of the fund relative to salary. In this way, we have considered an increasing concern of the manager for the final function as she approaches the end of the planning horizon in a way that cannot be captured with a standard or homogeneous discounting. Moreover, the stochastic benefit has been assumed proportional to the total salary of the participants of the plan. The main novelty with respect to the specialized literature is the introduction of heterogeneous discounting in the analysis of a dynamic pension plan. The structure of the model includes two state variables to the stochastic control problem. For it, it is some different compared with previous models with heterogeneous discounting as the Merton model, with only one state variable, studied in de-Paz et al. (Reference de-Paz, Marín-Solano and Navas2013). The problem has been analytically solved using the dynamic programming approach, although it has meant an increase in mathematical difficulty. In this setting, we have managed to make the time-consistent net benefit and the investments proportional to the fund assets, and that they depend on the rates of time preference and the risk aversion parameters.

When the salary is a GBM, the proportionality factors do not depend on the salary and the investment strategies do not depend on the rate of discounting, and they coincide with those of the homogeneous discount case. The time-consistent contribution strategy and the corresponding fund dynamics depend on the rate of time preference associated with the final utility. A numerical illustration shows that a lower risk aversion implies a higher expected value of the fund, and a lower variation range of the expected contribution, and a smaller dependence of the rate of time preference on the final utility. However, the dependence of the total expected contribution with respect to the rate of time preference of the final utility and the risk aversion parameter is very small.

Further research can be addressed to analyze the effect of heterogeneous discounting on the time-consistent policies in other models of pension plans and in asset liability management models. For instance, it could be of interest to compare the time-consistent solutions obtained here with other solution concepts that, being time-inconsistent, could nevertheless represent a different behavior of the decision maker. This is the case for the so-called naive and precommitment solutions. Other interesting extension to explore for the future is to consider several groups of workers represented by different salaries.

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to the guest editor and two anonymous referees for their comments and suggestions. The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación under projects PID2020-117354GB-I00, PID2020-112509GB-I00, ECO2017-86261-P and ECO2017-82227-P (AEI/FEDER, UE) and Consejería de Educación de la Junta de Castilla y León (Spain) under project VA148G18.

A. Appendix

Proof of existence and uniqueness of solutions of the system (4.3)–(4.4).

Here, we discuss the existence and uniqueness of the functions a and b, solution of the system (4.3)–(4.4). Under the assumption of positivity of a, the expressions defining a (t) and b (t) are continuously differentiable in their arguments, which is a sufficient condition for local Lipschitz continuity. Now, we can use the Picard-Lindelöf theorem to guarantee local existence and uniqueness. See, for instance, Walter (Reference Walter1998) or Teschl (Reference Teschl2012).

Next, we need to ensure that a and b also exist (globally) over $[t_0,T]$ , that is, that the local solution can be extended along the whole planning horizon, for which it is required that it remains bounded in $[t_0,T]$ . For this, we follow the arguments in Ekeland and Pirvu (Reference Ekeland and Pirvu2008). The key point is to realize that a is also solution of the integral equation obtained by evaluating the functional objective (expression (2.13)) along our time-consistent solutions:

\begin{align*}\frac{1}{1-\gamma} a(t) \left( \frac{F(t)}{s(t)} \right) ^{(1-\gamma)} & = \mathbb{E}_{t,F_t,s_t} \left\{ \int_{t}^{T } e^{-\rho_1(\tau-t)} \,U\left(\frac{v(\tau)}{s(\tau)}\right)\,d\tau+ e^{-\rho_2(T-t)} \alpha U\left(\frac{F(T)}{s(T)}\right)\right\} \\& = \int_{t}^{T } e^{-\rho_1(\tau-t)}\, \frac{1}{1-\gamma} a(\tau)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}\mathbb{E}_{t,F_t,s_t} \left\{ \left(\frac{F(\tau)}{s(\tau)}\right)^{1-\gamma} \right\}\,d\tau\\&\quad +e^{-\rho_2(T-t)} \alpha \frac{1}{1-\gamma}\mathbb{E}_{t,F_t,s_t} \left\{ \left(\frac{F(T)}{s(T)}\right)^{1-\gamma}\right\},\end{align*}

where

\begin{gather*}\mathbb{E}_{t,F_t,s_t} \left\{ \left(\frac{F(\tau)}{s(\tau)}\right)^{1-\gamma} \right\}=\left( \frac{F(t)}{s(t)} \right)^{1-\gamma} e^{\Omega (\tau-t)-\int_t^{\tau}(1-\gamma)a(m)^{-1/\gamma}dm},\end{gather*}

with

\begin{align*}\Omega & = (1-\gamma)\left\{r+\frac{\theta^2}{\gamma}+\left(1-\frac{1}{\gamma}\right)\beta^z \theta-\eta-\frac{1}{2\gamma}(\theta - (1-\gamma)\beta^z)^2 \right. \\& \quad \left. -\frac{1}{2} (\gamma-2)\left((\beta^z)^2+(\beta^w)^2\right)-(1-\gamma)\frac{\beta^z}{\gamma}(\theta - (1-\gamma)\beta^z)\right\}.\end{align*}

Here, $\Omega$ has been calculated in the scalar case of the diffusion of the processes F(t) and s(t) just for simplicity, but the vector specification extension is straightforward.

Next, by comparing terms in $(F(t)/s(t))^{1-\gamma}$ we have

(A1) \begin{equation}\begin{split}a(t)= & \int_t^T e^{-\rho_1 (\tau-t)} a(\tau)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}} e^{\Omega (\tau-t)-\int_t^{\tau} (1-\gamma)a(m)^{-1/\gamma}dm} d\tau \\& +e^{-\rho_2 (T-t)} \alpha e^{\Omega (T-t)-\int_t^T (1-\gamma)a(m)^{-1/\gamma}dm}.\end{split}\end{equation}

Expression (A1) defines the integral equation also satisfied by a but now without the interaction of b, so it will allow us to characterize the growth of a in an easier way than from the system (4.3)–(4.4). For this, we differentiate this expression with respect to t to obtain

(A2) \begin{equation} \begin{split}a'(t) = & -\gamma a(t)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}-(1-\gamma)\Omega a(t)\\&+\rho_1 \int_t^T e^{-\rho_1 (\tau-t)} a(\tau)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}} e^{\Omega (\tau-t)-\int_t^{\tau} (1-\gamma)a(m)^{-1/\gamma}dm} d\tau \\&+\rho_2 e^{-\rho_2 (T-t)} \alpha e^{\Omega (T-t)-\int_t^T (1-\gamma)a(m)^{-1/\gamma}dm}.\end{split}\end{equation}

Note that, under the assumption that $\rho_2>\rho_1$ , we have that

(A3) \begin{equation} \begin{split}\rho_1 a(t)< \; & \rho_1 \int_t^T e^{-\rho_1 (\tau-t)} a(\tau)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}} e^{\Omega (\tau-t)-\int_t^{\tau} (1-\gamma)a(m)^{-1/\gamma}dm} d\tau \\& +\rho_2 e^{-\rho_2 (T-t)} \alpha e^{\Omega (T-t)-\int_t^T (1-\gamma)a(m)^{-1/\gamma}dm}<\rho_2 a(t).\end{split}\end{equation}

From (A2) and (A3), we obtain

(A4) \begin{equation} a'(t)>\left(\rho_1 -(1-\gamma)\Omega\right)a(t)-\gamma a(t)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}},\end{equation}
(A5) \begin{equation}a'(t)<\left(\rho_2 -(1-\gamma)\Omega\right) a(t)-\gamma a(t)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}.\end{equation}

Finally, from (A4) and (A5) we have expressions for upper ( $w_u(t)$ ) and lower ( $w_l(t)$ ) solutions of a(t), which can be obtained by solving the following differential equations

(A6) \begin{equation} w_i'(t)=C_i w_i(t)-\gamma w_i(t)^{1-\frac{1}{\gamma}}, \;\;\; i=u,l,\end{equation}

where $C_u$ and $C_l$ are two arbitrary constants satisfying $C_u\leq\rho_1 -(1-\gamma)\Omega$ and $C_l\geq \rho_2 -(1-\gamma)\Omega$ . By solving (A6), we obtain

\begin{equation*}w_i(t)=\left( \alpha^{\frac{1}{\gamma}} e^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}C_i (T-t)}+\gamma \frac{1- e^{-\frac{1}{\gamma}C_i (T-t)}}{C_i}\right)^\gamma, \;\;\; i=u,l,\end{equation*}

which are continuous functions over [0, T], guarantying the existence of a along the whole planning horizon. Finally, note that b(t) in Equation (4.4), after substitution of a(t), follows a linear differential equation whose solution also exists on the considered interval.

References

Ahmad, Z., Ibrahim, H. and Tuyon, J. (2017) Institutional investor behavioral biases: Syntheses of theory and evidence. Management Research Review, 40, 578603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnold, L. (1974) Stochastic Differential Equations. Theory and Applications. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Ayton, P., Clacher, I., Strong, C., Thoma, V. and Weiss-Cohen, L. (2021) Pension Trustee Decision Making. London, UK: Actuarial Research Centre, Institute and Faculty of Actuaries.Google Scholar
Battocchio, P. and Menoncin, F. (2004) Optimal pension management in a stochastic framework. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 34,7995.Google Scholar
Battocchio, P., Menoncin, F. and Scaillet, O. (2007) Optimal asset allocation for pension funds under mortality risk during the accumulation and decumulation phases. Annals of Operations Research, 152, 141165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berkelaar, A. and Kouwenberg, R. (2003) Retirement saving with contribution payments and labor income as a benchmark for investments. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27, 10691097.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cairns, A.J.G. (2000) Some notes on the dynamics and optimal control of stochastic pension fund models in continuous time. ASTIN Bulletin, 30, 1955.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cairns, A.J.G., Blake, D. and Dowd, K. (2006) Stochastic lifestyling: Optimal dynamic asset allocation for defined-contribution pension plans. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30, 843877.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, S.C, Tzeng, L.Y. and Miao, J.C.Y. (2003) Pension funding incorporating downside risks. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 32, 217228.Google Scholar
Chen, A. and Delong, Ł. (2015) Optimal investment for a defined-contribution pension scheme under a regime-switching model. ASTIN Bulletin, 45, 397419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, S. and Hao, Z. (2013) Funding and investment decisions in a stochastic defined benefit pension with regime switching. Lithuanian Mathematical Journal, 53, 161180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delong, L., Gerrard, R. and Haberman, S. (2008) Mean-variance optimization problems for an accumulation phase in a defined benefit plan. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 42, 107118.Google Scholar
de-Paz, A., Marín-Solano, J. and Navas, J. (2013) A consumption-investment problem with heterogeneous discounting. Mathematical Social Sciences, 66, 221232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de-Paz, A., Marín-Solano, J., Navas, J. and Roch, O. (2014) Consumption, investment and life insurance strategies with heterogeneous discounting. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 54, 6675.Google Scholar
Devolder, P., Bosch, P.M. and Domínguez, F.I. (2003) Stochastic optimal control of annuity contracts. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 33, 227238.Google Scholar
Ekeland, I. and Pirvu, T. (2008) Investment and consumption without commitment. Mathematics and Financial Economics, 2(1), 5786.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. and O’Donoghue, T. (2002) Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gao, J. (2009) Optimal portfolios for DC pension plans under a CEV model. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 44, 479490.Google Scholar
Gerrard, R., Haberman, S. and Vigna, E. (2006) The management of decumulation risks in a defined contribution pension scheme. North American Actuarial Journal, 10, 84110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haberman, S. and Sung, J.H. (1994) Dynamics approaches to pension funding. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 15, 151162.Google Scholar
Hodgson, T., Hall, M., Urwin, R., Gao, J. and Khanna, S. (2021) Global top 300 pension funds. A Thinking Ahead Institute and Pensions & Investments joint study. Retrieved from https://www.thinkingaheadinstitute.org/content/uploads/2021/09/PI-300-2021.pdf.Google Scholar
Jackson, M.O. and Yariv, L. (2015) Collective dynamic choice: The necessity of time inconsistency. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 7, 150178.Google Scholar
Josa-Fombellida, R., López-Casado, P. and Rincón-Zapatero, J.P. (2018) Portfolio optimization in a defined benefit pension plan where the risky assets are processes with constant elasticity of variance. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 82, 7386.Google Scholar
Josa-Fombellida, R. and Navas, J. (2020) Time consistent pension funding in a defined benefit pension plan with non-constant discounting. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 94, 142153.Google Scholar
Josa-Fombellida, R. and Rincón-Zapatero, J.P. (2004) Optimal risk management in defined benefit stochastic pension funds. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 34, 489503.Google Scholar
Josa-Fombellida, R. and Rincón-Zapatero, J.P. (2008a) Funding and investment decisions in a stochastic defined benefit pension plan with several levels of labor-income earnings. Computers and Operations Research, 35, 4763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Josa-Fombellida, R. and Rincón-Zapatero, J.P. (2008b) Mean-variance portfolio and contribution selection in stochastic pension funding. European Journal of Operational Research, 187, 120137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Josa-Fombellida, R. and Rincón-Zapatero, J.P. (2019) Equilibrium strategies in a defined benefit pension plan game. European Journal of Operational Research, 275, 374386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karp, L. (2007) Non-constant discounting in continuous time. Journal of Economic Theory, 132, 557568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le Cortois, O. and Menoncin, F. (2015) Portfolio optimisation with jumps: Illustration with a pension accumulation scheme. Journal of Banking and Finance, 60, 127137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marín-Solano, J. and Patxot, C. (2012) Heterogeneous discounting in economic problems. Optimal Control Applications and Methods, 33, 3250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, R.C. (1971) Optimal consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 373413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teschl, G. (2012) Ordinary Differential Equations and Dynamical Systems. Rhode Island, USA: American Mathematical Society.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Urbano, B., Jurado, A. and Rosado-Cebrián, B. (2021) What will retirement pensions be like? Analysis of Spanish future pensioner households in terms of poverty. Sustainability, 13, 1760. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13041760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walter, W. (1998) Ordinary Differential Equations. New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weiss-Cohen, L., Ayton, P., Clacher, I. and Thoma, V. (2019) Behavioral biases in pension fund trustees’ decision making. Review of Behavioral Finance, 11, 128143. doi: 10.1108/RBF-05-2018-0049.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zou, B. and Cadenillas, A. (2017) Optimal investment and liability ratio policies in a multidimensional regime switching model. Risks, 5, 6. doi: 10.3390/risks5010006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zou, Z., Chen, S. and Wedge, L. (2014) Finite horizon consumption and portfolio decisions with stochastic hyperbolic discounting. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 52, 7080.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Evolution of salary and benefit over time.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Evolution of the fund and expected fund over time for different values of $\gamma$ and $\rho_2$.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Evolution of the contribution and the expected contribution over time for different values of $\gamma$ and $\rho_2$.

Figure 3

Table 1. Expected terminal fund for different values of $\gamma$ and $\rho_2$.

Figure 4

Figure 4. Evolution of the total expected rate of contribution over $\gamma$.

Figure 5

Figure 5. Evolution of the proportion invested in the risky asset over time for different values of $\gamma$.

Figure 6

Figure 6. Evolution of the fund and the expected fund over time for two financial markets.