Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T13:32:18.707Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HENRIK MOURITSEN, THE ROMAN ELITE AND THE END OF THE REPUBLIC. THE BONI, THE NOBLES, AND CICERO. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 2023. Pp. vii + 322. isbn 9781009180658 (hbk) £75.00; 9781009180672 (pbk); 9781009180665 (epub); 9781009190275 (PDF ebook).

Review products

HENRIK MOURITSEN, THE ROMAN ELITE AND THE END OF THE REPUBLIC. THE BONI, THE NOBLES, AND CICERO. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 2023. Pp. vii + 322. isbn 9781009180658 (hbk) £75.00; 9781009180672 (pbk); 9781009180665 (epub); 9781009190275 (PDF ebook).

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 October 2024

Emilio Zucchetti*
Affiliation:
Royal Holloway, University of London
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Reviews
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of The Society for the Promotion of Roman Studies

This ambitious conclusion to Henrik Mouritsen's trilogy on republican politics constitutes a vital contribution to the field, aiming to redefine its analytical framework by focusing on the previously ignored constituency of the boni, wealthy landowners of the first class, who ranked below the equestrians. The volume is divided into three sections: Part I investigates the social meaning of boni, through lexicological and historiographical means. Part II discusses the relationship between the boni and republican politics, their material interests as wealthy landowners and their debts, while Part III focuses on the boni's role at the end of the Republic.

M. builds his sophisticated identification of the boni with a distinct non-political group within the Roman elite mostly on Ciceronian writings, though he tests their limits through careful contextual reading and comparison with other sources. His interpretation of e.g. De Lege Agraria (154–62) or the Catilinarians (180–1) seems to accept Cicero's views on various issues as factual, implying that he was reproducing a pre-existing discourse. Similarly, the interpretation of furor/amentia of the perditi/egentes (165 and 171) seems to be understood literally (e.g. ‘wasting one's resource both reflected and aggravated mental disturbances’, 175). But this is a common trope (see e.g. Cic., Har. Resp. 10, 39, 50), and a discursive link between furor/Furies and civil war/discordia is found in epic poetry. The regularity M. spots in the use of boni to indicate a specific class (Appendix 1) might be due to Cicero's perspective rather than a shared ancient category. In ch. 8, M. acknowledges that boni also indicates the civic ideal of exemplary Roman citizen, constructing political discourse as a moralistic binary between honourable men and their opponents. However, a Sallustian fragment (Hist. 1.12M), which M. mentions once (88) and tangentially discusses later (134), stating that ‘the rich were regarded as boni because they defended the praesentia [i.e. the current conditions]’, suggests a more conventional interpretation of the noun: the boni are the author's supporters and the improbi his morally depraved enemies.

For M., the boni were a part of the elite not interested in politics and wanting simply to protect their otium, the internal peace that allows you to enjoy your resources. This term is politically more relevant than concordia, which is considered its ‘essential precondition’ (126). All politicians invoke otium to appeal to the boni, the intended audience of public oratory (73). This group dominated the Forum, formed the audience of contiones and public court proceedings and ‘provided most of the participants in the legislative comitia’ (69). M. argues that the narrative of otium and tranquillitas was not an ideology, which the boni never had. Here, reluctance to explicitly discuss modern categories emerges as a weakness of the volume. ‘Ideology’ is a contested category: e.g., Rosenblitt's argument (AJPh 137 (2016)) about fear in the rhetoric of late republican ‘popular champions’ could be applied to Cicero's leveraging of fear of losing property described in ch. 10.

Notwithstanding the boni's central role in M.'s view of Roman politics, they are said to belong to the non-political classes, which include the members of the senatorial and equestrian classes who were not directly involved in senatorial or magisterial roles but not the non-elite actors, which were included in Syme's use of the concept (Santangelo, Studi Storici 64, 2023). M.'s view of Roman politics leaves little space for non-elite agency, following P. J. J. Vanderbroeck's top-down reading of leadership and collective behaviour (150, n. 32): crowds emerged as political actors when elite leaders exploited their needs to further their individualistic politics (149) and most riots were pre-political reactions to food shortages (150). Though the boni are, in his view, deciding the elections, M. only considers individuals directly engaged as senators or magistrates as political, as he does in his recent article about populism (Historia 72 (2023), 334).

Similarly, debt is seen as an effect of the rising costs of politics, affecting the elite. M.'s analysis is perhaps too radical: the poorest indeed had no assets to offer as collateral (179), but there is no reason to believe that this forbade them access to credit except for ‘informal, interpersonal exchanges’ (189). Documentary sources from Egypt demonstrate that humble families commonly had debts (e.g. P. Kron.), often repaid through labour (e.g. the Harthotes archive), sometimes performed by children (e.g. P.Mich. 10.587). A second-century c.e. soothsayer's handbook (Sortes Astrampsychi) has two questions on debt (Q25 from the debtor's perspective, Q58 from the creditor's), suggesting that it was a widespread concern. Even if one accepts M.'s argument that debt is presented as solely an elite concern in the sources (182), this does not mean that it reflects social reality: non-elite actors are overlooked in elite sources, who saw them as an undifferentiated mass (Appendix 2) and were uninterested in their everyday life. However, there is no reason why politicians could not have used the argument of tabulae novae to appeal to their class and the lower classes simultaneously.

The final section of the book achieves important results. It nuances the notion of ‘elite’, by focusing on the different political interests of various groups (chs 13–14), provides the reader with a coherent reading of Cicero's political trajectory (ch. 15), placing him back at the centre of late republican politics, and offers a solid account of elite politics in the transition between Republic and Principate. Indeed, M.'s book is a must-read for all scholars of the Late Republic, with its useful appendices and refined scholarly discussion. If the argument is bound to divide readers, it will be impossible for any scholar to underestimate the importance of this work for future historiography on the subject.