Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T11:46:42.090Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Disentangling wealth effects on fertility in 64 low- and middle-income countries

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 November 2020

Joseph Hackman*
Affiliation:
University of Utah, Department of Anthropology, Salt Lake City, Utah, USA
Daniel Hruschka
Affiliation:
Arizona State University, School of Human Evolution and Social Change, Arizona, USA
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

Studies have shown mixed associations between wealth and fertility, a finding that has posed ongoing puzzles for evolutionary theories of human reproduction. However, measures of wealth do not simply capture economic capacity, which is expected to increase fertility. They can also serve as a proxy for market opportunities available to a household, which may reduce fertility. The multifaceted meaning of many wealth measures obscures our ability to draw inferences about the relationship between wealth and fertility. Here, we disentangle economic capacity and market opportunities using wealth measures that do not carry the same market-oriented biases as commonly used asset-based measures. Using measures of agricultural and market-based wealth for 562,324 women across 111,724 sampling clusters from 151 DHS surveys in 64 countries, we employ a latent variable structural equation model to estimate (a) latent variables capturing economic capacity and market opportunity and (b) their effects on completed fertility. Market opportunities had a consistent negative effect on fertility, while economic capacity had a weaker but generally positive effect on fertility. The results show that the confusion between operational measures of wealth and the concepts of economic capacity can impede our understanding of how material resources and market contexts shape reproduction.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Evolutionary Human Sciences

Media summary: Multiple measures of wealth can parse the effects of economic capacity from market opportunities on fertility in LMICS.

Introduction

The association between socioeconomic status and fertility

The global transition to low fertility in the midst of modernisation has been a biological puzzle for decades (Handwerker, Reference Handwerker1986; Kaplan, Reference Kaplan1996; Vining, Reference Vining1986). A central feature of this puzzle is the inconsistent relationship between socioeconomic status and fertility across human contexts. Studies in anthropology have often documented positive effects of wealth and status on reproduction and fertility across a range of traditional, small-scale and subsistence populations (Cronk, Reference Cronk1991; Flinn, Reference Flinn1986; Turke & Betzig, Reference Turke and Betzig1985). For example, when wealth is measured as food energy, researchers have often found a strong positive association between wealth and reproductive success (Borgerhoff Mulder & Beheim, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder and Beheim2011; Kaplan, Lancaster, Tucker, & Anderson, Reference Kaplan, Lancaster, Tucker and Anderson2002). When wealth comes in the form of material assets in these contexts, there is also a positive association with reproductive output, particularly for men (Borgerhoff Mulder & Beheim, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder and Beheim2011; Cronk, Reference Cronk1991; Flinn, Reference Flinn1986; Nettle & Pollet, Reference Nettle and Pollet2008). These studies suggest that in small-scale and traditional populations, the accrual of wealth and status carried positive fitness benefits (Kaplan, Reference Kaplan1996; Sear, Lawson, Kaplan, & Shenk, Reference Sear, Lawson, Kaplan and Shenk2016; von Rueden, Reference von Rueden2014; von Rueden et al., Reference von Rueden, Gurven, Kaplan, Rueden, Gurven and Kaplan2011). However, the positive effects of wealth and status on fertility are far from universal, and numerous studies have also shown negative or null associations, especially among market-integrated populations (Retherford, Reference Retherford1986; Vining, Reference Vining1986).

Within contemporary Western populations, wealthier, higher status men tend to have lower fertility (Kaplan et al., Reference Kaplan, Lancaster, Tucker and Anderson2002; Lam, Reference Lam1986; Pérusse, Reference Pérusse1993). In low and middle-income countries where populations are at different stages of this transition, women in wealthier households have fewer children on average (Hruschka & Burger, Reference Hruschka and Burger2016; Hruschka, Sear, Hackman, & Drake, Reference Hruschka, Sear, Hackman and Drake2019; Lutz & KC, Reference Lutz and KC2011; Myrskylä, Kohler, & Billari, Reference Myrskylä, Kohler and Billari2009; Pérusse, Reference Pérusse1993). Over the course of the fertility transition, wealthier families also reduce their fertility earlier and more dramatically than the rest of the population (Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder1998; Livi-Bacci, Reference Livi-Bacci1986; Skirbekk, Reference Skirbekk2008). Finally, studies using historical samples have identified a switch in the relationship between socioeconomic status and fertility, whereby high-status individuals move to low-fertility strategies while low-status individuals move to having relatively higher fertility (Skirbekk, Reference Skirbekk2008). Scholars have argued that these findings show that the links between fitness and the accumulation of wealth and status have been disrupted or severed in contemporary populations (Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk, & Mace, Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2015; Pérusse, Reference Pérusse1993). Indeed, studies of low-fertility regimes have shown that increases in wealth and status at the expense of fertility have never resulted in a long-term fitness payoff (Goodman, Koupil, & Lawson, Reference Goodman, Koupil and Lawson2012; Kaplan, Lancaster, Johnson, & Bock, Reference Kaplan, Lancaster, Johnson and Bock1995).

The current paper addresses the puzzling and inconsistent associations between socioeconomic status and fertility by exploring the possibility that measures of socioeconomic status (e.g. income, wealth & education) confound two conceptually distinct factors – differential economic capacity and differential market opportunities – that should have opposing effects on fertility. We first review recent studies and theoretical explanations of the wealth–fertility association. We focus on investment models, common in economics and evolutionary social sciences, which argue that market economies drive down fertility as parents focus on generating access to novel forms of social and economic opportunities for their children (Shenk, Reference Shenk2009). Next, we argue that commonly used measures of wealth tend to conflate economic capacity with market opportunities, making it difficult to test theories about the independent effects of economic capacity and market opportunities. Finally, we attempt to disentangle the effects of market opportunities and economic capacity on fertility using multiple forms of wealth to parse out the effects of economic capacity from those of market opportunities.

Market economies and changes in quality–quantity trade-offs

The demographic transition and associated changes in the wealth and fertility relationship have been discussed in great detail in evolutionary social sciences (Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder1998; Irons, Reference Irons1983; Mace, Reference Mace1996; Sear et al., Reference Sear, Lawson, Kaplan and Shenk2016; Vining, Reference Vining1986). The causes of the fertility decline and changing relationships between socioeconomic status and fertility have been attributed to increasing costs and benefits of status competition (Boone & Kessler, Reference Boone and Kessler1999; Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Borgerhoff Mulder1998; Hill & Reeve, Reference Hill and Reeve2005; Low, Simon, & Anderson, Reference Low, Simon and Anderson2002; Mace, Reference Mace2008), the increasing costs and benefits of parental investments in novel market economies (Becker, Murphy, & Tamura, Reference Becker, Murphy and Tamura1990; Kaplan, Reference Kaplan1996), women's education (Low et al., Reference Low, Simon and Anderson2002), changing payoffs to human capital investments (Kaplan, Hill, Lancaster, & Hurtado, Reference Kaplan, Hill, Lancaster and Hurtado2000), the breakdown of kinship networks (Newson, Postmes, Lea, & Webley, Reference Newson, Postmes, Lea and Webley2005; Turke, Reference Turke1989), cultural evolution (Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson1985; Richerson & Boyd, Reference Richerson and Boyd2005), or the costs and benefits of fertility reduction as a social mobility strategy in a stratified society (Rogers, Reference Rogers1990).

Perhaps the most prominent evolutionary and economic explanations have been those that focus on how market economies shape the quality–quantity trade-off that parents face. These models focus on life-history trade-offs where parents balance investment in producing offspring with investment in the quality of existing offspring to promote survival and future success (Lawson, Alvergne, & Gibson, Reference Lawson, Alvergne and Gibson2012; Lawson & Mace, Reference Lawson and Mace2011; Lawson & Mulder, Reference Lawson and Mulder2016).

Figure 1 outlines the key points of the quality–quantity models. Resources that are devoted to reproduction (A) are split between the total number of offspring (B) and the investment in each offspring (C) in order to maximise a parent's reproductive success (G). Kaplan and colleagues developed an extensive theory of human reproduction that specified many of the links in the full model (Kaplan, Reference Kaplan1996; Kaplan et al., Reference Kaplan, Lancaster, Tucker and Anderson2002; Snopkowski & Kaplan, Reference Snopkowski and Kaplan2014). According to their model, among hunter–gatherers, fertility is coordinated through systems of behavioural and physiological responses, with psychological adaptations which evolved to track the links between parental investment and the reproductive success of their offspring. The skill-dependent foraging niche of humans required extended parental support, which placed constraints on the fitness returns to both parental investments in existing offspring, and the production of additional offspring.

Figure 1. Theoretical model of the quality quantity trade-off.

A key premise in this model is that navigating trade-offs in order to maximise reproductive success (G) is a complex task. Thus, parents try to optimise some combination of proximate currencies like total offspring (B) and offspring socioeconomic success (E).

To do this, parents will pay attention to how the investments in child quality (C) translate to child quality (D) and how child quality translates into socioeconomic success (E). These links are indicated by dashed lines in Figure 1. The model also proposes that parents use offspring quality (D) and offspring socioeconomic (E) as proxies for the more distal variables of offspring reproductive fitness, and do not pay particular attention to the downstream links between D and F, or E and F. Thus, when these links become broken (as they are in contemporary societies), the argument is that these do not hold strong sway over decision-making (Goodman et al., Reference Goodman, Koupil and Lawson2012).

According to this model, increasing socioeconomic payoffs to investment in child quality can tip the balance of quality–quantity trade-offs, leading parents to reduce fertility in favour of investing in fewer high-quality children. The model here outlines two ways that returns on investment can be increased. The first is increasing the efficiency with which parental investments (C) translate into child quality (D), for example investments in education leading to a more educated and skilled child. The second is how well a person can use their education and skills to unlock opportunities for increased income or socioeconomic success. The embodied capital model touches on both of these. First, it proposes that parents with experience in the education system are better equipped to help their children navigate the educational system, and their investments in education can more efficiently lead to an educated child (Kaplan, Reference Kaplan1996; Kaplan et al., Reference Kaplan, Lancaster, Tucker and Anderson2002). This can increase the efficiency of translating investments to educational achievement, and lead parents with more embodied capital (H) to redirect investments to offspring quality at the expense of offspring quantity. Second, and critical to the current study, the model also considers how changing market opportunities can increase the socioeconomic returns to education (e.g. the efficiency by which D translates to E). Competitive wage-labour economies increase opportunities to translate current child quality (i.e. education) into future offspring socioeconomic success. Furthermore, changing balances of supply and demand for skilled labour can affect returns on investment in child quality (Kaplan & Lancaster, Reference Kaplan and Lancaster2000).

While broad social changes can shape overall quality–quantity trade-offs, not all children in a population will have the same opportunities to translate education (or other investments in quality) into greater later life success. For example, changing economic conditions may affect women differentially because of lower expected socioeconomic gains from education and differences in available employment opportunities (Snopkowski & Kaplan, Reference Snopkowski and Kaplan2014). A family's social connections may provide more opportunities for translating a child's education into income-producing jobs (Coleman, Reference Coleman1988; Matthews, Pendakur, & Young, Reference Matthews, Pendakur and Young2009; Portes & Landolt, Reference Portes and Landolt1998). The wage returns to schooling may be lower for ethnic groups that suffer from exclusion from certain sectors of the labour market (Patrinos, Reference Patrinos2000; Patrinos & Psacharopoulos, Reference Patrinos and Psacharopoulos1997). Even physical proximity to market opportunities may shape returns to investment (McAllister, Gurven, Kaplan, & Stieglitz, Reference McAllister, Gurven, Kaplan and Stieglitz2012). Market opportunities are often more concentrated in urban centres, providing more opportunities to translate education into income-producing employment (Mattison & Neill, Reference Mattison and Neill2013; Neill, Reference Neill2010). Additionally, a family's experience with labour markets and market economies may provide valuable skills and connections necessary to translate education into future income and socioeconomic status. Even in the presence of educational opportunities, family livelihoods may shape the expected returns to, and willingness to invest in, offspring education (Hedges, Borgerhoff Mulder, James, & Lawson, Reference Hedges, Borgerhoff Mulder, James and Lawson2016).

In each of these cases, individual and household variation in market opportunities – or the suite of options to translate education into future socioeconomic status – may substantially shape the returns on investment in child quality and quality–quantity trade-offs. Analyses of populations without accounting for this variation in accessing market opportunities may obscure how parents make decisions about the trade-offs (Stulp, Sear, & Barrett, Reference Stulp, Sear and Barrett2016). For example, in heterogeneous populations, where different groups of people face unique suites of employment opportunities, investment options, or different costs of raising children, groups with greater market opportunities might follow decision rules that lead to smaller families overall compared with groups with fewer market opportunities (Mace, Reference Mace1998; Stulp & Barrett, Reference Stulp and Barrett2016). In those cases where family status (however measured) is associated with greater market opportunities for their children, this can lead to a negative correlation between family status and fertility at the population level. However, within those high- and low-status groups we may see those with greater economic capacity still having higher relative fertility (Mace, Reference Mace1998). In an early empirical example, one study among highly educated women in Britain's top universities found wealth was positively associated with reproductive success (Hubback, Reference Hubback1957). Here, similarities in education can be assumed to reflect similarities in market opportunities. In another example, across subgroups in urban and rural Mongolia, researchers found a negative association between resources and fertility; however, within each group fertility correlated positively with measures of material resources (Alvergne & Lummaa, Reference Alvergne and Lummaa2014). More recently, Colleran found that within communities in rural Poland, associations of non-farming and farming wealth with fertility were generally positive after controlling for market integration and education (Colleran et al., Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2015).

Notably, this theoretical model also illustrates the various ways that the concept of status can figure in fertility decisions, and the difficulties of clearly differentiating wealth and status. One approach distinguishes wealth defined as resources from status defined as access to resources (Colleran et al., Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2015; Colleran & Snopkowski, Reference Colleran and Snopkowski2018). According to this definition, a number of key aspects of the model fall under the concept of status. Parents’ education (under embodied capital H) provides access to cultural capital that can increase the efficiency of translating parental investments in child education into child quality. Parents’ and children's access to market opportunities (I) and children's socioeconomic success (E) are also forms of status, defined again as access to resources. Even parent's economic capacity – which is an intuitively straightforward measure of material wealth – is an indicator of their ability to access resources through economic exchange, and thus a form of status as well.

Another approach defines status as a positional good where the value is defined relative to the amount held by others in a relevant community, whereas wealth is defined as an absolute good whose value is fixed (Shenk, Hooper, & Kaplan, Reference Shenk, Hooper and Kaplan2016). However, it can be difficult to disentangle what resources are absolute and what resources are relative in a given context. For example, parental embodied capital (H), offspring quality (D) and socioeconomic success (E) can be defined as relational goods, where the value depends on how much is present in a relevant community. Even parental economic capacity can be a relative concept. For example, the economic value of money can change depending on how much others in the monetary system control. More generally, the status–wealth distinction can be difficult to parse empirically, as resources and access to resources can by proxied by the same measures, and absolute and relational goods are often not clearly demarcated in the real world. The multidimensional and entangled nature of both wealth and status suggests that simple status–wealth distinctions may not be sufficient to understand the effects of resources on fertility. Rather, models may need to carefully specify how different kinds of resources, access and opportunities shape fertility-related decisions and how a single measure may capture several kinds of resources, access and opportunities that are relevant to fertility in different ways.

Assessing support for the model is difficult due to data and measurement issues

Researchers have argued that data limitations have inhibited clear tests of the model, particularly in comparative contexts (Colleran et al., Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2015; Hopcroft, Reference Hopcroft2006; Stulp, Sear, Schaffnit, Mills, & Barrett, Reference Stulp, Sear, Schaffnit, Mills and Barrett2016). A key component of this critique is disentangling key concepts, such as economic capacity and market opportunity, from standard measures of socioeconomic status. Disentangling economic capacity and market opportunities is important because they are argued to have distinct, interactive or even opposing effects on fertility (Colleran et al., Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2015; Shenk et al., Reference Shenk, Hooper and Kaplan2016). However, historical and cross-sectional datasets often use measures that conflate market opportunities with economic capacity. Different measures of socioeconomic status may differentially confound economic status and market opportunities available to their children. For example, parental education may more strongly reflect market opportunities than economic capacity. Consistent with this expectation, parental education is robustly associated with investing more in each of fewer children (Skirbekk, Reference Skirbekk2008).

Even something as apparently simple as parental wealth may reflect both parental economic capacity and market opportunities available to their children. For example, asset-based wealth measures commonly used in large demographic datasets most commonly reflect the kinds of assets that can be accumulated with cash and engagement in market economies (e.g. TVs, cell phones, concrete walls, tin roofs; Bingenheimer, Reference Bingenheimer2007; Hruschka, Hadley, & Hackman, Reference Hruschka, Hadley and Hackman2017; Rutstein & Johnson, Reference Rutstein and Johnson2004). As such, these measures reflect the outcome of a history of engagement in specific types of economic production and exposure to distinct suites of opportunities to accumulate different sorts of material assets and manage reproduction. For this reason, these measures of material wealth reflect not only the economic capacity of a household, but also the extent to which households are exposed to, and can capitalise on, market opportunities.

In contrast to a one-dimensional model of material wealth, a multidimensional model of wealth suggests that different asset-based indicators of wealth reflect not only the economic capacity of a household, but also a proxy for engagement in different types of economic production. Engagement in these distinct dimensions may create suites of opportunities and constraints for households that are not captured in one-dimensional approaches to estimating material wealth. These opportunities and constraints are particularly important for understanding the nature of the reversals between wealth and fertility. For example, success in the agricultural economy requires that parents make very different decisions regarding investments in human capital compared with households engaged in the livelihoods grounded in the cash economy. The returns to investments in education and to reduced fertility may vary widely when households are predominantly engaged in professional wage-labour vs. predominantly agricultural production (Hedges et al., Reference Hedges, Borgerhoff Mulder, James and Lawson2016).

To address this concern, recent studies have focused on agricultural measures of material wealth and the effects on fertility, particularly in mixed economies where traditional livelihoods exist alongside market opportunities (Colleran et al., Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2015; Garenne, Reference Garenne2015). In previous work, Colleran has pointed to the need to include multiple forms of wealth, particularly traditional and market-based, as a means of disentangling economic capacity and engagement in the market economy. Indeed, in her study of farming communities in rural Poland she includes measures of both farming and non-farming wealth, based on ownership of different suites of assets. Furthermore, she used independent indicators of market integration using employment status and occupation categories. The ability to capture more direct measures of ‘traditional’ and ‘modern’ wealth is a strength of using primary data in small-scale or regional studies. However, these studies tell us little about the effects across a broader range of global contexts. To better understand the process of demographic change in the contexts of market integration, the changes in the importance of different types of material wealth and the suites of opportunities that accompany economic development, we need comparative data.

The current study

The current study proposes and tests a method for parsing the effects of economic capacity from market opportunities using multiple measures of wealth. To do so, we treat economic capacity and market opportunities as underlying latent traits, which are partially captured by measures of education and wealth along different dimensions (Figure 2). We assume that both market-based wealth and educational attainment to some extent reflect a history of the market opportunities available to a household. Similarly, we expect market-based wealth and agricultural-based wealth to both reflect the economic capacity of a household. Using multiple empirical measures to estimate economic capacity and market opportunities as latent variables permits a more direct test of the links between fertility and what anthropologists consider wealth and status.

Figure 2. Latent variable model estimating economic capacity and market opportunities.

We use this approach on a large database of demographic and health monitoring surveys from low- and middle-income countries worldwide to assess the overall effect of economic capacity and market opportunities on fertility. These surveys have the advantage of containing information about both cash economy market wealth (e.g. TVs, cars) and agricultural wealth (e.g. land and livestock) (Garenne, Reference Garenne2015; Hackman, Hruschka, & Vizireanu, Reference Hackman, Hruschka and Vizireanu2020; Hruschka et al., Reference Hruschka, Hadley and Hackman2017). Using both measures of wealth in a latent variable structural equation model, we estimate how agricultural and market-based wealth reflect economic capacity, and how education and market wealth reflect market opportunities. The modelling approach permits estimation of (a) the economic capacity and market opportunities as independent latent variables and (b) their overall effect on fertility outcomes across a broad range of populations currently undergoing transitions to low fertility.

Data and methods

Data and general approach

We analyse data from 151 Demographic and Health surveys (DHS, 1989–2016). The DHS are nationally representative surveys that collect data in low- and middle-income countries. Most DHS surveys contain detailed information on reproduction for women aged 15–49 as well as household economic status. We use available data from 64 countries with reliable estimates of market and agricultural dimensions of wealth (Hackman et al., Reference Hackman, Hruschka and Vizireanu2020) and data on completed fertility for women aged 40–50 (562,324 women, across 111,724 sampling clusters; Figure S1 and Table S1 in the Supporting Information). The surveys reflect populations in Europe and Central Asia (n = 11), South Asia and Oceania (n = 10), sub-Saharan Africa (n = 92), the Middle East and North Africa (n = 5), Southeast Asia (n = 16) and Latin America and the Caribbean (n = 17). Given that the nature and meaning of wealth may vary across contexts with different suites of social and economic opportunities for pursuing different livelihoods, we also conduct analyses stratified by urban vs. rural residence. Sample sizes varied across the 151 surveys, ranging from a low of n = 322 for Malawi 2012 to a high of n = 149,295 for India 2015.

Measures

Wealth indices

We follow the procedure outlined in prior publications to estimate orthogonal measures of market-based and agricultural wealth using multiple correspondence analysis (MCA) (Hackman et al., Reference Hackman, Hruschka and Vizireanu2020; Hruschka et al., Reference Hruschka, Hadley and Hackman2017). Household-level wealth dimensions were computed for each survey independently, as the MCA provides estimates of relative ranking of households based on similar asset ownerships within the population, but is not strictly comparable across surveys. Variables used to estimate the dimensions included source of drinking water, electricity, wall, roof and floor construction material, sanitation, cooking fuels and material asset ownership like bikes, radios, televisions and cell phones. Household holdings of land and livestock (e.g. cattle, cows, sheep, chickens, horses, goats and country-specific animals) were also included. The MCA produced two wealth dimensions that had clear interpretations of reflecting either the market economy or the agricultural sector when validated against agricultural indicators (e.g. livestock, and land) and market-oriented goods (e.g. TVs, cars) (Hackman et al., Reference Hackman, Hruschka and Vizireanu2020). These dimensions are scaled to have a mean standard deviation (SD) of 1 within surveys. We excluded seven (of 158 total) surveys that had a low internal reliability of the agricultural wealth dimension (Cronbach's α< 0.6, see Figure S8 for distribution). A rule-of-thumb threshold for acceptable reliability is typically 0.7, as lower α scores suggest that the wealth dimension is not sufficiently reliable to warrant a clear interpretation. The MCA produces a ranking of households along each dimension for all households included in that survey. In other words, the indices produce a survey-level relative ranking of households along each of two wealth dimensions. For example, a household that owns neither land or livestock would be ranked relatively low on the agricultural wealth dimension. Notably, in the low- and middle-income countries considered here, many urban households own agricultural assets, and many rural households own no agricultural assets. Thus, one frequently finds urban households having higher agricultural wealth dimensions than rural households.

Education

We use number of years of education which ranged from 0 to 15 across all surveys (Snopkowski, Towner, Shenk, & Colleran, Reference Snopkowski, Towner, Shenk and Colleran2016).

Total fertility

We used total children ever born for all women aged 40–50 years old. Survey average completed family size ranged from a low of 1.8 in Ukraine 2007 and 2.3 in Moldova 2005 to a high of 7.6 in Niger 2012 and 7.5 in Chad 2015 (Table S1). Across all surveys the mean total fertility was 5.2 (SD = 1.3, range between 5 and 95% percentiles 2.9–7.1). The distributions of survey-level fertility and fertility variance are reported in Figure S7.

Centering on sampling cluster

To assess the local, relative effects of both measures of wealth, we centre each household's measures of wealth, fertility and education relative to the local cluster mean. The sampling cluster is the lowest level of geographic scale in the DHS sampling strategy. Clusters reflect sampling units that represent about 20–50 households that are in relatively close proximity to each other (mean 43.9, SD = 91.7). Some 95% of the primary sampling units (PSUs) have between 1 and 80 individuals represented in the dataset, despite the range realistically going as high as 776. To facilitate centring, we exclude 317 sampling clusters with N = 1.

This centring permits estimation of a household's economic position relative to the community mean rather than the country (Colleran & Snopkowski, Reference Colleran and Snopkowski2018). This is the level at which we would expect to observe the strongest effects of resources and opportunities on fertility (Gibson & Lawson, Reference Gibson and Lawson2011; Nettle & Pollet, Reference Nettle and Pollet2008). It is precisely in these local contexts where the distributions of opportunities and resources shape what economic pathways are feasible. Furthermore, local social contexts provide the suite of behavioural strategies deemed acceptable behaviour (Bachrach & Morgan, Reference Bachrach and Morgan2013; Colleran et al., Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2014; Johnson-Hanks, Bachrach, Morgan, & Kohler, Reference Johnson-Hanks, Bachrach, Morgan and Kohler2011). Centring all measures at the cluster level permits estimation of the relative effects of wealth and education on fertility while holding community-level differences constant.

Analyses

To test whether market-based wealth measures conflate economic capacity and market opportunities, we employ a latent variable structural regression model (Kline, Reference Kline2015). In the model, we use market wealth, agricultural wealth, and education to estimate two latent factors – economic capacity and market opportunities – which are then regressed on relative fertility (see Figure 2). This model aims to disentangle the effects of market opportunities from economic capacity in standard asset-based wealth measures. Thus, it provides a first approximation of the relative magnitude of the positive effects of economic capacity on fertility relative to the negative effects of market opportunities.

We estimate a total of four structural equation models (SEM). We first run the model on the full sample, without accounting for population differences. We then stratify this model by urban and rural residence to assess how the effects of economic capacity and market opportunities might vary across broad contexts. Finally, we estimate the full model for each population in the sample using multigroup specification. The multigroup SEM runs an independent model for each survey, producing both a survey-specific estimate and an average estimate of the effect. We examine the sign and magnitude of the regression parameters in the structural model for each population to assess whether economic capacity and market opportunities are associated with relative fertility in the predicted directions. We expect a positive effect of economic capacity on fertility while market opportunities should have a negative effect.

The results of the measurement submodel – the part of the model estimating the latent variables from the measures of wealth and education – are presented as the fully standardised solution (the standardized beta coefficient β) in Table 1. This allows for interpreting the factor loading coefficients on each latent variable as standardised regression coefficients, which permits comparisons within and between models on a similar metric. This standardised solution allows for a clearer interpretation of the factor loadings on the latent variables, whereas, for the structural submodel, the coefficients are presented as the unstandardised coefficients. In contrast to the measurement portion of the model, the unstandardised coefficients have a meaningful interpretation – a standard deviation increase in the latent variable reflects the average increase in number of children relative to the community mean.

Table 1. Results of the SEM models

a The multigroup specification presents the coefficients averaged across all individual survey models.

For each of the SEM models, we assess model fit using a number of model fit indices. We use the standard χ 2 test to assess model fit; however, this test becomes less reliable with large samples, and very small discrepancies can result in failing this model test (Kenny, Reference Kenny2014). We also report the RMSEA, which is a widely used measure of model fit and is relatively invariant to large increases in sample sizes. The RMSEA has standard thresholds of less than 0.05 for a good fit (Kline, Reference Kline2015). Finally, we include the comparative fit index (CFI), which compares the model fit with the null model, and has standard threshold cutoffs of greater than 0.95 as indicating good fit (Schreiber, Reference Schreiber, Nora, Stage, Barlow and King2006).

In SEM models, estimating a latent variable requires a factor loading to be fixed in order to scale the latent variables (Kenny, Reference Kenny2014). We fix the factor loadings of agricultural wealth as the indicator for economic capacity, and education as the indicator for market opportunities. For the full model and urban–rural stratified models, we fix the factor loadings to 0.5, which scales the latent variable variance to the units of the indicator variable. For example, a 0.5 increase in the Agricultural Wealth Index is associated with a 1 SD increase in economic capacity. However, our multigroup model was sensitive to the fixed values of the indicator variables, and convergence issues occurred when setting values to 0.5. Running a multigroup SEM across 151 different surveys with standard fixed factor loadings can result in convergence issues, particularly with a measurement submodel that has relatively few indicators. Most prominent are Heywood cases, where estimated variances are negative. Fixing both indicator factor loadings to 0.5 produced 32% significant negative variance cases across all 151 studies. Rescaling the latent variables by setting one of the reference indicators (education attainment) to 0.35 rather than the standard 0.5 resulted in only 2% of cases having significant negative variances. Here we report results of the multigroup model with the fixed indicator set to 0.35. A sensitivity analysis shows that changing the fixed indicator values had little effect on estimated model parameters (Figures S4 and S5).

Results

Model estimation and model fit

The results of the four SEM models are presented in Table 1 and Figure 3. The χ 2 test was significant, indicating a poor fit for all models; however, this is probably the result of large sample size capturing small differences (Kenny, Reference Kenny2014). Assessment of model fit, using measures less sensitive to sample size, showed acceptable fits for all models. The full model showed good fit across all indices [RMSEA = 0.038, 95% CI = (0.037–0.039), CFI = 0.97]. The urban model similarly showed good fit across all indices [RMSEA = 0.03, 95% CI = (0.030–0.034), CFI = 0.99], while the rural sample model showed acceptable fit [RMSEA = 0.05, 95% CI = (0.049–0.052), CFI = 0.93]. Finally, the aggregate fit indices for the multigroup showed acceptable fit with RMSEA = 0.058, 95% CI = (0.056–0.059) and good fit with CFI = 0.95. Taken together, the four models fit the data well, with the unstratified and urban models showing the greatest fit.

Figure 3. Unstandardised SEM results for the full sample SEM model.

The measurement submodel: estimating the latent variables

Full sample

In the full sample, both agricultural wealth (standard β = 0.61, p < 0.001) and market-based wealth (standard β = 0.20, p < 0.001) load positively on the latent variable economic capacity (Table 1). While the MCA produces orthogonal dimensions, when clustering at community-levels these two dimensions show a small positive association (r = 0.19, p < 0.001). The factor loading for agricultural wealth on economic capacity is three times higher than the factor loading for market wealth on economic capacity. Both education and market wealth had positive and significant loadings on market opportunities (market wealth standard β = 0.38, p < 0.001 and education standard β = 0.80, p < 0.001). Finally, economic capacity was positively associated with market opportunities (standard β = 0.27, p < 0.001).

Urban vs. rural sample

The urban and rural stratified results were qualitatively similar to the full unstratified model, with a few exceptions. First, factor loadings of market wealth on economic capacity, were weaker in rural settings (standard β = 0.09, p < 0.001) than in urban settings (standard β = 0.38, p < 0.001). Second, the associations between the latent variables, economic capacity and market opportunities were weaker in rural settings (standard β = 0.21, p < 0.001) than in urban settings (standard β = 0.38, p < 0.001).

Multigroup sample

In the multigroup sample both market wealth (standard β = 0.16, p < 0.001) and agricultural wealth (standard β = 0.61, p < 0.001) loaded positively on economic capacity, while market wealth (standard β = 0.34, p < 0.001) and education (standard β = 0.77, p < 0.001) loaded positively on market opportunities. The average association between the economic capacity and market opportunities was also positive and significant (standard β = 0.30, p < 0.001).

The structural submodel: predicting fertility by economic capacity and market opportunities

In the full sample model, a 1 SD increase in the Economic Capacity latent variable was associated with a small but significant increase in fertility (β = 0.13. 95% CI = (0.12–0.14), p < 0.001). Similar effects were observed in the urban and rural models [urban β = 0.17, 95% CI = (0.15–0.18), p < 0.001, rural β = 0.17, 95% CI = (0.15–0.18), p < 0.001], while the mean effect was slightly larger in the multigroup models (mean β = 0.21). These estimates correspond to approximately 0.50–0.85 more children for women in households with 4 SD greater economic capacity.

In contrast, market opportunities showed strong negative effects on fertility in all models. A 4 SD increase in market opportunities was associated with a decline of approximately two children in both the full model [β = −0.53, 95% CI = (−0.54 to −0.52), p < 0.001] and the multigroup model (mean β = −0.60, p < 0.001). The effect of market opportunities on fertility was weaker in the rural sample [rural β = −0.39, 95% CI = (−0.40 to −0.38), p < 0.001] than in the urban sample [urban β = −0.76, 95% CI = (−0.77 to −0.74), p < 0.001]. The ratio of the effects of both latent variables on fertility shows that the positive effects of economic capacity ranged from one-fifth the size of the negative effect of market opportunities in urban settings, to over one-third the size in rural settings.

Multigroup SEM results

The effects of market opportunities and economic capacity on fertility across surveys and countries showed substantial variation (Figures 4 and 5). Overall, market opportunities had a consistent negative effect on fertility across 99.3% of the 151 surveys included in the model. In contrast, economic capacity had an average positive effect, with 87.4% positive. The remaining 12.6% showed null effects of economic capacity (See Figure S3). The effects of market opportunities showed a range of variation across countries with the 5–95% percentile of the distribution between −0.06 and −0.52. The effects of economic capacity similarly showed a range of variation, with the 5–95% range of the distribution from −0.03 to 0.33.

Figure 4. Distribution of effects of latent variables on fertility.

Figure 5. Distribution of effects of latent variables on fertility across survey waves. The top panel shows the effects of economic capacity on fertility for multiple survey waves within a country. The effects were largely positive with within countries across survey waves. The bottom panel shows that the effects of market opportunities were similarly consistent within countries across survey waves. Countries are ordered by average completed fertility across all survey waves (Tables S1 and S7).

Discussion

These results suggest a new approach to assessing the associations between measured wealth and fertility found in populations undergoing fertility transitions. Rather than capturing fertility differences between households with different levels of economic resources, these associations are capturing households that vary not just in terms of their economic capacity, but also in their access to market opportunities needed to turn high-cost investments into greater socioeconomic success. Furthermore, when accounting for variation in market opportunities, households with greater economic capacity still tend to have relatively higher fertility than households with less economic capacity. This suggests that many of the puzzling associations between wealth and fertility may reflect the inability of current approaches to properly disentangle market opportunities and economic capacity. Indeed, the majority of economic and evolutionary theories of low fertility point to the influence of modern competitive wage labour economies as the primary driver of fertility declines. However, as market economies develop and take hold in a population, households vary in their ability to access and take advantage of novel economic opportunities offered by expanding markets. Households with greater opportunities to turn costly investments in education into greater socioeconomic success are more likely to engage in a low-fertility, high-investment strategy.

This exercise in disentangling economic capacity and market opportunities permits a more direct test of the importance of theoretically relevant constructs, such as market opportunities and economic capacity. For standard asset-based wealth measures used in demographic and health surveys, the bias towards market-oriented goods and services means that the measure tracks not only household economic capacity but also serves as a proxy for market opportunities. And if the effects of market opportunities are much larger than the effects of economic capacity (as observed here), then commonly used asset-based measures may tell us comparatively little about economic capacity. When these wealth measures are treated uncritically as simply reflecting economic capacity, they can limit our ability to draw inferences about how economic resources shape reproductive outcomes.

Returning to the theoretical model, the positive association between economic capacity and fertility tells us little about why the links between offspring socioeconomic success (E) and offspring reproductive success (F) are broken or breaking in contemporary societies. In the past offspring quality and socioeconomic status may have served as reliable proxies for the ultimate aim of reproductive success (G). However, in contemporary societies, such proxy relationships can become broken, leading to investments in wealth and status accumulation that do not have associated fitness payoffs (Goodman et al., Reference Goodman, Koupil and Lawson2012). Rather than arguing that parental investments are adaptive in these contexts, the model proposes that parents are paying attention to more proximate cues, and may be wholly unaware of the downstream links.

The results also open new questions about how fertility responds to economic development over the course of the fertility transition. For example, what accounts for the considerable cross-national variation in the effects of economic capacity and market opportunities? Potential factors shaping this variation include cultural history, ethnic and economic heterogeneity, the diversity of agricultural livelihoods and their opportunity costs associated with engaging in wage-labour production. Additionally, our approach can be extended to refine operationalisation of other key concepts in theoretical models of fertility. For example, education is often treated as a proxy for status in evolutionary demography (Colleran & Snopkowski, Reference Colleran and Snopkowski2018), although recently the effects of education on fertility have been considered multidimensional, capturing more than simply access to resources (Martin & Juarez, Reference Martin and Juarez1995), such as exposure to modern low-fertility norms (Colleran et al., Reference Colleran, Jasienska, Nenko, Galbarczyk and Mace2014), knowledge and ability to control reproduction (Cleland & Kaufmann, Reference Cleland and Kaufmann2002; Jayne & Jejeebhoy, Reference Jayne and Jejeebhoy1997; Peña, Wall, & Persson, Reference Peña, Wall and Persson2000). Indeed, education seems to have a robust negative effect on fertility although the mechanisms appear to be context specific (Snopkowski et al., Reference Snopkowski, Towner, Shenk and Colleran2016). Latent variable analyses may be one means of disentangling these multidimensional effects.

There are a number of important limitations and caveats to interpreting these structural regression models. Primarily, there is a need for additional indicators for the latent variables in order to fully assess the constructs in the measurement model. Our ability to estimate the latent variables rests on the covariance structures in the indicator variables. Here that is the covariance between market-based wealth, and agricultural wealth and education independently. Using only two indicator variables for each latent construct resulted in a relatively unstable model. For example, the SEM model fared worse in rural settings, with relatively poorer scores on model fit indices than in urban settings. One reason for this could be that the low covariance between the indicator variables in rural settings results in poor measurement. The lower covariance between the indicator variables could reflect greater variation in the nature and meaning of the wealth measures, or it could reflect contexts where success along one dimension is not easily transferred to success along another. Without a significant amount of shared variance, it is difficult to estimate reliable latent variables. Another possibility is that the two wealth measures are truly orthogonal and reflect that in many contexts success along one dimension carries steep trade-offs with success along another dimension. To assess these two possibilities, we need more empirical indicators of market opportunities and economic capacity. Two important candidates to include in future work are occupation types and employment status of individuals and heads-of-households. Similar to stocks of assets, these directly reflect a household's engagement with wage-labour employment and also proxy a household's access to competitive labour economies. While the DHS surveys do collect data on occupation and employment, the types of occupations available and their meaning across contexts can vary significantly. Alternatively, future research could use a subset of the underlying asset variables to create the latent variables, rather than the dimension scores produced from the MCA. However, the creation of the MCA dimensions and the process of anchoring the dimensions facilitate a clear interpretation (Hackman et al., Reference Hackman, Hruschka and Vizireanu2020; Hruschka et al., Reference Hruschka, Hadley and Hackman2017). Estimating the latent variables using the raw assets would require an independent method of validating the interpretation of the latent variables. Finally, we would ideally model urban and rural contexts separately within a given survey (see Figure S10). However, the small number of observations in these highly stratified samples led to convergence issues for a substantial portion of samples (30%). Future work on larger samples should permit a clearer understanding of how the effects of wealth on fertility vary across rural contexts in different countries.

Another potential concern is that the positive effects of economic capacity on fertility are largely driven by urban households who are highly integrated into the market economy and also have low agricultural wealth and low fertility. These households might also have low scores on economic capacity owing to their having little or no agricultural wealth, which would create an artificial positive association between economic capacity and fertility. This is an unlikely explanation for several reasons. First, the positive associations of economic capacity and fertility are observed in both rural and urban samples. Second, the correlation between market-based wealth and agricultural wealth is positive in urban settings (not negative) and the covariance between the latent variables economic capacity and market opportunities is positive (Table 1). This shows that urbanites who are poor on agricultural wealth are often poor on market-based wealth as well and that both contribute to low economic capacity and low market opportunities. Additionally, we conducted a sensitivity analyses on the urban subsample, excluding households who were in the bottom 25% of agricultural wealth and the top 25% of market-based wealth. The results were qualitatively similar to those presented in Table 1 (Table S8).

Our results highlight the need to estimate multiple, varying forms of wealth and status in order to disentangle the effects of market opportunities from economic capacity. While anthropologists have focused on estimating multiple forms of wealth and status in community studies, this is difficult in the large secondary datasets often used in evolutionary demography. Our method draws on recent changes to demographic and health monitoring surveys where data on livestock, land and other agricultural assets are used to estimate measures of wealth that track economic capacity independent of market opportunities. Using multiple measures of wealth, we were able to estimate the independent effects of economic capacity and market opportunities on relative fertility. We showed that across a broad range of contexts, economic capacity typically has a positive association with fertility. However, this positive association appears to be masked by a strong, negative association between fertility and a household's engagement in the market economy. Accounting for household-level variation in market opportunities and relying on multiple measures of household economic capacity are key steps to testing and refining theories about how households make reproductive and parental investment decisions both within and between populations.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2020.62

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Jonathan Maupin, Kim Hill, for guidance and support in completing this project. Thanks also go to Leo Tiokhin, Andrew Bishop, Alexandria Drake and students in the Laboratory of Culture Change and Behavior for feedback and support.

Author contributions

All authors contributed equally to the manuscript.

Financial support

DJH acknowledges support from the National Science Foundation grant BCS-1150813, jointly funded by Programs in Cultural Anthropology, Social Psychology Program and Decision, Risk, and Management Sciences, and BCS-1658766, jointly funded by Programs in Cultural Anthropology and Methodology, Measurement and Statistics, and support from the Virginia G Piper Charitable Trust through an award to Mayo Clinic/ASU Obesity Solutions. The funder had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish or preparation of the manuscript. JH would like to acknowledge support from ASU's School of Human Evolution and Social Change Graduate Completion Fellowship.

Conflicts of interest

JH and DH declare no conflicts of interest.

Research transparency and reproducibility

The data used for this study are publicly available from the DHS Program (https://www.dhsprogram.com/).

References

Alvergne, A., & Lummaa, V. (2014). Ecological variation in wealth–fertility relationships in Mongolia: The ‘central theoretical problem of sociobiology’ not a problem after all? Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 281(1796). https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2014.1733Google ScholarPubMed
Bachrach, C. A., & Morgan, S. P. (2013). A cognitive–social model of fertility intentions. Population and Development Review, 39(3), 459485. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2013.00612.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Becker, G., Murphy, K., & Tamura, R. (1990). Human capital, fertility, and economic growth chapter. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5, Part 2), S12S37. https://doi.org/10.1086/261723CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bingenheimer, J. B. (2007). Wealth, wealth indices and HIV risk in East Africa. International Family Planning Perspectives, 33(2), 8384. https://doi.org/10.1363/3308307CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boone, J. L., & Kessler, K. L. (1999). More status or more children? Social status, fertility reduction, and long-term fitness Evolution and Human Behavior, 20(4), 257277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borgerhoff Mulder, M. (1998). The demographic transition: Are we any closer to an evolutionary explanation? Trends in Ecology and Evolution. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0169-5347(98)01357-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borgerhoff Mulder, M., & Beheim, B. A. (2011). Understanding the nature of wealth and its effects on human fitness. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 366(1563), 344356. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2010.0231CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press. https://doi.org/10.1097/00005053-198702000-00018Google Scholar
Cleland, J., & Kaufmann, G. L. (2002). Education, fertility and child survival: Unravelling the links. In The methods and uses of anthropological demography (pp. 128152). Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital social capital in the creation of human capital. Source: American Journal of Sociology, 94, 95120. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/2780243Google Scholar
Colleran, H., Jasienska, G., Nenko, I., Galbarczyk, A., & Mace, R. (2014). Community-level education accelerates the cultural evolution of fertility decline. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 281(1779), 20132732. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2013.2732Google ScholarPubMed
Colleran, H., Jasienska, G., Nenko, I., Galbarczyk, A., & Mace, R. (2015). Fertility decline and the changing dynamics of wealth, status and inequality. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 282(1806), 20150287. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2015.0287Google ScholarPubMed
Colleran, H., & Snopkowski, K. (2018). Variation in wealth and educational drivers of fertility decline across 45 countries. Population Ecology, 60(1), 115. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10144-018-0626-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cronk, L. (1991). Wealth, status, and reproductive success among the Mukogodo of Kenya. American Anthropologist, 93(2), 345360. https://doi.org/10.1525/aa.1991.93.2.02a00040CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flinn, M. (1986). Correlates of reproductive success in a Caribbean village. Human Ecology, 14(2), 225243. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00889239CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garenne, M. (2015). Traditional wealth, modern goods, and demographic behavior in rural Senegal. World Development, 72, 267276. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.03.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibson, M. A., & Lawson, D. (2011). ‘Modernization’ increases parental investment and sibling resource competition: Evidence from a rural development initiative in Ethiopia. Evolution and Human Behavior, 32(2), 97105. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2010.10.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman, A., Koupil, I., & Lawson, D. (2012). Low fertility increases descendant socioeconomic position but reduces long-term fitness in a modern post-industrial society. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 279(1746), 43424351. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2012.1415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hackman, J., Hruschka, D., & Vizireanu, M. (2020). An agricultural wealth index for multidimensional wealth assessments. Population and Development Review, padr.12367. https://doi.org/10.1111/padr.12367CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handwerker, W. P. (1986). The modern demographic transition: An analysis of subsistence choices and reproductive consequences. American Anthropologist, 88(2), 400417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hedges, S., Borgerhoff Mulder, M., James, S., & Lawson, D. (2016). Sending children to school: Rural livelihoods and parental investment in education in northern Tanzania. Evolution and Human Behavior, 37(2), 142151. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.10.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, S. E., & Reeve, H. K. (2005). Low fertility in humans as the evolutionary outcome of snowballing resource games. Behavioral Ecology, 16(2), 398402. https://doi.org/10.1093/beheco/ari001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopcroft, R. L. (2006). Sex, status, and reproductive success in the contemporary United States. Evolution and Human Behavior, 27(2), 104120. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2005.07.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hruschka, D., & Burger, O.. (2016). How does variance in fertility change over the demographic transition? Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 371(1692), 20150155. Retrieved from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/doi/10.1098/rstb.2015.0155.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hruschka, D., Hadley, C., & Hackman, J. (2017). Material wealth in 3D: Mapping multiple paths to prosperity in low- and middle- income countries. PLoS ONE, 12(9), e0184616. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0184616CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hruschka, D., Sear, R., Hackman, J., & Drake, A. (2019). Worldwide fertility declines do not rely on stopping at ideal parities. Population Studies, 73(1), 117. https://doi.org/10.1080/00324728.2018.1513164CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubback, J. (1957). Wives who went to college. Heinemann.Google Scholar
Irons, W. (1983). Human female reproductive strategies. In Social behavior of female vertebtrates (pp. 169213). Academic Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jayne, S., & Jejeebhoy, S. (1997). Women's education, autonomy and reproductive behaviour: Experience from developing countries. Studies in Family Planning, 28(1), 72. https://doi.org/10.2307/2137974CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson-Hanks, J. A., Bachrach, C. A., Morgan, S. P., & Kohler, H.-P. (2011). The theory of conjunctural action. In Understanding Family Change and Variation (pp. 122). Springer Netherlands. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-1945-3_1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, H. (1996). A theory of fertility and parental investment in traditional and modern human societies. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 101(S23), 91135. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1096-8644(1996)23+<91::AID-AJPA4>3.0.CO;2-C3.0.CO;2-C>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, H., Hill, K., Lancaster, J., & Hurtado, M. (2000). A theory of human life history evolution: diet, intelligence, and longevity. Evolutionary Anthropology, 9(4), 156185.3.0.CO;2-7>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, H., & Lancaster, J. (2000). The evolutionary economics and psychology of the demographic transition to low fertility. In Adaptation and Human Behavior: An Anthropological Perspective (pp. 283322). Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Kaplan, H., Lancaster, J., Johnson, S., & Bock, J. (1995). Does observed fertility maximize fitness among new mexican men. Human Nature, 6(4), 325360. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02734205CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kaplan, H., Lancaster, J. B., Tucker, W. T., & Anderson, K. G. (2002). Evolutionary approach to below replacement fertility. American Journal of Human Biology, 14(2), 233256. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajhb.10041CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kenny, D. (2014). Structural equation modelling. Retrieved March 18, 2019, from http://davidakenny.net/cm/causalm.htmGoogle Scholar
Kline, R. B. (2015). Principles and practice of structural equation modelling (3rd ed.). The Guilford Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107415324.004Google Scholar
Lam, D. (1986). The dynamics of population growth, differential fertility, and inequality. The American Economic Review, 76. https://doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/stable/1816471Google Scholar
Lawson, D., Alvergne, A., & Gibson, M. A. (2012). The life-history trade-off between fertility and child survival. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 279(1748), 47554764. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2012.1635CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lawson, D., & Mace, R. (2011). Parental investment and the optimization of human family size. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B, Biological Sciences, 366(1563), 333343. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2010.0297CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lawson, D., & Mulder, M. B. (2016). The offspring quantity–quality trade-off and human fertility variation. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 371(1692). https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0145CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Livi-Bacci, M. (1986). Social-group forerunners of fertility control in Europe. In The decline of fertility in Europe (pp. 182200). Princeton University Press. Retrieved from https://www.popline.org/node/345317Google Scholar
Low, B. S., Simon, C. P., & Anderson, K. G. (2002). An evolutionary ecological perspective on demographic transitions: Modeling multiple currencies. American Journal of Human Biology: The Official Journal of the Human Biology Council, 14(2), 149167. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajhb.10043CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lutz, W., & KC, S. (2011). Global human capital: Integrating education and population. Science, 333(6042), 587592. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1206964CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mace, R. (1996). When to have another baby: A dynamic model of reproductive decision-making and evidence from gabbra pastoralists. Ethology and Sociobiology, 17(4), 263273. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162-3095(96)00044-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mace, R. (1998). The coevolution of human fertility and wealth inheritance strategies. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 353(1367), 389397. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.1998.0217CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mace, R. (2008). Reproducing in cities. Science, 319(5864), 764766. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1153960CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Martin, T. C., & Juarez, F. (1995). The impact of women's education on fertility in Latin America: Searching for explanations. International Family Planning Perspectives, 21(2), 52. https://doi.org/10.2307/2133523Google Scholar
Matthews, R., Pendakur, R., & Young, N. (2009). Social capital, labour markets, and job-finding in urban and rural regions: Comparing paths to employment in prosperous cities and stressed rural communities in Canada. Sociological Review, 57(2), 306330. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-954X.2009.01831.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattison, S., & Neill, D. B. (2013). The effects of residential ecology on patterns of child work and mother's reproductive success among Indo-Fijians. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34(3), 207215. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2013.01.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAllister, L., Gurven, M., Kaplan, H., & Stieglitz, J. (2012). Why do women have more children than they want? Understanding differences in women's ideal and actual family size in a natural fertility population. American Journal of Human Biology, 24(6), 786799. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajhb.22316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myrskylä, M., Kohler, H. P., & Billari, F. C. (2009). Advances in development reverse fertility declines. Nature, 460(7256), 741743. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature08230CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Neill, D. (2010). Expanding opportunity structures: Parental investments in education, migration, and extrinsic risk reduction among Indo-Fijians. Human Nature, 21(2), 165185. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-010-9086-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nettle, D., & Pollet, T. V. (2008). Natural selection on male wealth in humans. The American Naturalist, 172(5), 658666. https://doi.org/10.1086/591690CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Newson, L., Postmes, T., Lea, S. E. G., & Webley, P. (2005). Why are modern families small? Toward an evolutionary and cultural explanation for the demographic transition. Personality and social psychology review, 9(4), 360375.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Patrinos, H. A. (2000). The cost of discrimination in Latin America. Studies in Comparative International Development, 35(2), 317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patrinos, H. A., & Psacharopoulos, G. (1997). Family size, schooling and child labor in Peru – An empirical analysis. Journal of Population Economics, 10(4), 387405. https://doi.org/10.1007/s001480050050CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Peña, R., Wall, S., & Persson, L. Å. (2000). The effect of poverty, social inequity, and maternal education on infant mortality in Nicaragua, 1988–1993. American Journal of Public Health, 90(1), 6469. https://doi.org/10.2105/AJPH.90.1.64Google ScholarPubMed
Pérusse, D. (1993). Cultural and reproductive success in industrial societies: Testing the relationship at the proximate and ultimate levels. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 16(2), 267283. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X00029939CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Portes, A., & Landolt, P. (1998). Social capital: Promise and pitfalls of its role in development. Journal of Latin American Studies, 32(2), 529547. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022216X00005836CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Retherford, R. D. (1986). Demographic transition and the evolution of intelligence: Theory and evidence. Honolulu Hawaii East–West Population Institute East–West Center. Retrieved from https://www.popline.org/node/345563Google Scholar
Richerson, P. J., & Boyd, R. (2005). Not by genes alone. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Rogers, A. R. (1990). Evolutionary economics of human reproduction. Ethology and Sociobiology, 11(6), 479495. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162-3095(90)90022-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutstein, S. O., & Johnson, K. (2004). The DHS wealth index (DHS Comparative Reports no. 6). https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107415324.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schreiber, J. B., Nora, A, Stage, F.K., Barlow, E.A, & King, J. (2006). Reporting structural equation modeling and confirmatory factor analysis results: A review. The Journal of educational research, 99(6), 323338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sear, R., Lawson, D., Kaplan, H., & Shenk, M. (2016). Understanding variation in human fertility: What can we learn from evolutionary demography? Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 371(1692), 20150144. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0144CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shenk, M. (2009). Testing three evolutionary models of the demographic transition: Patterns of fertility and age at marriage in urban South India. American Journal of Human Biology, 21(4), 501511. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajhb.20943CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shenk, M., Hooper, P., & Kaplan, H. (2016). Status competition, inequality, and fertility: Implications for the demographic transition. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 371(1692), 20150150. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0150CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Skirbekk, V. (2008). Fertility trends by social status. Demographic Research, 18, 145180. https://doi.org/10.4054/DemRes.2008.18.5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snopkowski, K., & Kaplan, H. (2014). A synthetic biosocial model of fertility transition: Testing the relative contribution of embodied capital theory, changing cultural norms, and women's labor force participation. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 154(3), 322333. https://doi.org/10.1002/ajpa.22512CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Snopkowski, K., Towner, M., Shenk, M., & Colleran, H. (2016). Pathways from education to fertility decline: A multi-site comparative study. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 371(1692), 112. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0156CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stulp, G., & Barrett, L. (2016). Wealth, fertility and adaptive behaviour in industrial populations. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 371(1692), 20150153. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0153CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stulp, G., Sear, R., & Barrett, L. (2016). The reproductive ecology of industrial societies, part I: Why measuring fertility matters. Human Nature, 27(4), 422444. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-016-9269-4CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stulp, G., Sear, R., Schaffnit, S. B., Mills, M. C., & Barrett, L. (2016). The reproductive ecology of industrial societies, part II. Human Nature, 27(4), 445470. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-016-9272-9CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Turke, P. W. (1989). Evolution and the demand for children. Population and Development Review, 15(1), 61. https://doi.org/10.2307/1973405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turke, P. W., & Betzig, L. L. (1985). Those who can do: Wealth, status, and reproductive success on Ifaluk. Ethology and Sociobiology, 6(2), 7987. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162-3095(85)90001-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vining, D. R. (1986). Social versus reproductive success: The central theoretical problem of human sociobiology. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 9(01), 167187. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X00021968CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Rueden, C. (2014). The roots and fruits of social status in small-scale human societies. In The psychology of social status (pp. 179200). Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4939-0867-7_9Google Scholar
von Rueden, C., Gurven, M., Kaplan, H., Rueden, C. Von, Gurven, M., … Kaplan, H. (2011). Why do men seek status? Fitness payoffs to dominance and prestige. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 278(1715), 22232232. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2010.2145CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figure 0

Figure 1. Theoretical model of the quality quantity trade-off.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Latent variable model estimating economic capacity and market opportunities.

Figure 2

Table 1. Results of the SEM models

Figure 3

Figure 3. Unstandardised SEM results for the full sample SEM model.

Figure 4

Figure 4. Distribution of effects of latent variables on fertility.

Figure 5

Figure 5. Distribution of effects of latent variables on fertility across survey waves. The top panel shows the effects of economic capacity on fertility for multiple survey waves within a country. The effects were largely positive with within countries across survey waves. The bottom panel shows that the effects of market opportunities were similarly consistent within countries across survey waves. Countries are ordered by average completed fertility across all survey waves (Tables S1 and S7).

Supplementary material: File

Hackman and Hruschka supplementary material

Hackman and Hruschka supplementary material

Download Hackman and Hruschka supplementary material(File)
File 778.4 KB