Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T05:33:32.151Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Balance of Power between Producers and Retailers: a Differentiation Model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Marie-Laure Allain*
Affiliation:
CNRS École Polytechnique et CREST**
Get access

Summary

This paper argues that the balance of power between producers and retailers depends on the relative degrees of differentiation at the two levels of the vertical structure. We propose an extension of Hotelling’s model in which two producers, competing in prices with horizontally differentiated products, face two horizontally differentiated retailers also competing in prices. We study the setting of producers’ and retailers’ margins. We show that when retailers are more differentiated than producers, they dominate the relationship and their margin is higher than producers’.

Résumé

Résumé

Cet article étudie l’impact des différenciations entre producteurs et entre distributeurs sur leurs rapports de force. On construit une extension du modèle d’Hotelling à deux dimensions dans lequel deux producteurs sont en concurrence à la Bertrand en produits différenciés horizontalement et font face à deux distributeurs différenciés horizontalement et eux aussi en concurrence à la Bertrand. On étudie l’influence des deux degrés de différenciation sur les marges des producteurs et des distributeurs, et on montre que lorsque les distributeurs sont plus différenciés que les producteurs, leurs marges sont plus importantes, et le rapport de force est en leur faveur.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2002 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

I thank Laurent Flochel, Anne Perrot, Bernard Salanié and two anonymous referees for their comments.

**

CNRS-Laboratoire d’Econométrie, École Polytechnique, 1 rue Descartes 75005 Paris (Tel: 33 1 55 55 85 41, E-Mail: [email protected]) et CREST-LEI.

References

Comanor, W. S. and Rey, P. (2000), “Vertical Restraints and the Market Power of Large Distributors”, Review of Industrial Organization, 17–2, 135153.Google Scholar
Dobson Consulting (1999), Buyer Power and its Impact on Competition in the Food Retail Distribution Sector of the European Union, report for the European Commission, publications of the European Commission.Google Scholar
Dobson, P. W. and Waterson, M. (1996), “Exclusive Trading Contracts in Successive Differentiated Duopoly”, Southern Economic Journal, 63–2, 361377.Google Scholar
Katz, M. L. (1989), “Vertical Contractual Relations”, in Handbook of Industrial Organization, Schmalensee, R. et Willig, R. éd., North-Holland.Google Scholar
Matutes, C. and Regibeau, P. (1988), “Mix and match: product compatibility without network externalities”, Rand Journal of Economics, 19–2, 221234.Google Scholar
Mills, D. (1995), “Why retailers sell private labels”, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 4–3, 509528.Google Scholar
O’Brien, D.P. and Shaffer, G. (1992), “Vertical Control with bilateral contracts”, Rand Journal of Economics, 22–3, 299308.Google Scholar
Rey, P. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1995), “The role of exclusive territories in producers’competition”, Rand Journal of Economics, 26–3, 431451.Google Scholar
Shaffer, G. (1991), “Slotting allowances and resale price maintenance: a comparison of facilitating practices”, Rand Journal of Economics, 22–1, 120135.Google Scholar
Steiner, R. L. (1985), “The nature of vertical restraints”, The Antitrust Bulletin, Spring 1985, 143197.Google Scholar