Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vsgnj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-21T06:42:50.290Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

CONSUMER DEMAND, CONSUMPTION, AND ASSET PRICING: AN INTEGRATED ANALYSIS WITH INTERTEMPORAL TWO-STAGE BUDGETING

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 July 2019

H. Youn Kim*
Affiliation:
Western Kentucky University
Keith R. Mclaren
Affiliation:
Monash University
K. K. Gary Wong
Affiliation:
The University of Macau
*
Address correspondence to: H. Youn Kim, Department of Economics, Western Kentucky University, Bowling Green, KY 42101, USA. e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This paper integrates seemingly disjoint studies on consumer behavior in micro and macroanalyses via an intertemporal two-stage budgeting procedure with durable goods and liquidity constraints. The model specifies an indirect utility function as a function of nondurable consumption, commodity (nondurables) prices, and durables stock, and derives the demand functions for nondurable goods. A demand function for durable goods is derived in an adjustment cost framework. The consumption growth equation accounts for relative price effects with precautionary saving, durables stock, and liquidity constraints. The stochastic discount factor is approximated by a time-varying linear function of nondurable consumption growth, commodity price growth, durables stock growth, and disposable income growth. The demand functions for six nondurable goods and services are jointly estimated with the Euler equations for bonds, stocks, and durable goods with allowance for liquidity constraints, using US data. Estimation provides new findings for intertemporal consumption and a multifactor consumption-based capital asset pricing model.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We would like to thank the Associate Editor (Apostolos Serletis) and two referees for their helpful comments and suggestions to improve the paper.

References

REFERENCES

Aguiar, M. and Hurst, E. (2013) Deconstructing life cycle expenditure. Journal of Political Economy 121, 437492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahn, S. C., Youn Kim, H., and Kang, T. H. (2017) Life-cycle consumption, precautionary saving, and risk sharing: An integrated analysis using household panel data. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 17(2), DOI: 10.1515/bejm-2016-0082.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alessie, R., Dsvereux, M. P. and Weber, G. (1997) Intertemporal consumption, durables, and liquidity constraints: A cohort analysis. European Economic Review 41, 3759.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, J. M., Carter, C. A., Green, R. and Pick, D. (1990) Whither Armington trade models. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72, 455467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attanasio, O. P. (1999) Consumption. In: Taylor, J. B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, pp. 741811. Amsterdam; Oxford: Elsevier Science.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attanasio, O. P. and Weber, G. (1995) Is consumption growth consistent with intertemporal optimization? Evidence from the consumer expenditure survey. Journal of Political Economy 103, 11211157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attfield, C. L. F. (1985) Homogeneity and endogeneity in systems of demand equations. Journal of Econometrics 27, 197209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azeredo, F. (2014) The equity premium: A deeper puzzle. Annals of Finance 10, 347373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, J., Blundell, R. and Lewbel, A. (1997) Quadratic Engel curves and consumer demand. Review of Economics and Statistics 79, 527539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. (2002) Tastes and technology: Curvature is not sufficient for regularity. Journal of Econometrics 108, 199202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A. and Serletis, A. (2008) Consumer preferences and demand systems. Journal of Econometrics 147, 210224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, W. A., Fisher, D. and Serletis, A. (1992) Consumer theory and the demand for money. Journal of Economic Literature 30, 20862119.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. (1985) Adjustment costs, durables, and aggregate consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics 15, 4168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blundell, R., Browning, M. and Meghir, C. (1994) Consumer demand and the life-cycle allocation of household expenditures. Review of Economic Studies 61, 5780.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldrin, M., Christiano, L. J. and Fisher, J. D.M. (2001) Habit persistence, asset returns, and the business cycle. American Economic Review 91, 149–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, M. (2005) A Working Paper from April 1985: Which demand elasticities do we know and which do we need to know for policy analysis? Research in Economics 59, 293320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, M., Crossley, T. F. and Luhrmann, M. (2016) Durable purchases over the later life cycle. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 78, 145169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, M., Deaton, A. and Irish, M. (1985) A profitable approach to labor supply and commodity demands over the life-cycle. Econometrica 55, 503544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, M. and Lusardi, A. (1996) Household saving: Micro theories and micro facts. Journal of Economic Literature 34, 17971855.Google Scholar
Browning, M. and Meghir, C. (1991) The effects of male and female labor supply on commodity demands. Econometrica 59, 925951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y. (1996) Understanding risk and return. Journal of Political Economy 104, 298345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y. and Cocco, J. F. (2007) How do house prices affect consumption? Evidence from micro data. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 591621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y. and Cochrane, J. H. (1999) By force of habit: A consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. Journal of Political Economy 107, 205251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y., Lo, A. W. and MacKinley, A. C. (1997) The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chah, E. Y., Ramey, V. A. and Starr, R. M. (1995) Liquidity constraints and intertemporal consumer optimization: Theory and evidence from durable goods. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, 272287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chirinko, R. S. (1993) Business fixed investment spending: Modeling strategies, empirical results, and policy implications. Journal of Economic Literature 31, 18751911.Google Scholar
Choi, H., Lugauer, S. and Mark, N. C. (2017) Precautionary saving of Chinese and U.S. Households. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 49, 635661CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochrane, J. H. (2005) Asset Pricing. Revised edition. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cooper, R. J and McLaren, K. R. (1992) An empirically oriented demand system with improved regularity properties. Canadian Journal of Economics 25, 652668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, R. J. and McLaren, K. R. (1996) A system of demand equations satisfying effectively global regularity conditions, Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 359–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crossley, T. F. and Low, H. W. (2011) Is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution constant? Journal of the European Economic Association 9, 87105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, G. C. and Jensen, K. L. (1994) Two-stage utility maximization and import demand systems revisited: Limitations and an alternative. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 19, 409424.Google Scholar
Deaton, A. (1986) Demand analysis. In: Griliches, Z. and Intriligator, M. D. (ed.) Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. III, Chapter 10, pp. 17671839, Amsterdam; Oxford: Elsevier Science Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, A. (1991) Saving and liquidity constraints, Econometrica 59, 12211248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, A. (1992) Understanding Consumption. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, A. and Muellbauer, J. (1980a) Economics and Consumer Behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, A. and Muellbauer, J. (1980b) An almost ideal demand system. American Economic Review 70, 312326.Google Scholar
Dynan, K. E (1993) How prudent are consumers? Journal of Political Economy 101, 11041113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dynan, K. E. (2000) Habit formation in consumer preferences: Evidence from panel data. American Economic Review 90, 391406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernandez-Villaverde, J. and Kruege, D. (2011) Consumption and saving over the life cycle: How important are consumer durables?, Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 725770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, D., Fleissig, A. R., and Serletis, A. (2001) An empirical comparison of flexible demand system functional forms. Journal of Applied Econometrics 16, 5980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuss, M. (1977) The demand for energy in Canadian manufacturing. Journal of Econometrics 5, 89116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorman, W. M. (1959) Separable utility and aggregation. Econometrica 27, 469481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gourinchas, P.-O. and Parker, J. A. (2001) The empirical importance of precautionary saving. American Economic Review 91, 406412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. E. (1978) Stochastic implications of the life cycle - permanent income hypothesis: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy 86, 971987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. E. (1988) Intertemporal substitution in consumption. Journal of Political Economy 96, 339357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, L. P. and Jagannathan, R. (1991) Implications of security market data for models of dynamic economies. Journal of Political Economy 99, 225262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, L. P. and Singleton, K. J. (1982) Generalized instrumental variables estimation of nonlinear rational expectations models. Econometrica 50, 12691286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, L. P. and Singleton, K. J. (1983) Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of asset returns. Journal of Political Economy 91, 249265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayashi, F. (1982) Tobin’s marginal q and average q: A neoclassical interpretation. Econometrica, 50, 213224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodrick, R. J. and Zhang, X. (2001) Evaluating the specification errors of asset pricing models. Journal of Financial Economics 62, 327376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubbard, R. G. (1998) Capital-market imperfections and investment. Journal of Economic Literature 36, 193225.Google Scholar
Jorgenson, D. W., Slesnick, D. T. and Stoker, T. M. (1988) Two-stage budgeting and exact aggregation. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 6, 313325.Google Scholar
Kim, H. Y. (1990) Relative prices and the demand for money. Journal of Macroeconomics 19, 5195–541.Google Scholar
Kim, H. Y. (1993) Frisch demand functions and intertemporal substitution in consumption. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25, 445454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, H. Y. (2004) Commodity rates of interest and intertemporal substitution in commodity demand and consumption. Australian Economic Papers 43, 228247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, H. Y. (2017a) The permanent income hypothesis, transitional dynamics, and excess sensitivity of consumption. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 40, 1025.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, H. Y. (2017b). Corrigendum to the permanent income hypothesis, transitional dynamics, and excess sensitivity of consumption. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 41, 7878.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, H. Y., McLaren, K. R. and Gary Wong, K. K. (2013) Empirical demand systems incorporating intertemporal consumption dynamics. Empirical Economics 45, 49370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, H. Y., McLaren, K. R. and Gary Wong, K. K. (2018) Valuation of Public Goods: An Intertemporal Mixed Demand Approach. Western Kentucky University, Working Paper Empirical Economics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Kocherlakota, N. (1996) The equity premium: It’s still a puzzle. Journal of Economic Literature 35, 4271.Google Scholar
Lettau, M. and Ludvigson, S. (2001) Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A cross-sectional test when risk premia are time-varying. Journal of Political Economy 109, 12381287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lettau, M., Ludvigson, S. C. and Wachter, J. A. (2008) The declining equity premium: What role does macroeconomic risk play? Review of Financial Studies 21, 16531687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewbel, A. (1991) The rank of demand systems: Theory and non-parametric estimation. Econometrica 59, 711730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, J. S. (1994) Siegel’s Formula via Stein’s Identities. Statistics & Probability Letters 21, 247251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ljungqvist, L. and Sargent, T. J. (2012) Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, 3rd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Ludvigson, S. and Paxson, C. H., (2001) Approximation bias in linearized Euler equations. Review of Economics and Statistics 83, 242256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lustig, H. N. and Nieuwerburgh, S. V. (2005) Housing collateral, consumption insurance, and risk premia: An empirical perspective. Journal of Finance 60, 11671219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLaughlin, K. J. (1995) Intertemporal substitution and λ-constant comparative statics. Journal of Monetary Economics 35, 193213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehra, R. and Prescott, E. C. (1985) The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics 15, 145161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mian, A. and Sufi, A. (2011) House prices, home equity-based borrowing, and the US household leverage crisis. American Economic Review 101, 21322156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moschini, G. and Moro, D. (1994) Autocorrelation specification in singular equation systems. Economics Letters 46, 303309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muellbauer, J. (1975) Aggregation, income distribution, and consumer demand. Review of Economic Studies 42, 525543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ogaki, M. and Reinhart, C. M. (1998) Measuring intertemporal substitution: The role of durable goods. Journal of Political Economy 106, 10781098.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piazzesi, M., Schneider, M. and Tuzel, S. (2007) Housing, consumption, and asset pricing. Journal of Financial Economics 83, 531569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Runkle, D. E. (1991) Liquidity constraints and the permanent-income hypothesis. Journal of Monetary Economics 27, 7398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Serletis, A. and Shahmoradi, A. (2007) Flexible functional forms, curvature conditions, and the demand for assets. Macroeconomic Dynamics 11: 455486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sills, K. (2005) Macroeconomic Volatility and the Equity Premium., Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Working Paper No. 06-1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soderlind, P. (2009) An extended Stein’s Lemma for asset pricing. Applied Financial Economics Letters 16, 10051008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Summers, L. H. (1981) Taxation and corporate investment: A q-theory approach. Brookings Paper on Economic Activity 1, 67127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yogo, M. (2006) A consumption-based explanation of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance 61, 539580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zeldes, S. P. (1989) Consumption and liquidity constraints: An empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 97, 305346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar