Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-30T17:37:58.686Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 May 2011

Malcolm Rutherford
Affiliation:
University of Victoria, British Columbia
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramovitz, Moses. 2001. Days Gone By: A Memoir for my Family. http://www.econ.stanford.edu/abramovitz/abramovitzM.html
Adams, Henry C. 1887. On the Relation of the State to Industrial Action. Publications of the American Economic Association 1, No 6.Google Scholar
Adams, Thomas S. and Sumner, Helen L.. 1905. Labor Problems. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Alchon, Guy. 1985. The Invisible Hand of Planning: Capitalism, Social Science and the State in the 1920s. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altmeyer, Arthur J. 1966. The Formative Years of Social Security. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Anderson, Theodore W. 1955. The Department of Mathematical Statistics. In Gordon Hoxie, R. et al. A History of the Faculty of Political Science, Columbia University. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Arnold, Thurman. 1937. The Folklore of Capitalism. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1975. Thorstein Veblen as an Economic Theorist. American Economist 19 (Spring): 5–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asso, Pier Francesco and Fiorito, Luca. 2004a. Human Nature and Economic Institutions: Instinct Psychology, Behaviorism, and the Development of American Instituionalism. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 26 (December): 445–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asso, Pier Francesco and Fiorito, Luca 2004b. Lawrence Kelso Frank's Proto-Ayresian Dichotomy. History of Political Economy 36 (Fall): 557–578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkins, Willard, E., McConnell, Donald W., Edwards, Corwin D., Raushenbush, Carl, Friedrich, Anton A., and Reed, Louis S.. 1931. Economic Behavior: An Institutional Approach. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1918. The Epistemological Significance of Social Psychology. Journal of Philosophy, Psychology and Scientific Methods (January 17): 35–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1921a. Instinct and Capacity–I. Journal of Philosophy 18 (October 13): 561–565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1921b. Instinct and Capacity–II. Journal of Philosophy 19 (October 27): 600–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1936. Fifty Years Developments in Ideas of Human Nature and Motivation. American Economic Review 26 (March): 224–236.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1938. The Problem of Economic Order. New York: Farrar and Rinehart.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1944. The Theory of Economic Progress. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1945. Addendum tothe Theory of Economic Progress. American Economic Review 35 (December): 937–942.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1951. The Co-ordinates of Institutionalism. American Economic Review 41 (May): 47–55.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1966. Guaranteed Income: An Institutionalist View. In Theobald, Robert, ed., The Guaranteed Income. New York: Doubleday, pp. 161–174.Google Scholar
Ayres, Clarence E. 1968. The Price System and Public Policy. Journal of Economic Issues 2 (September): 342–344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Edith. 1938. What Shall We Do with Economic Science?International Journal of Ethics 48 (January): 143–164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 1998. The Transformation of American Economics, 1920–1960, Viewed Through a Survey of Journal Articles. In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds., From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, Annual Supplement to Volume 30 of History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 85–107.Google Scholar
Bain, Joe S. 1944. The Economics of the Pacific Petroleum Industry. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Bain, Joe S. 1959. Industrial Organization. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Balisciano, Marcia. 1998. Hope for America: American Notions of Economic Planning Between Pluralism and Neoclassicism, 1930–1950. In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds., From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, Annual Supplement to Volume 30, History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 153–178.Google Scholar
Barber, William J. 1987. The Career of Alvin H. Hansen in the 1920s and 1930s: A Study in Intellectual Transformation. History of Political Economy 19 (Summer): 191–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, William J. 1988. From New Era to New Deal: Herbert Hoover, the Economists, and American Economic Policy, 1921–1933. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barber, William J. 1994. The Divergent Fates of Two Strands of “Institutionalist” Doctrine during the New Deal Years. History of Political Economy 26 (Winter): 569–587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, William J. 1996. Designs within Disorder: Franklin D. Roosevelt, the Economists, and the Shaping of Economic Policy, 1933–1945. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnard, Chester. 1938. The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bateman, Bradley W. 1998. Clearing the Ground: The Demise of the Social Gospel Movement and the Rise of Neoclassicism in American Economics. In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds., From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, Annual Supplement to Volume 30 of History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 29–52.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1965. A Theory of the Allocation of Time. Economic Journal 75: 493–515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Beller, Andrea H. and Elizabeth Kiss, D.. 2001. Kyrk, Hazel. In Schultz, Rima L. and Hast, Adele, eds., Women Building Chicago 1790–1990. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press, pp. 482–485.Google Scholar
Beller, Andrea H. 2003. On the Contribution of Hazel Kyrk to Family Economics. Paper Presented at the ASSA/HES Meetings, Washington DC.
Berle, Adolf. A. and Means, Gardiner C.. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bernasek, Alexandra and Kinnear, Douglas 1995. Ruth Allen: Frontier Labor Economist. In Phillips, Ronnie J., ed., Economic Mavericks: The Texas Institutionalists. Political Economy and Public Policy 9. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, pp. 75-106.Google Scholar
Beveridge, William H. 1909. Unemployment: A Problem of Industry. London: Longmans, Green.Google Scholar
Biddle, Jeff. 1998a. Institutional Economics: A Case of Reproductive Failure? In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds. From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism. Annual Supplement to Volume 30, History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp.108–133.Google Scholar
Biddle, Jeff 1998b. Social Science and the Making of Social Policy: Wesley Mitchell's Vision. In Rutherford, Malcolm, ed., The Economic Mind in America: Essays in the History of American Economics. London: Routledge, pp. 43–79.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1978. Economic Theory in Retrospect, 3rd. edition. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark 1999. The Formalist Revolution or What Happened to Orthodox Economics after World War II? In Backhouse, Roger and Creedy, John, eds., From Classical Economics to the Theory of the Firm: Essays in Honour of D. P. O'Brien. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, pp. 257–280.Google Scholar
Bonbright, James C. 1937. The Valuation of Property. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Bonbright, James and Means, Gardiner C.. 1932. The Holding Company. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Boyer, George and Smith, Robert. 2001. The Development of the Neoclassical Tradition in Modern Labor Economics. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 54 (January): 199–223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratton, William W. 2001. Berle and Means Reconsidered at the Century's Turn. Journal of Corporation Law 26: 737.Google Scholar
Brazelton, Robert. 1997. The Economics of Leon Hirsch Keyserling. The Journal of EconomicPerspectives 11 (Autumn): 189–197.Google Scholar
Breit, William and Culbertson, William P. Jr. 1976. Clarence Edwin Ayres: An Intellectual's Portrait. In Breit, William and Culbertson, William P. Jr., eds., Science and Ceremony: The Institutional Economics of C. E. Ayres. Austin, TX: University of Texas Press, pp. 3–22.Google Scholar
Brissenden, Paul F. 1919. The IWW: A Study of American Syndicalism. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Bronfenbrenner, Martin. 1993. Wisconsin 1947–1957–Reflections and Confessions. In Lampman, Robert J., ed., Economists at Wisconsin, 1892–1992. Madison, WI: Board of Regents of the University of Wisconsin System, pp. 130–138.Google Scholar
Institution, Brookings. 1931. Essays on Research in the Social Sciences. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Brown, John Howard. 2008. Where Did Industrial Organization Come From? Mimeo.
Bruce, Kyle. 2000. Conflict and Conversion: Henry S. Dennison and the Shaping of J. K. Galbraith's Economic Thought. Journal of Economic Issues 34 (December): 949–967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon. 1965. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Bulmer, Martin and Bulmer, Joan. 1981. Philanthropy and Social Science in the 1920s: Beardsley Ruml and the Laura Spelman Rockefeller Memorial, 1922–1929. Minerva 19 (3): 347–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, Arthur F. 1934. Production Trends in the United States since 1870. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Burns, Arthur F. 1936. The Brookings Inquiry into Income Distribution and Progress. Quarterly Journal of Economics 50 (May): 476–523.CrossRef
Burns, Arthur F. 1946. Economic Research and the Keynesian Thinking of Our Times. Twenty-Sixth Annual Report of the National Bureau of Economic Research. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Burns, Arthur F. 1947. Keynesian Economics Once Again. Review of Economic Statistics 29 (November): 252–267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, Arthur F. 1952. Hicks and the Real Cycle. Journal of Political Economy 60 (February): 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, Arthur F. 1953. The Instability of Consumer Spending, 32nd Annual Report, National Bureau of Economic Research. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Burns, Arthur F. and Wesley C. Mitchell. 1946. Measuring Business Cycles. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Burns, Arthur R. 1936. The Decline of Competition: A Study of the Evolution of American Industry. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.Google Scholar
Burns, Arthur R. 1937. The Organization of Industry and the Theory of Prices. Journal of Political Economy 45 (September): 662–680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, Eveline M. 1931. Does Institutional Economics Complement or Compete with “Orthodox” Economics. American Economic Review 21 (March): 80–87.Google Scholar
Burns, Eveline M. 1936. Toward Social Security. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Bye, Raymond T. (1924) 1971. Some Recent Developments of Economic Theory. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 271–300.Google Scholar
Bye, Raymond T. 1940. An Appraisal of F. C. Mills The Behavior of Prices: Critiques of Research in the Social Sciences II. New York: Social Science Research Council.Google Scholar
Caldwell, Bruce J. 1982. Beyond Positivism: Economic Methodology in the Twentieth Century. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Camic, Charles. 1991. Introduction: Talcott Parsons before The Structure of Social Action. In Camic, Charles, ed., Talcott Parsons, the Early Essays. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. ix–xix.Google Scholar
Camic, Charles. 1992. Reputation and Predecessor Selection: Parsons and the Institutionalists. American Sociological Review 57 (August): 421–445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camic, Charles Forthcoming. Veblen's Apprenticeship: On the Translation of Gustav Cohn's System der Finanzwissenschaft. History of Political Economy.
Camic, Charles and Xie, Yu. 1994. The Statistical Turn in American Social Science: Columbia University, 1890–1915. American Sociological Review 59 (October): 773–805.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Persia. (1940) 1968. Consumer Representation in the New Deal. New York: AMS Press.Google Scholar
Cauley, Troy J. 1964. Max Handman. Bulletin of the Wardman Group 1 (April): 2–3.Google Scholar
,Central Statistical Board. 1939. The Central Statistical Board and its Work. Prepared for the use of the Committee on Expenditures in the Executive Departments, House of Representatives, in Connection with consideration of HR 5917, 76th Congress. April 25, 1939. Morris A Copeland Papers, Box 3, Central Statistical Board Folder, Butler Library, Columbia University.
Chamberlin, Edward H. 1933. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chamberlin, Edward H. 1961. The Origin and Early Development of Monopolistic Competition Theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics 75 (November): 515–543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chase, Stuart. 1925. The Tragedy of Waste. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Chasse, John Dennis. 1986. John R. Commons and the Democratic State. Journal of Economic Issues 20 (September): 759–784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chasse, John Dennis 1991. The American Association for Labor Legislation: An Episode in Institutional Policy Analysis. Journal of Economic Issues 15 (September): 799–828.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chasse, John Dennis 1994. The American Association for Labor Legislation and the Institutionalist Tradition in National Health Insurance. Journal of Economic Issues 28 (December): 1063–1090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chasse, John Dennis 2004. John R. Commons and His Students: The View from the End of the Twentieth Century. In Champlin, Dell P. and Knoedler, Janet T., eds., The Institutionalist Tradition in Labor Economics. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, pp. 50–74.Google Scholar
Christ, Carl F. 1994. The Cowles Commission's Contributions to Econometrics at Chicago, 1939–1955. Journal of Economic Literature 32 (March): 30–59.Google Scholar
Clapham, J. H. 1922. Of Empty Economic Boxes. Economic Journal 32 (September): 305–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John M. 1915. The Concept of Value. Quarterly Journal of Economics 29 (August): 663–673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John M. 1916. The Changing Basis of Economic Responsibility. Journal of Political Economy 24 (March): 209–229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John M. 1917. Business Acceleration and the Law of Demand: A Technical Factor in Business Cycles. Journal of Political Economy 25 (March): 217–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John M. 1918. Economics and Modern Psychology, I and II. Journal of Political Economy 26 (January, February): 1–30, 136–166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John M. 1919. Economic Theory in an Era of Social Readjustment. American Economic Review, 9 (March): 280–290.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1921. Soundings in Non-Euclidean Economics. American Economic Review, 11 (March): 132–143.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1923. Studies in the Economics of Overhead Costs. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. (1924) 1971. The Socializing of Theoretical Economics. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 73–102.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1926. Social Control of Business. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1927. Recent Developments in Economics. In Hayes, Edward C., ed., Recent Developments in the Social Sciences. Philadelphia: Lippencott, pp. 213–306.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1931. Wesley C. Mitchell's Contribution to the Theory of Business Cycles. In Rice, Stuart, ed., Methods in Social Science: A Case Book. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1932. Round Table Conferences – Institutional Economics. American Economic Review 22 (March): 105–106.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1934. Strategic Factors in Business Cycles. New York: National Bureau for Economic Research.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1935a. Cumulative Effects of Aggregate Spending as Illustrated by Public Works. American Economic Review 25 (March): 14–20.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1935b. Economics of Planning Public Works. Washington DC: US Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1936. Preface to Social Economics: Essays on Economic Theory and Social Problems. Edited and with an Introduction by Abramovitz, Moses and Ginzberg, Eli. New York: Farrar and Rinehart.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1940. Towards a Concept of Workable Competition. American Economic Review 30 (June): 241–256.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1942. The Theoretical Issues. American Economic Review 32 (March): 1–12.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1946. Realism and Relevance in the Theory of Demand. Journal of Political Economy 54 (August): 374–353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John M. 1947. Mathematical Economists and Others: A Plea for Communicability. Econometrica 15 (April): 75–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John M. 1957. Economic Institutions and Human Welfare. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Clark, John M. 1961. Competition as a Dynamic Process. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Clark, John M., Hamilton, Walton H., and Moulton, Harold G., eds. 1918. Readings in the Economics of War. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Clark, John M., et al. 1949. National and International Measures for Full Employment. Lake Success, NY: United Nations.Google Scholar
Clay, Henry. 1916. Economics: An Introduction for the General Reader. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1984. The New Institutional Economics. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 140 (March): 229–231.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1993. Law and Economics at Chicago. Journal of Law and Economics 36 (April): 239–254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coats, A. W. 1960. The First Two Decades of the American Economic Association. American Economic Review 50 (September): 555–574.Google Scholar
Cobb, Charles W. and Douglas, Paul H.. 1928. A Theory of Production. The American Economic Review 18 (March): 139–165.Google Scholar
Cohen, Jacob. 1972. Copeland's Moneyflows after Twenty-Five Years: A Survey. Journal of Economic Literature 10 (March): 1–25.Google Scholar
Cohen, Wilbur J. 1960. Edwin E. Witte (1887–1960): Father of Social Security. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 14 (October): 7–9.Google Scholar
,Commission of Inquiry, Interchurch World Movement. (1920) 1971. Report on the Steel Strike of 1919. New York: Da Capo Press.Google Scholar
,Committee on the Costs of Medical Care. 1932. Medical Care for the American People. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
,Committee on Government Statistics and Information Services. 1933. The Statistical Services of the Federal Government in Relation to the Recovery Program. Report Addressed to Hon. John Dickinson, Assistant Secretary of Commerce and Dr. Alexander Sachs, Chief of Research and Planning, Industrial Recovery Administration, Washington DC, July 1933. Morris A Copeland Papers, Box 3, Central Statistical Board Folder.
,Committee on Recent Economic Changes. 1929. Recent Economic Changes in the United States. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1899–1900. A Sociological View of Sovereignty. American Journal of Sociology 5 (July-November): 1–15, 155–171, 347–366; (January to May): 544–552, 683–695, 814–825; 6 (July): 67–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R. 1901. A New Way of Settling Labor Disputes. American Monthly Review of Reviews 23 (March): 328–333.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1907. The Wisconsin Public-Utilities Law. American Review of Reviews 36 (August): 221–224.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1908. Races and Immigrants in America. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1909. American Shoemakers, 1648–1895: A Sketch of Industrial Evolution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 24 (November): 219–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R. 1910. How Wisconsin Regulates Her Public Utilities. American Review of Reviews 42 (August): 215–217.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1921. Unemployment: Compensation and Prevention. The Survey 42 (October 1): 5–9.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1924a. The Legal Foundations of Capitalism. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1924b. The Delivered Price Practice in the Steel Market. American Economic Review 14 (September): 505–519.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1925a. The Stabilization of Prices and Business. American Economic Review 15 (March): 43–52.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1925b. The True Scope of Unemployment Insurance. American Labor Legislation Review 15 (March): 33–44.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1925c. Reasonable Value. Reprinted and edited by Malcolm Rutherford, Warren J. Samuels, and Charles J. Whalen, in Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 26-B (2008): 235–307.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1925d. Law and Economics. Yale Law Journal 34 (February): 371–382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R. 1925e. Marx Today: Capitalism and Socialism. Atlantic Monthly 136 (November): 682–693.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1927. Price Stabilization and the Federal Reserve System. The Annalist 29 (April 1): 459–462.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1931. Institutional Economics. American Economic Review 21 (December): 648–657.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1932. The Problem of Correlating Law, Economics and Ethics. Wisconsin Law Review 8 (December): 3–26.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1934a. Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1934b. Myself. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1936. Institutional Economics. American Economic Review 26 (March): 237–249.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1937. Capacity to Produce, Capacity to Consume, Capacity to Pay Debts. American Economic Review 27 (December): 680–697.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. and Andrews, John B.. 1916. Principles of Labor Legislation. New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1936. Principles of Labor Legislation, Fourth Revised Edition. New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Commons, John R., McCracken, H. L., and Zeuch, W. E.. 1922. Secular Trend and Business Cycles: A Classification of Theories. Review of Economic Statistics 4 (October): 244–263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R. and Morehouse, E. W.. 1927. Legal and Economic Job Analysis. Yale Law Journal 37 (December): 139–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R., Phillips, Ulrich B., Gilmore, Eugene A., Sumner, Helen L., and Andrews, John B.. 1910–1911. A Documentary History of American Industrial Society. Cleveland, OH: Arthur H. Clark.Google Scholar
Commons, John R., Saposs, D. J., Sumner, H. L., Mittleman, E. B., Hoagland, H. E., Andrews, J. B., and Perlman, Selig. 1918 and 1935. History of Labor in the United States, 4 vols. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Cookingham, Mary E. 1987. Social Economists and Reform: Berkeley, 1906–1961. History of Political Economy 19 (Spring): 47–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooley, Charles H. 1913. The Institutional Character of Pecuniary Valuation. American Journal of Sociology 18 (January): 543–555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1920. Seasonal Problems in Financial Administration. Journal of Political Economy 28 (December): 793–826.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1921. Some Phases of Institutional Value Theory. PhD Thesis, University of Chicago. Morris A. Copeland Papers, Box 8, Manuscripts by M. A. Copeland Folder.
Copeland, Morris A. (1924) 1971. Communities of Economic Interest and the Price System. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics, pp. 105–150. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press.
Copeland, Morris A. 1925a. The Economics of Advertising – Discussion. American Economic Review 15 (March): 38–41Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1925b. Review of John M. ClarkStudies in the Economics of Overhead Costs. Political Science Quarterly 40 (June): 296–299.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1925c. Professor Knight on Psychology. Quarterly Journal of Economics 40 (November): 134–151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1926. Desire, Choice, and Purpose from a Natural-Evolutionary Standpoint. Psychological Review 33 (July): 245–267CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1927. An Instrumental View of the Part-Whole Relation. Journal of Philosophy 24 (February 17): 96–104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1928. An Estimate of Total Volume of Debts to Individual Accounts in the United States. Journal of the American Statistical Association 23 (September): 301–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929a. Two Hypotheses Concerning the Equation of Exchange. Journal of the American Statistical Association 24, Supplement (March): 146–148.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929b. Special Purpose Indexes for the Equation of Exchange for the United States, 1919–1927. Journal of the American Statistical Association 24 (June): 109–122.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929c. Money, Trade, and Prices – A Test of Causal Primacy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 43 (August): 648–666.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1929d. The National Income and its Distribution. In Recent Economic Changes in the United States, vol. 2., New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. (1930) 1973. Psychology and the Natural Science Point of View. Reprinted in Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, pp. 11–36.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1931a. Economic Theory and the Natural Science Point of View. American Economic Review 21 (March): 67–79.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1931b. Some Suggestions for Improving our Information on Wholesale Commodity Prices. Journal of the American Statistical Association 26, Supplement (March): 110–115.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1932a. Some Problems in the Theory of National Income. Journal of Political Economy 40 (February): 1–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1932b. How Large Is Our National Income?Journal of Political Economy 40 (December): 771–795.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. (1934) 1973. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. In Copeland, Morris A., Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport CT: Greenwood Press, pp. 247–251.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1935. National Wealth and Income – An Interpretation. Journal of the American Statistical Association 30 (June): 377–386.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1936. Commons's Institutionalism in Relation to Problems of Social Evolution and Economic Planning. Quarterly Journal of Economics 50 (February): 333–346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1937. Concepts of National Income. In Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. I. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1939a. Public Investment in the United States. American Economic Review 29 (March): 33–41.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1939b. Aims and Purposes of the United States Central Statistical Board. The Controller 7 (July): 236–237, 255.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1940a. Examining for Professional Positions. Personnel Administration 2 (January): 1–4.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. (1940b) 1973. Competing Products and Monopolistic Competition. In Copeland, Morris A., Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, pp. 251–300.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1941. Economic Research in the Federal Government. American Economic Review 31 (September): 526–536.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1942a. Production Planning for a War Economy. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 220 (March): 94–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1942b. The Defense Effort and the National Income Response Pattern. Journal of Political Economy 50 (June): 415–426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1944. How Achieve Full and Stable Employment. American Economic Review 34 (March): 134–147.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. (1948) 1973. Authority and Reason as Instruments of Coordination in the United States. In Copeland, Morris A., Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, pp. 119–129.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1951. Institutional Economics and Model Analysis. American Economic Review 41 (May): 56–65.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1952a. A Study of Moneyflows in the United States. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1952b. The Keynesian Reformation: Three Lectures. Delhi: Delhi School of Economics.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. (1955) 1973. Statistics and Objective Economics. In Copeland, Morris A., Fact and Theory in Economics. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, pp. 67–91.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1958a. Institutionalism and Welfare Economics. American Economic Review 48 (March): 1–17.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1958b. On the Scope and Method of Economics. In Dowd, Douglas F., ed., Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Reappraisal. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1965. Our Free Enterprise System. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1966. Toward Full Employment in Our Free Enterprise Economy. New York: Fordham University Press.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1967. Laissez Faire, Pecuniary Incentives, and Public Policy. Journal of Economic Issues 1 (December): 335–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1970. On Unemployment and Overemployment, Assuming Wage and Price Stability [Flexibility]. Journal of Economic Issues 4 (June-Sept): 40–59. Corrigenda, Journal of Economic Issues 5 (June 1971): 134–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. and Martin, Edwin M.. 1938. The Correction of Wealth and Income Estimates for Price Changes. In Studies in Income and Wealth, vol II. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Copeland, Morris A. 1939. National Income and Capital Formation. Journal of Political Economy 47 (June): 398–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craver, Earlene. 1986. Patronage and the Direction of Research in Economics: The Rockefeller Foundation in Europe, 1924–1938. Minerva 24 (2–3): 205–223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craver, Earlene and Leijonhufvud, Axel. 1987. Economics in America: The Continental Influence. History of Political Economy 19 (Summer): 173–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cross, Ira B. 1935. A History of the Labor Movement in California. Berkeley, CA: University of California.Google Scholar
Curti, Merle. 1980. Human Nature in American Thought. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Curti, Merle and Carstensen, Vernon. 1949. The University of Wisconsin: A History 1848–1925. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Cutler, Addison T. 1938. The Ebb of Institutional Economics. Science and Society 2 (Fall): 448–470.Google Scholar
Davidson, Audrey B. and Ekelund, Robert B.. 1994. America's Alternative to Marshall: Property, Competition, and Capitalism in Hadley's Economics of 1896. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 16 (Spring): 1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawson, John C. 1991. Copeland as Social Accountant. In Dawson, John C., ed., Flow of Funds Analysis: A Handbook for Practitioners. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1996.Google Scholar
Dawson, John C. ed. 1996. Flow of Funds Analysis: A Handbook for Practitioners. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, pp. 93–100.Google Scholar
Degler, Carl N. 1991. In Search of Human Nature: the Decline and Revival of Darwinism in American Economic Thought. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rouvray, Cristel. 2004. “Old” Economic History in the United States: 1939–1954. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 26 (June): 221–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewey, John. 1926. The Historic Background of Corporate Legal Personality. Yale Law Journal 35: 665–673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewey, John 1929. The Quest for Certainty. New York: Minton, Blach.Google Scholar
Dewey, John 1931. Social Science and Social Control. New Republic 67 (29 July): 276–277.Google Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 2000. Theresa Schmid McMahon (1878–1961). In Dimand, Robert W., Dimand, Mary Ann, and Forget, Evelyn L., eds., A Biographical Dictionary of Women Economists. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 304–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 2002. John Maurice Clark's Contribution to the Genesis of the Multiplier Analysis: A Response to Luca Fiorito. History of Economic Ideas 10 (1): 85–91.Google Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. and Koehn, Robert H.. 2008. Galbraith's Hexerodox Teacher: Leo Rogin's Historical Approach to the Meaning and Validity of Economic Theory. Journal of Economic Issues 41 (June): 561–568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donohue, Kathleen G. 2003. Freedom from Want: American Liberalism and the Idea of the Consumer. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph. 1934. Thorstein Veblen and His America. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1949. The Economic Mind in American Civilization, vol 3. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1955. The Department of Economics. In Gordon Hoxie, R., et al., A History of the Faculty of Political Science, Columbia University. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 161–206.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1958. Walter Winne Stewart (1815–1958). Year Book of the American Philosophical Society. Philadelphia: American Philosophical Society, pp. 155–159.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1959. The Economic Mind in American Civilization, vols. 4 and 5. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1963. The Background of Institutional Economics. In Institutional Economics: Veblen, Commons, and Mitchell Reconsidered. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, pp. 1–44.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1967. Introduction. Wesley C. Mitchell, Types of Economic Theory, vol 1. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1973. New Light on Veblen. Introduction to Thorstein Veblen, Essays Reviews and Reports, edited by Dorfman, Joseph. Clifton, NJ: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 5–326.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph 1974. Walton Hale Hamilton and Industrial Policy. Introduction to Walton H. Hamilton, Industrial Policy and Institutionalism: Selected Essays. Clifton, NJ: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 5–28.Google Scholar
Douglas, Paul H. 1934a. The Role of the Consumer in the New Deal. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 172 (March): 98–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Douglas, Paul H. 1934b. The Theory of Wages. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Douglas, Paul H. 1935. Controlling Depressions. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Douglas, Paul H. 1936. Social Security in the United States. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Douglas, Paul H. 1971. In the Fullness of Time. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Dowd, Douglas F. ed. 1958. Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Reappraisal. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Dowd, Douglas F. 1994. Against Decadence: The Work of Robert A. Brady (1901–63). Journal of Economic Issues 28 (December): 1031–1061.CrossRef
Downey, E. H. 1910. The Futility of Marginal Utility. Journal of Political Economy 18 (April): 253–268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downey, E. H. 1924. Workmen's Compensation. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Duncan, Joseph W. and Shelton, William C.. 1978. Revolution in United States Government Statistics, 1926–1976. Washington DC: U. S. Department of Commerce.Google Scholar
Duxbury, Neil. 1995. Patterns of American Jurisprudence. Oxford: Oxford UniversityGoogle Scholar
Edie, Lionel D. 1922. Principles of the New Economics. New York: Thomas Y. Crowell.Google Scholar
Edie, Lionel D. 1926. Economic Principles and Problems. New York: University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Edie, Lionel D. 1927. Some Positive Contributions of the Institutional Concept. Quarterly Journal of Economics 41 (May): 405–440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, George W., Moulton, Harold G., Lewis, Celona, and Magee, James D.. 1940. Capital Expansion, Employment, and Economic Stability. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Eisner, J. Michael. 1967. William Morris Leiserson: A Biography. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B. and Hebert, Robert F.. 1990. A History of Economic Theory and Method. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard, T. 1914. Property and Contract in Their Relation to the Distribution of Wealth. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard, T. 1932. Round Table Conferences: Institutional Economics. American Economic Review 22 (March): 114–116.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T., Adams, Thomas A., Lorenz, Max O., and Young, Allyn. 1908. Outlines of Economics, revised edition. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Emmett, Ross B. 1999. Introduction. In Emmett, Ross B., ed., Selected Essays of Frank H. Knight. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. vii–xxiv.Google Scholar
Emmett, Ross B. 2009. Frank Knight and the Chicago School in American Economics. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Emmett, Ross B. Forthcoming. Specializing in Interdisciplinarity: The Committee on Social Thought as Chicago's Antidote to Specialization in the Social Sciences. History of Political Economy.
Epstein, Abraham. 1936. Insecurity: A Challenge to America. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Epstein, Roy J. 1987. A History of Econometrics. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Everett, Helen. 1931. Social Control. Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences, vol. 4. New York: Macmillan, pp. 344–349.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai. 1930. Methods of Correlation Analysis. New York: J. Wiley.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai 1936. $2,500 a Year: From Scarcity to Abundance. New York: Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai 1937. An Annual Estimate of Savings by Individuals. Review of Economic Statistics 19 (November): 178–191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai 1938. The Cobweb Theorem. Quarterly Journal of Economics 52 (February): 255–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai 1939a. Jobs for All through Industrial Expansion. New York: A. A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai 1939b. Keynes versus Chamberlin. Report of the Fifth Annual Conference on Economics and Statistics. Colorado Springs, CO: Cowles Commission for Research in Economics, pp. 54–57.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai 1942. Statistical Investigations of Saving, Consumption, and Investment, Parts I and II. American Economic Review 32 (March): 22–49 and (June): 272–307.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai 1957. Reminiscences of Mordecai Ezekiel. Columbia University Oral History Research Office Collection.Google Scholar
Fabricant, Solomon. 1984. Toward a Firmer Basis of Economic Policy: The Founding of The National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/nberhistory/
Fetter, Frank A. 1932. The Economists' Committee on Anti-Trust Law Policy. American Economic Review 22 (September): 465–469.Google Scholar
Field, James A. 1917. The Place of Economic Theory in Graduate Work. Journal of Political Economy 25 (January): 48–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorito, Luca. 2001. John Maurice Clark's Contribution to the Genesis of the Multiplier Analysis (With Some Unpublished Correspondence). History of Economic Ideas 9 (1): 7–37.Google Scholar
Fiorito, Luca 2009. Frank H. Knight, Pragmatism and American Institutionalism: A Note. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 16 (September): 475–487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorito, Luca 2010a. The Institutionalists' Reaction to Chamberlin's Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Fiorito, Luca 2010b. John R. Commons, Wesley N. Hohfeld and the Origins of Transactional Economics. History of Political Economy 42 (Summer): 267–295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorito, Luca and Vernengo, Matias. 2009. The Other J. M.: John Maurice Clark and the Keynesian Revolution. Journal of Economic Issues 43 (December): 899–916.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Donald. 1993. Fundamental Development of the social Sciences: Rockefeller Philanthropy and the United States Social Science Research Council. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1919. Economists and the Public Service. American Economic Review 9 (March): 5–21.Google Scholar
Fisher, William W., Horwitz, Morton J., and Reed, Thomas A., eds. 1993. American Legal Realism. New York: Oxford University Press.
Fishman, L. 1958. Veblen, Hoxie, and American Labor. In Dowd, D. F., ed., Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Reappraisal. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, pp. 221–236.Google Scholar
Fitch, John A. (1910) 1989. The Steel Workers. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh.Google Scholar
Florence, P. Sargant. 1927. Economics and Human Behavior: A Reply to Social Psychologists. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Forget, Evelyn L. 2000. Margaret Gilpin Reid (1896–1991). In Dimand, Robert W., Dimand, Mary Ann and Forget, Evelyn L., eds., A Biographical Dictionary of Women Economists. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 357–361.Google Scholar
Fosdick, Raymond B. 1952. The Story of the Rockefeller Foundation. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Frank, Lawrence K. 1923a. The Status of Social Sciences in the United Sates. RAC-LSRM, Series 3.6, Box 63, Folder 679.
Frank, Lawrence K. 1923b. A Theory of Business Cycles. Quarterly Journal of Economics 37 (August): 625–642.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Lawrence K. 1924. The Emancipation of Economics. American Economic Review 14 (March): 17–38.Google Scholar
Frank, Lawrence K. 1925. The Significance of Industrial Integration. Journal of Political Economy 33 (April): 179–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friday, David. 1919. Maintaining Productive Output – A Problem in Reconstruction. Journal of Political Economy 27 (February): 117–126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friday, David 1920. Profits, Wages, and Prices. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Howe.Google Scholar
Fried, Barbara H. 1998. The Progressive Assault on Laissez Faire: Robert Hale and the First Law and Economics Movement. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1945. Incomes from Independent Professional Practice (With Simon Kuznets). New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton 1953. The Methodology of Positive Economics. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton 1962. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Friedman, Rose. 1998. Two Lucky People. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna J.. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States: 1867–1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Froman, Lewis A. 1942. Graduate Students in Economics, 1904–1940. American Economic Review 32 (December): 817–826.Google Scholar
Furner, Mary O. 1975. Advocacy and Objectivity: A Crisis in the Professionalization of American Social Science, 1865–1905. Lexington, KY: University of Kentucky Press.Google Scholar
Furner, Mary O. 2005. Structure and Virtue in United States Political Economy. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 (March): 13–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1952. A Theory of Price Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth 1958. The Affluent Society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth 1967. The New Industrial State. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth 1981. A Life in Our Times. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Gambs, John S. 1946. Beyond Supply and Demand: A Reappraisal of Institutional Economics. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Geiger, Roger L. 1988. American Foundations and Academic Social Science, 1945–1960. Minerva 26 (3): 315–341.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gillin, John L. 1921. Poverty and Dependency. New York: Century.Google Scholar
Gillin, John L. 1926. Criminology and Penology. New York: Century.Google Scholar
Ginzberg, Eli. 1990. Economics at Columbia: Recollections of the Early 1930s. American Economist: 14–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginzberg, Eli 1997. Wesley Clair Mitchell. History of Political Economy 29 (Fall): 371–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Givens, Meredith. 1934. An Experiment in Advisory Service: The Committee on Government Statistics and Information Services. Journal of the American Statistical Association 29 (December): 394–404.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Martin G. 1927. Outlines of Public Utility Economics. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Gonce, Richard A. 2006. John R. Commons' Successful Plan for Constitutional, Effective, Labor Legislation. Journal of Economic Issues 40 (December): 1045–1067.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodrich, Carter L. 1920. The Frontier of Control: A Study of British Workshop Politics. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Howe.Google Scholar
Goodrich, Carter L. 1925. The Miner's Freedom: A Study of the Working Life in a Changing Industry. Boston: Marshall Jones.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Craufurd. 1998. The Patrons of Economics in a Time of Transformation. In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds., From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, Annual Supplement to Volume 30, History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 53–81.Google Scholar
,Graduate School of Economics and Government, Washington University. 19241925. Preliminary Announcement 1924–1925. Laura Spelman Rockefeller Memorial Archives, Record Group 3.6, Box 49, Folder 517.
Grossbard-Shechtman, Shoshana. 2001. The New Home Economics at Columbia and Chicago. Feminist Economics 7 (November): 103–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, David M. 1982. American Foundations and the Support of Economic Research, 1913–1929. Minerva 20 (1–2): 59–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groves, Harold M. 1964. Institutional Economics and Public Finance. Land Economics 40 (August): 239–246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grimmer-Solem, Erik. 2003. The Rise of Historical Economics and Social Reform in Germany 1864–1894. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruchy, Allan G. 1947. Modern Economic Thought. New York: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Gruchy, Allan G. 1950a. Keynes and the Institutionalists: Some Similarities. In Lawrence Christensen, C., ed., Economic Theory in Review. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press, pp. 96–100.Google Scholar
Gruchy, Allan G. 1950b. Keynes and the Institutionalists: Important Contrasts. In Lawrence Christensen, C., ed., Economic Theory in Review. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press, pp. 101–126.Google Scholar
Gruchy, Allan G. 1972. Contemporary Economic Thought: The Contribution of Neo-Institutionalist Economics. Clifton, NJ: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Gunning, J. Patrick. 1998. Herbert J. Davenport's Transformation of the Austrian Theory of Value and Cost. In Rutherford, Malcolm, ed., The Economic Mind in America. London: Routledge, pp. 99–127.Google Scholar
Hagemann, Harald. 2005. Dismissal, Expulsion, and Emigration of German-Speaking Economists after 1933. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 (December): 405–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1921. The “Physical Value” Fallacy in Rate Cases. Yale Law Journal 30: 710–731.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1922. “Rate Making and the Revision of the Property Concept.”Columbia Law Review 22: 209–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1923. Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State. Political Science Quarterly 38 (September): 470–494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Randal L. and Badgett, Ken. 2009. Robinson Newcomb and the Limits of Liberalism at UNC: Two Case Studies of Black Businessmen in the 1920s south. North Carolina Historical Review 86 (October): 373–403.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. nda. Control of Industrial Development. Walton Hamilton Papers, Box J4, Folder 6.
Hamilton, Walton H. ndb. The Control of Industry. Walton Hamilton Papers, Box J3, Folder 3.
Hamilton, Walton H. 1915. Economic Theory and “Social Reform.”Journal of Political Economy 23 (June): 562–584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1916a. The Development of Hoxie's Economics. Journal of Political Economy 24 (November, 1916): 855–883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1916b. Tendencies in Economic Theory – Discussion. American Economic Review 6 (March): 164–166.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1917. Problems of Economic Instruction. Journal of Political Economy 25 (January): 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1918a. The Price System and Social Policy. Journal of Political Economy 26 (January): 31–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1918b. The Place of Value Theory in Economics, I and II. Journal of Political Economy 26 (March, April): 217–245, 275–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1918c. The Requisites of a National Food Policy. Journal of Political Economy 26 (June): 612–637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1919a. The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory. American Economic Review 9 (March): 309–318.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. ed. 1919b. Current Economic Problems, revised edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1919c. The Rate of Demobilization and the Labor Market. Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science 8 (February): 323–329.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1919d. The Lapse to Laissez-Faire. The Dial 66 (April 5): 337–340.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1921. Review ofLabor and the Common Welfare; Labor and the Employer. Political Science Quarterly 36 (June): 326–329.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1922. A Theory of the Rate of Wages. Quarterly Journal of Economics 36 (August): 581–625.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1923. Education – Ritual or Adventure?The Nation 116 (June): 720–721.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1924. The Educational Policy of “A Labor College.”Social Forces 2 (January): 204–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1926a. Report to the Board of Trustees, The Robert Brookings Graduate School of Economics and Government, April 30, 1926. Appendix 3 to Harold G. Moulton, The History of the Organization of the Brookings Institution, June 1928. Brookings Institution Archives, Item 17, Formal and Informal Histories of the Brookings Institution, 1928–1966, Box 1, File: Memoranda on the Early History of the Brookings Institution.
Hamilton, Walton H. 1926b. The Problem of Bituminous Coal. American Labor Legislation Review 16: 217–229.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1927. Memorandum to Abraham Flexner: The Brookings Ventures at Washington. Appendix 12 to Harold G. Moulton, The History of the Organization of the Brookings Institution, June 1928. Brookings Institution Archives, Item 17, Formal and Informal Histories of the Brookings Institution, 1928–1966, Box 1, File: Memoranda on the Early History of the Brookings Institution.
Hamilton, Walton H. 1928a. The Plight of Soft Coal. The Nation 126 (April 4): 367–369.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1928b. The Regulation of Employment Agencies. Yale Law Journal 38 (December): 225–235.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1929a. Charles Horton Cooley. Social Forces 8 (December): 183–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1929b. Judicial Tolerance of Farmers' Cooperatives. Yale Law Journal 38 (May): 936–954.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1930a. An Economist Audits His Costs. The Survey 63 (January 1): 380–383.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1930b. Affectation with Public Interest. Yale Law Journal 39 (June): 1089–1112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1931a. Competition. Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences, Volume 4. New York: Macmillan, pp. 141–147.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1931b. The Jurist's Art. Columbia Law Review 31 (November): 1073–1093.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1931c. The Ancient Maxim Caveat Emptor. Yale Law Journal 40 (June): 1133–1187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1931d. The Legal Philosophy of Justices Holmes and Brandeis. Current History 33 (February): 654–660.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1931e. The World-Wide Depression: Ways Out. Pamphlet No. 71. New York: Foreign Policy Association.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1932a. The Control of Big Business. The Nation 134 (May 25): 591–593.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1932b. The Anti-Trust Laws and the Social Control of Business. In Handler, Milton, ed., The Federal Anti-Trust Laws: A Symposium. Chicago: Commerce Clearing House.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1932c. The Problem of Anti-Trust Reform. Columbia Law Review 32 (February): 173–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1932d. Statement by Walton H. Hamilton. In Committee on the Costs of Medical Care, Medical Care for the American People. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp.189–200.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1932e. Property According to Locke. Yale Law Journal 41 (April): 864–880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1933a. In Re The Small Debtor. Yale Law Journal 42 (February): 473–486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1933b. The Credo of Recovery. New Republic 75 (June 28): 185.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1934. Consumers' Interest in Price Fixing. Survey Graphic 23 (February): 76–80, 95–96.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1935a. Black Justice. The Nation 140 (May 1): 497.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1935b. The Consumer's Front. Survey Graphic 24 (November): 524–528, 565, 567.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1935c. Testimony of Walton Hamilton. Hearings before the Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate, 74th Congress, 1st. Session. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
Hamilton, Walton H. 1936a. Why the Price Studies?The Consumer 1 (January 15): 6–9.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1936b. The Constitution as an Instrument of Public Welfare. American Labor Legislation Review 26: 103–107.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1937. The Living Law. Survey Graphic 26 (December): 632–635, 735.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1938a. The Path of Due Process of Law. Ethics 48 (April): 269–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1938b. Cardozo the Craftsman. University of Chicago Law Review 6 (December): 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1938c. Price – By Way of Litigation. Columbia Law Review 38 (June): 1008–1036.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1938d. The Doctors' “Union.”New Republic 96 (September 7): 117–118.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1939a. Preview of a Justice. Yale Law Journal 48 (March): 819–838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1939b. Industrial Inquiry and Sectarian Dogma. American Economic Review 29 (March): 102–106.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1940a. Common Right, Due Process, and Antitrust. Law and Contemporary Problems 7 (Winter): 24–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1940b. The Pattern of Competition. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1941a. Patents and Free Enterprise. Temporary National Economic Committee, Monograph No. 31. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1941b. On Dating Mr. Justice Holmes. University of Chicago Law Review 9 (December):1–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1941c. Coal and the Economy – A Demurrer. Yale Law Journal 50 (February): 595–621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1943a. Whitewashing the Patent System. New Republic 109 (August 30): 278–279.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1943b. Property Rights in the Market. Journal of Legal and Political Sociology 2 (April): 10–33.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1944. Review of The Great Transformation, England's Service, Bureaucracy, and The Road to Serfdom. Yale Law Journal 53 (September): 805–811.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1946a. On the Composition of the Corporate Veil. Brandeis Lawyers' Society, Publication No 6. Philadelphia: Brandeis Lawyers' Society.
Hamilton, Walton H. 1946b. The Economic Man Affects a National Role. American Economic Review 36 (May): 735–744.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1949a. A New Patent Policy. Current History 17 (December): 338–341.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1949b. The Genius of the Radical. In Chase, John W., ed., Years of the Modern. New York: Longmans, Green.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1953. The Law, the Economy, and Moral Values. In Dudley Ward, A., ed., Goals of Economic Life. New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1957. The Politics of Industry. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1958. Veblen – Then and Now. In Dowd, Douglas, ed., Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Reappraisal. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. and Adair, Douglass. 1937. The Power to Govern. New York: Da Capo Press, 1972.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. and Associates, . 1938. Price and Price Policies. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. and Braden, George D.. 1941. The Special Competence of the Supreme Court. Yale Law Journal 50 (June): 1319–1375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. and May, Stacy. 1923. The Control of Wages. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1968.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. and Till, Irene. 1940a. Antitrust in Action. Temporary National Economic Committee, Monograph No. 16. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1940b. Antitrust – The Reach after New Weapons. Washington University Law Quarterly 26 (December): 1–26.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1948. What Is a Patent?Law and Contemporary Problems 13 (Spring): 245–259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. and White, John C.. 1926. A Book of Book Reviews. Washington DC: np.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. and Wright, Helen R.. 1925. The Case of Bituminous Coal. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1928. A Way of Order for Bituminous Coal. New York: Macmillan.
Hammond, Claire H. 2000a. Edith Abbott (1876–1957). In Dimand, Robert W., Dimand, Mary Ann, and Forget, Evelyn L., eds., A Biographical Dictionary of Women Economists. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 1–7.Google Scholar
Hammond, Claire H. 2000b. Sophonisba Breckinridge (1866–1948). In Dimand, Robert W., Dimand, Mary Ann and Forget, Evelyn L. eds., A Biographical Dictionary of Women Economists. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 81–88.Google Scholar
Hammond, J. Daniel. 1996. Theory and Measurement: Causality Issues in Milton Friedman's Monetary Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, J. Daniel 2001. Columbia Roots of the Chicago School: The Case of Milton Friedman. Paper Presented at the ASSA Meetings, New Orleans, January 2001.
Hands, D. Wade. 2004. On Operationalism in Economics. Journal of Economic Issues 38 (December): 953–968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hands, D. Wade 2006. Frank Knight and Pragmatism. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 13 (December): 571–605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Alvin H. 1927. Business Cycle Theory, Its Development and Present Status. Boston: Ginn.Google Scholar
Hansen, Alvin H. 1932. The Contributions of Professor John R. Commons to American Economics. Alvin Hansen Papers, Harvard University Archives, HUGFP – 3.42, Box 1.
Hansen, Alvin H. 1947. Two Interpretations of Keynesian Economics: Dr. Burns on Keynesian Economics. Review of Economic Statistics 29 (November): 247–252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Alvin H. and Murray, Merrill G.. 1933. A New Plan for Unemployment Reserves. Minneapolis: Employment Stabilization Research Institute, University of Minnesota.Google Scholar
Harris, Abram L. 1932. Types of Institutionalism. Journal of Political Economy 40 (December): 721–749.Google Scholar
Harris, Abram L. 1934. Economic Evolution: Dialectical and Darwinian. Journal of Political Economy 42 (February): 34–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harter, Lafayette G. 1962. John R. Commons: His Assault on Laissez-Faire. Corvallis, OR: Oregon State University.Google Scholar
Hastay, M. 1951. Review of Koopmans, T. C., ed., Statistical Inference in Dynamic Economic Models. Journal of the American Statistical Association 46 (September): 388–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hawley, Ellis W. 1966. The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayes, Edward C., ed. 1927. Recent Developments in the Social Sciences. Philadelphia: Lippencott.
Heaton, Herbert. 1952. A Scholar in Action: Edwin F. Gay. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herbst, Jurgen. 1965. The German Historical School in American Scholarship. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1932. The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. and Allen, R. G. D.. 1934. A Reconsideration of the Theory of Value. Economica NS 1 (February and May): 52–76, 196–219.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Abraham and DeMarchi, Neil. 1990. Milton Friedman: Economics in Theory and Practice. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschfield, Mary L. 1998. Methodological Stance and Consumption Theory: A Lesson in Feminist Methodology. In Davis, John B., ed., New Economics and its History. Annual Supplement to Volume 29 History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 191–211.Google Scholar
Hirshfeld, Daniel S. 1970. The Lost Reform: The Campaign for Compulsory Health Insurance in the United States from 1932 to 1943. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2001. How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2004. The Evolution of Institutional Economics. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homan, Paul T. 1928. Contemporary Economic Thought. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Homan, Paul T. 1932. An Appraisal of Institutional Economics. American Economic Review 22 (March): 10–17.Google Scholar
Homan, Paul T. 1937. The Institutional School. Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences, volume 5, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Howlett, Charles F. 2003. David J. Saposs. American National Biography Online. http://www.anb.org/articles/14/14–01131.html
Hoxie, Robert F. 1901. On the Empirical Method of Economic Instruction. Journal of Political Economy 9 (September): 481–526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoxie, Robert F. 1907. The Trade Union Point of View. Journal of Political Economy 15 (June): 345–363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoxie, Robert F. 1908. President Gompers and the Labor Vote. Journal of Political Economy 16 (December): 693–700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoxie, Robert F. 1915. Scientific Management and Labor. New York: D. Appleton.Google Scholar
Hoxie, Robert F. 1917. Trade Unionism in the United States. New York: D. Appleton.Google Scholar
Hurley, Jack F. 1972. Portrait of a Decade: Roy Stryker and the Development of Documentary Photography in the Thirties. Baton Rouge, LA: Louisiana State University.Google Scholar
Innis, Harold A. 1929. A Bibliography of Thorstein Veblen. Southwestern Political and Social Science Quarterly 10 (June): 56–68.Google Scholar
Ise, John. 1932. Recent Textbooks on Economics and Their Trend. Quarterly Journal of Economics 46 (February): 385–397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Alvin. 1952. Pioneer's Progress. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Jorgensen, Elizabeth and Jorgensen, Henry. 1999. Thorstein Veblen: Victorian Firebrand. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. 1974. Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Science 185 (September): 1124–1131.Google Scholar
Kantor, J. R. 1922. An Essay Toward an Institutional Conception of Social Psychology. American Journal of Sociology 27 (March): 611–627; (May): 758–779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantor, J. R. 1924. The Institutional Foundation of a Scientific Social Psychology. American Journal of Sociology 29 (May): 674–687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kapp, William K. 1950. The Social Costs of Private Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kapp, William K. 1976. The Nature and Significance of Institutional Economics. Kyklos 29 (2): 209–232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kates, Steven. 2008. The American Roots and Origins of the General Theory. Paper Presented at the History of Economics Society Meetings.
Kaufman, Bruce E. 1993. The Origins and Evolution of the Field of Industrial Relations in the United States. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.Google Scholar
Kaufman, Bruce E. 2003. John R. Commons and the Wisconsin School on Industrial Relations Strategy and Policy. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 57 (October): 3–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, Bruce E. 2004. The Institutional and Neoclassical Schools in Labor Economics. In Champlin, Dell P. and Knoedler, Janet T., eds., The Institutionalist Tradition in Labor Economics. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, pp. 13–38.Google Scholar
Kay, Lily E. 1997. Rethinking Institutions: Philanthropy as an Historiographic Problem of Knowledge and Power. Minerva 35 (3): 283–293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keaney, Michael. 2000. The Radical Political Economics of Douglas F. Dowd. Journal of Economic Issues 34 (March): 117–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keezer, Dexter M. 1934. The Consumer under the National Recovery Administration. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 172 (March): 88–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keezer, Dexter M., Cutler, Addison T., and Garfield, Frank R.. 1928. Problem Economics. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Keezer, Dexter M. and May, Stacy. 1930. The Public Control of Business. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Kerr, Clark. 1988. The Neoclassical Revisionists in Labor Economics (1940–1960) – R.I.P. In Kaufman, Bruce E., ed., How Labor Markets Work: Reflections on Theory and Practice by John Dunlop, Clark Kerr, Richard Lester, and Lloyd Reynolds. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. 1941. Letter to J. M. Clark. In Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. XXIII. London: Macmillan, pp. 192–193.Google Scholar
Keyserling, Leon H. 1972. The Keynesian Revolution and Its Pioneers – Discussion. American Economic Review 62 (1/2): 134–138.Google Scholar
King, Willford I. 1923. Employment, Hours, and Earnings in Prosperity and Depression. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Kitch, Edmund W., ed. 1983. The Fire of Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago, 1923–1970. Journal of Law and Economics 26 (April): 163–234.CrossRef
Knapp, Joseph G. 1979. Edwin G. Nourse: Economist for the People. Danville, IL: Interstate Publishers.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank, H. 1920. Review of The Place of Science in Modern Civilization by T. Veblen. Journal of Political Economy 28 (June): 518–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Frank, H. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank, H. (1924) 1935. The Limitations of Scientific Method in Economics. In The Ethics of Competition and Other Essays. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 105–147.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank, H. (1928) 1956. Historical and Theoretical Issues in the Problem of Modern Capitalism. In On The History and Method of Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 89–103.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank, H. 1932. The Newer Economics and the Control of Economic Activity. Journal of Political Economy 40 (August): 433–476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Frank, H. 1935. Review of John R. Commons'sInstitutional Economics. Columbia Law Review 35 (May): 803–805.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank, H. 1951. The Economic Organization. New York: A. M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Koopmans, Tjalling C. 1947. Measurement without Theory. Review of Economic Statistics 29 (August): 161–172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. 1934. National Income: 1929–1932. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon 1936. Review of the Formation of Capital by Harold G. Moulton and Income and Economic Progress by Harold G. Moulton. Political Science Quarterly 51 (June): 300–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, Simon 1937. National Income and Capital Formation, 1919–1935: A Preliminary Report. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon 1942. Uses of National Income in Peace and War. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon 1963. The Contribution of Wesley C. Mitchell. In Dorfman, Joseph, et al., Institutional Economics. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, pp. 95–122.Google Scholar
Kyrk, Hazel. 1923. A Theory of Consumption. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Kyrk, Hazel 1933. Economic Problems of the Family. New York: Harper and Brothers.Google Scholar
Lagemann, Ellen C. 1989. The Politics of Knowledge: The Carnegie Corporation, Philanthropy, and Public Policy. Middletown, CT: Wesleyan University Press.Google Scholar
Laidler, David. 1999. Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution: Studies of the Inter-war Literature on Money, the Cycle, and Unemployment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lampman, Robert J., ed. 1993. Economists at Wisconsin, 1892–1992. Madison, WI: Board of Regents of the University of Wisconsin System.
Landreth, Harry and Colander, David C.. 1994. History of Economic Thought, 3rd. edition. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Lange, Dorothea and Taylor, Paul S.. 1939. An American Exodus. New York: Reynal and Hitchcock.Google Scholar
Lee, Frederic S. 1990. From Multi-Industry Planning to Keynesian Planning: Gardiner Means, the American Keynesians, and National Economic Planning at the National Resources Committee. Journal of Policy History 2 (2): 186–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Frederic S. 1997. Philanthropic Foundations and the Rehabilitation of Big Business, 1934–1977: A Case Study of Directed Economic Research. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 15: 51–90.Google Scholar
Lee, Frederic S. and Samuels, Warren J., eds. 1992. The Heterodox Economics of Gardiner C. Means. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.
Leeson, Robert. 1997. The Eclipse of the Goal of Zero Inflation. History of Political Economy 29 (Fall): 445–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, Robert 1998. The Early Patinkin-Friedman Correspondence. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20 (December): 433–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, Robert 2000. The Eclipse of Keynesianism: The Political Economy of the Chicago Counter-Revolution. New York: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leiter, B. 2001. Llewellyn, Karl Nickerson (1893–1962). International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Sciences. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 8999–9001.Google Scholar
Lerner, Max. 1931. The Social Thought of Mr. Justice Brandeis. Yale Law Journal 41 (November): 1–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, Max 1935. What Is Useable in Veblen?New Republic 83 (May): 7–10.Google Scholar
Lerner, Max 1948. The Portable Veblen. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Lescohier, Don D. 1919. The Labor Market. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lester, Richard A. 1941. Economics of Labor. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lester, Richard A. 1946. Shortcomings of Marginal Analysis for Wage-Employment Problems. American Economic Review 36 (March): 63–82.Google Scholar
Lester, Richard A. 1947. Marginalism, Minimum Wages and Labor Markets. American Economic Review 37 (March): 135–148Google Scholar
Levin, Maurice, Moulton, Harold, and Warburton, Clark. 1934. America's Capacity to Consume. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Lewin, Shira. 1996. Economics and Psychology: Lessons for Our Own Day from the Early Twentieth Century. Journal of Economic Literature 35 (September): 1293–1323.Google Scholar
Lewinson, Paul. 1932. Race, Class and Party: A History of Negro Suffrage and White Politics in the South. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lewinson, Paul 1947. A Guide to Documents in the National Archives for Negro Studies. Washington, DC: The American Council for Learned Societies.Google Scholar
Lind, Hans. 1993. The Myth of Institutionalist Method. Journal of Economic Issues 27 (March): 1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llewellyn, Karl N. 1925. The Effect of Legal Institutions upon Economics. American Economic Review 15 (December): 665–683.Google Scholar
Llewellyn, Karl N. 1930. A Realistic Jurisprudence – The Next Step. Columbia Law Review 30: 431–465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llewellyn, Karl N. 1931. What Price Contract? – An Essay in Perspective. Yale Law Journal 40: 704–751.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lobdell, Richard A. 2000. Helen Laura Sumner Woodbury (1876–1933). In Dimand, Robert W., Dimand, Mary Ann, and Forget, Evelyn L., eds., A Biographical Dictionary of Women Economists. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 46–48.Google Scholar
Lubin, Isador. 1924. Miner's Wages and the Cost of Coal. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Lubin, Isador and Everett, Helen. 1927. The British Coal Dilemma. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Lynd, Robert. 1934. A New Deal for the Consumer?New Republic 177 (January 3): 220–222.Google Scholar
Lynd, Robert 1936. Democracy's Third Estate: The Consumer. Political Science Quarterly 51 (December): 481–515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lynd, Robert 1939. Knowledge for What?Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lyon, Leverett S. 1927. Report to the Board of Trustees, The Robert Brookings Graduate School of Economics and Government, April 30, 1926. Appendix 10 to Harold G. Moulton, The History of the Organization of the Brookings Institution, June 1928. Brookings Institution Archives, Item 17, Formal and Informal Histories of the Brookings Institution, 1928–1966, Box 1, File: Memoranda on the Early History of the Brookings Institution.
Lyon, Leverett S., et al. 1935. The National Recovery Administration: An Analysis and Appraisal. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Machlup, Fritz. 1946. Marginal Analysis and Empirical Research. American Economic Review 36 (September): 519–554.Google Scholar
Marschak, Jacob. 1941. A Discussion on Methods in Economics. Journal of Political Economy 49 (June), 441–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Leon C. 1918. Readings in Industrial Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, Leon C., Wright, Chester W., and Field, James A., eds. 1913. Materials for the Study of Elementary Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Mason, Edward S. 1939. Price and Output Policies of Large Scale Enterprise. American Economic Review 29 (March): 61–74.Google Scholar
Mayhew, Anne. 1998. How American Economists Came to Love the Sherman Antitrust Act. In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds., From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, Annual Supplement to Volume 30, History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 179–201.Google Scholar
McAllister, Breck P. 1930. Lord Hale and Business Affected with a Public Interest. Harvard Law Review 43 (March): 759–791.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCarthy, Charles. 1912. The Wisconsin Idea. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
McCracken, H. L. 1933. Value Theory and Business Cycles. New York: Falcon Press.Google Scholar
McDougall, William. 1908. An Introduction to Social Psychology. London: Methuen.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDougall, William 1924. Can Sociology and Social Psychology Dispense with Instincts?American Journal of Sociology 29 (May): 657–673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMahon, Theresa S. 1912. Women and Economic Evolution. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Bulletin no. 496.Google Scholar
McMahon, Theresa S. 1925. Social and Economic Standards of Living. Boston: D. C. Heath.Google Scholar
McNulty, Paul J. 1973. Hoxie's Economics in Retrospect: The Making and Unmaking of a Veblenian. History of Political Economy 5 (Fall): 449–484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Means, Gardiner C. 1934. The Consumer and the New Deal. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 173 (May): 7–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Means, Gardiner C. 1935. Industrial Prices and Their Relative Inflexibility. Senate Document 13, 74th Congress, 1st Session. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
Means, Gardiner C. 1939. The Structure of the American Economy: Part I, Basic Characteristics. Washington, DC: National Resources Committee.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 1998. Wandering the Road from Pluralism to Posner: The Transformation of Law and Economics in the Twentieth Century. In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds., From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, Annual Supplement to Volume 30, History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 202–224.Google Scholar
Mehrling, Perry G. 1997. The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought 1920–1970. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Millar, James R. 1980. Institutionalism from a Natural Science Point of View: An Intellectual Profile of Morris A. Copeland. In Adams, John, ed., Institutional Economics: Essays in Honor of Allan G. Gruchy. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff, pp. 105–124.Google Scholar
Mills, Frederick, C. (1924a) 1971. On Measurement in Economics. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 37–70.Google Scholar
Mills, Frederick, C. 1924b. Statistical Methods. New York: Holt.Google Scholar
Mills, Frederick, C. 1927. The Behavior of Prices. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Mills, Frederick, C. 1929. Price Movements and Related Industrial Changes. In Recent Economic Changes, Report of the Committee on Recent Economic Changes of the President's Conference on Unemployment. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Mills, Frederick, C. 1932. Economic Tendencies in the United States. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Mills, Frederick, C. 1936. Prices in Recession and Recovery. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 1987. The Philosophical Bases of Institutionalist Economics. Journal of Economic Issues 21 (September): 1001–1038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip 1990. Problems in the Paternity of Econometrics: Henry Ludwell Moore. History of Political Economy 22 (Winter): 587–609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip 2002. Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Lucy Sprague. 1953. Two Lives: The Story of Wesley Clair Mitchell and Myself. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1910a. The Rationality of Economic Activity, I. Journal of Political Economy 18 (February): 97–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1910b. The Rationality of Economic Activity, II. Journal of Political Economy 18 (March): 197–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1910c. Money Economy and Modern Civilization (Paper Read Before the Cross-Roads Club of Stanford, May 6, 1910). Edited by Rutherford, Malcolm, History of Political Economy 28 (Fall 1996): 329–357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1912. The Backward Art of Spending Money. American Economic Review 2 (June): 269–281.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1913. Business Cycles. Berkeley CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1914. Human Behavior and Economics: A Survey of Recent Literature. Quarterly Journal of Economics 29 (November): 1–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1915) 1950. Wieser's Theory of Social Economics. In Mitchell, Wesley C., The Backward Art of Spending Money. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 225–257.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1916. The Role of Money in Economic Theory. American Economic Review 6 (March): 140–161.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1918) 1950. Bentham's Felicific Calculus. In Mitchell, Wesley C., The Backward Art of Spending Money. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 177–202.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. ed. 1919. History of Prices During the War. War Industries Board Price Bulletins Nos. 1–57. Washington DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1919) 1950. Statistics and Government. In Mitchell, Wesley C., The Backward Art of Spending Money. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 42–57.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1923a) 1950. Making Goods and Making Money. In Mitchell, Wesley C., The Backward Art of Spending Money. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, pp.137–148.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. ed. 1923b. Business Cycles and Unemployment. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1924a. Commons on the Legal Foundations of Capitalism. American Economic Review 14 (June): 240–253.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1924b) 1971. The Prospects of Economics. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 1–34.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1925. Quantitative Analysis in Economic Theory. American Economic Review 15 (March): 1–12.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1927. Business Cycles: The Problem and Its Setting. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1928a) 1936. Letter from Wesley C. Mitchell to John M. Clark. In Clark, J. M.Preface to Social Economics. New York: Farrar and Rinehart, pp. 410–416.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1928b. The Present Status and Future Prospects of Quantitative Economics. American Economic Review, Supplement,18 (March): 39–41.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1929a. Sombart's Hochkapitalismus. Quarterly Journal of Economics 43 (February): 303–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1929b. Thorstein Veblen, 1857–1929. New Republic 60 (September 4), 66–68.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1935. Foreword. In Grether, Ewald T., et al., eds., Essays in Social Economics in Honor of Jessica Blanche Peixotto. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, pp. 1–4.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1936a. Thorstein Veblen. In Mitchell, Wesley C., ed., What Veblen Taught. New York: Viking, pp. vii–xlix.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. (1936b) 1950. Intelligence and the Guidance of Economic Evolution. In The Backward Art of Spending Money. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 103–136.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1939. The National Bureau's Social Function. NBER Annual Report. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1944. Facts and Values in Economics. Journal of Philosophy 41 (April): 212–219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1949. Types of Economic Theory, 2 vols., (stenographic notes from 1934/35). New York: Augustus Kelley.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1967/1969. Types of Economic Theory, 2 vols., edited by Dorfman, Joseph. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C., King, Willford I., Macaulay, Frederick R., and Knauth, Oswald W.. 1921. Income in the United States: Its Amount and Distribution, 1909–1919, Volume I: Summary. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C. 1922. Income in the United States: Its Amount and Distribution, 1909–1919, Volume II: Detailed Report. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Mongin, Philippe. 1992. The “Full Cost” Controversy of the 1940s and 1950s: A Methodological Assessment. History of Political Economy 24 (Summer): 311–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mongiovi, Gary. 2005. Émigré Economists and American Neoclassical Economics, 1933–1945. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 (December): 427–437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, Harry H. 1927. American Medicine and the Peoples' Health. New York: Appleton.Google Scholar
Moore, Harry H. 1933. Health and Medical Practice. In Recent Social Trends in the United States. President's Research Committee on Social Trends. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Moore, Henry L. 1908. The Statistical Complement of Pure Economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 23 (November): 1–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, W. Underhill and Hope, Theodore S.. 1929. An Institutional Approach to the Law of Commercial Banking. Yale Law Journal 38 (April): 703–719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morehouse, E. W. 1923. Development of Industrial Law in the Rochester Clothing Market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 37 (February): 257–290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. 1990. The History of Econometric Ideas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds. 1998. From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, Annual Supplement to Volume 30 of History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
Moulton, Harold G. 1928. The History of the Organization of the Brookings Institution, with 24 Appendices, June 1928. Brookings Institution Archives, Item 17, Formal and Informal Histories of the Brookings Institution, 1928–1966, Box 1, File: Memoranda on the Early History of the Brookings Institution.
Moulton, Harold G. 1935a. The Formation of Capital. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Moulton, Harold G. 1935b. Income and Economic Progress. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Moulton, Harold G. 1943. The New Philosophy of Public Debt. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Moulton, Harold G. 1949. Controlling Factors in Economic Development. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Mund, Vernon. 1938. Review of Hamilton and AssociatesPrice and Price Policies. American Economic Review 28 (December): 818–820.Google Scholar
Myrdal, Gunnar. 1972. Against the Stream: Critical Essays in Economics. New York: Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
,National Bureau of Economic Research. 1926. Bulletin (May 10). http://www.nber.org/newsbulletin/
,National Bureau of Economic Research. 1930. Annual Report of the President and Director of Research. http://www.nber.org/nberhistory/annualreports.html
,National Bureau of Economic Research 1935. Bulletin (July 1). http://www.nber.org/newsbulletin/
Nef, John U. 1934. James Laurence Laughlin (1850–1933). Journal of Political Economy 42 (February): 1–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nef, John U. 1973. Search for Meaning: The Autobiography of a Nonconformist. Washington DC: Public Affairs Press.Google Scholar
Neill, Robin. 1972. A New Theory of Value: The Canadian Economics of H. A. Innis. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, Ralph L. 1966. Economic Research Sponsored by Private Foundations. American Economic Review 56 (May): 519–529.Google Scholar
Nourse, Edwin G. 1944. Price Making in a Democracy. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Nourse, Edwin G. and Associates, . 1934. America's Capacity to Produce. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Nutter, G. Warren. 1951. The Extent of Enterprise Monopoly in the United States, 1899–1939. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Nyland, Chris. 1996. Taylorism, John R. Commons, and the Hoxie Report. Journal of Economic Issues 30 (December): 985–1016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ogburn, William F. 1919. The Psychological Basis for the Economic Interpretation of History. American Economic Review 9 (March): 291–308.Google Scholar
Ogburn, William F. 1922. Social Change with Respect to Culture and Original Nature. New York: Huebsch.Google Scholar
Ogburn, William F. and Goldenweiser, Alexander, eds. 1927. The Social Sciences and Their Interrelations. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Oser, Jacob and Brue, Stanley L.. 1988. The Evolution of Economic Thought, 4th. edition. San Diego, CA: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Panunzio, Constantine, M. 1927. Immigration Crossroads. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Parker, Carleton H. 1920. The Causal Laborer and Other Essays. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Howe.Google Scholar
Parker, Cornelia S. 1919. An American Idyll. Boston: Atlantic Monthly Press.Google Scholar
Parker, Cornelia S. 1922. Working with the Working Woman. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Parker, Cornelia S. 1934. Wanderer's Circle. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Parker, Richard. 2005. John Kenneth Galbraith: His Life, His Politics, His Economics. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Parrish, John B. 1967. The Rise of Economics as an Academic Discipline: The Formative Years to 1900. Southern Economic Journal 34 (July): 1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Kenneth H. 1942. John R. Commons' Point of View. Journal of Land and Public Utility Economics 18 (August): 245–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Kenneth H. 1976. Interview by Laura Small. University of Wisconsin-Madison Archives, Oral History Project, interview #081.
Parsons, Talcott. 1928/1929. Capitalism in Recent German Literature: Sombart and Weber: Parts I and II. Journal or Political Economy 36 (December): 641–664, 37 (February): 31–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott 1934. Some Reflections on “The Nature and Significance of Economics.”Quarterly Journal of Economics 48 (May): 511–545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott 1935. Sociological Elements in Economic Thought. Quarterly Journal of Economics 49 (May): 414–453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott 1959. A Short Account of my Intellectual Development. Alpha Kappa Delta 29 (Winter): 3–12.Google Scholar
Parsons, Talcott 1976. Clarence Ayres's Economics and Sociology. In Breit, William and Culbertson, William Patton, eds., Science and Ceremony: The Institutional Economics of C. E. Ayres. Austin: University of Texas Press, pp. 175–179.Google Scholar
Parsons, Talcott and Cutler, Addison T.. 1923. A Word From Amherst Students. Reprinted in Camic, Charles, ed., Talcott Parsons, The Early Essays. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991, pp. 287–292.Google Scholar
Peck, Gustav and Galloway, George B.. 1928. On the Dissolution of the Robert Brookings Graduate School. The Survey (May 15): 229–231.Google Scholar
Peixotto, Jessica B. 1927. Getting and Spending at the Professional Standard of Living. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Perkins, A. J. G. and Wolfson, Theresa. 1939. Frances Wright, Free Enquirer. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Perkins, B. B. 1998. Economic Organization of Medicine and the Committee on the Costs of Medical Care. American Journal of Public Health 88: 1721–1726.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perlman, Mark, ed. 1971. Carter Goodrich, 1897–1971. Np.
Perlman, Mark, 2001. Two Phases of Kuznets' Interest in Schumpeter. In Biddle, Jeff E., Davis, John B., and Medema, Steven G., eds., Economics Broadly Considered: Essays in Honor of Warren J. Samuels. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Perlman, Selig. 1928. A Theory of the Labor Movement. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Persky, Joseph. 2000. The Neoclassical Advent: American Economics at the Dawn of the 20th Century. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (Winter): 95–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, Almarin and Stevenson, Rodney E.. 1974. The Historical Development of Industrial Organization. History of Political Economy 6 (Fall): 324–342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, Ronnie J. 1995. Economic Mavericks: The Texas Institutionalists. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Pigou, Arthur C. 1912. Wealth and Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, Arthur C. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pittenger, Mark. 1997. A World of Difference: Constructing the “Underclass” in Progressive America. American Quarterly 49 (March): 26–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polanyi, Karl, Arensberg, Conrad, and Pearson, Harry, eds. 1957. Trade and Market in Early Empires. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Porter, Theodore M. 1994. Rigour and Practicality: Rival Ideas of Quantification in Nineteenth Century Economics. In Mirowski, Philip, ed., Natural Images in Economic Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 128–170.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1995. Overcoming Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Prasch, Robert E. 2007. Professor Lester and the Neoclassicals: The “Marginalist Controversy” and the Postwar Academic Debate Over Minimum Wage Legislation: 1945–1950. Journal of Economic Issues 41 (September): 809–825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,President's Research Committee on Social Trends. 1933. Recent Social Trends in the United States. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Quine, W. V. 1985. The Time of My Life. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Rader, Benjamin G. 1966. The Academic Mind and Reform: The Influence of Richard T. Ely in American Life. Lexington, KY: University of Kentucky.Google Scholar
Raushenbush, Paul A. and Raushenbush, Elizabeth Brandeis. 1979. Our “U. C.” Story. Madison, WI: np.Google Scholar
Reder, Melvin W. 1982. Chicago Economics: Permanence and Change. Journal of Economic Literature 20 (March): 1–38.Google Scholar
Reid, Margaret G. 1934. The Economics of Household Production. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
,Report of the Columbia University Committee. 1934. Economic Reconstruction. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Reynolds, Lloyd. 1949. Labor Economics and Labor Relations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Rice, Stuart A., ed. 1931. Methods in Social Science: A Case Book. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Rice, Stuart A. 1933. Committee on Governmental Statistics and Information Services. Journal of the American Statistical Association 28 (September): 333–334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, Theresa and Fisher, Donald. 1999. Introduction: The Social Sciences and Their Philanthropic Mentors. In Richardson, Theresa and Fisher, Donald, eds., The Development of the Social Sciences in the United States and Canada: The Role of Philanthropy. Stamford, CT: Ablex.Google Scholar
Riefler, Winfield W. 1930. Money Rates and Money Markets in the United States. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Rima, Ingrid H. 1996. Development of Economic Analysis, 5th. edition. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ripley, William Z. 1927. Main Street and Wall Street. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1932. The Nature and Significance of Economic Science. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
,Robert Brookings Graduate School of Economics and Government. 1928. General Catalogue 1923–1928. Washington, DC. Appendix 23 to Harold G. Moulton, The History of the Organization of the Brookings Institution, June 1928. Brookings Institution Archives, Item 17, Formal and Informal Histories of the Brookings Institution, 1928–1966, Box 1, File: Memoranda on the Early History of the Brookings Institution.
,Robert Brookings Graduate School of Economics and Government. The Institute of Economics, The Institute for Government Research. 1924–1925. Personnel. Walton H. Hamilton Papers, Box J9, Folder 5.
,Robert Brookings Graduate School of Economics and Government, The Institute of Economics, The Institute for Government Research. 1927–1928. Personnel. Walton H. Hamilton Papers, Box J9, Folder 5.
Robinson, Joan. 1933. The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ross, Dorothy. 1991. The Origins of American Social Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ross, Edward A. 1901. Social Control. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ross, Edward A. 1920. Principles of Sociology. New York: Century.Google Scholar
Ross, Joseph S. 2002. The Committee on the Costs of Medical Care and the History of Health Insurance in the United States. The Einstein Quarterly Journal of Biology and Medicine 19: 129–134.Google Scholar
Rostow, Eugene V. 1941. Bituminous Coal and the Public Interest. Yale Law Journal 50 (February): 543–594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 1981. Clarence Ayres and the Instrumental Theory of Value. Journal of Economic Issues 15 (September): 657–673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 1987. Wesley Mitchell: Institutions and Quantitative Methods. Eastern Economic Journal 13 (1): 63–73.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 1994a. Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 1994b. J. A. Hobson and American Institutionalism: Underconsumption and Technological Change. In Pheby, John, ed., J. A. Hobson after Fifty Years. London: Macmillan, pp. 188–210.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 1997. American Institutionalism and the History of Economics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19 (Fall): 178–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 1998. Thorstein Veblen's Evolutionary Programme: A Promise Unfulfilled. Cambridge Journal of Economics 22 (July): 463–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 1999. Institutionalism as “Scientific” Economics. In Backhouse, Roger and Creedy, John, eds., From Classical Economics to the Theory of the Firm: Essays in Honour of D. P. O'Brien. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, pp. 223–242.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2000a. Institutionalism between the Wars. Journal of Economic Issues 34 (June): 291–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2000b. Understanding Institutional Economics: 1918–1929. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 (3): 277–308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2001. Institutional Economics: Then and Now. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (Summer): 173–194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2002. Morris A. Copeland: A Case Study in the History of Institutional Economics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 24 (September): 261–290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2003. On the Economic Frontier: Walton Hamilton, Institutional Economics and Education. History of Political Economy 35 (Winter): 611–653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2004. Institutional Economics at Columbia University. History of Political Economy 36 (Spring): 31–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2005a. ‘Who's Afraid of Arthur Burns?’ The NBER and the Foundations. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 (June): 109–139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2005b. Walton H. Hamilton and the Public Control of Business. In Medema, Steven and Boettke, Peter, eds., The Role of Government in the History of Political Economy, Supplement to volume 37, History of Political Economy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, pp. 234–273.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2006. Wisconsin Institutionalism: John R. Commons and His Students. Labor History, 47 (May): 161–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2007. American Institutionalism and Its British Connections. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 14 (June): 291–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm 2009. Did Commons Have Few Followers?Journal of Economic Issues 43 (June): 441–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm Forthcoming. The USDA Graduate School: Government Instruction in Statistics and Economics, 1921–1945. Journal of the History of Economic Thought.
Rutherford, Malcolm and DesRoches, Tyler C.. 2008. The Institutionalist Reaction to Keynesian Economics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 30 (March): 29–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm, Samuels, Warren J., and Whalen, Charles J.. 2008. Introduction to John R. Commons'sReasonable Value. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 26-B: 223–233.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. 1967. Edwin E. Witte's Concept of the Role of Government in the Economy. Land Economics 43 (May): 131–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. 1973. The Economy as a System of Power and Its Legal Bases: The Legal Economics of Robert Lee Hale. University of Miami Law Review 27 (Spring and Summer): 261–371.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J, ed. 2004. Wisconsin “Government and Business.”Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 22-C.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1938. A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumer's Behaviour. Economica 5 (February): 61–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Saposs, David J. 1926. Left-Wing Unionism: A Study of Radical Policies and Tactics. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
Saposs, David J. 1931. The Labor Movement in Post-War France. New York: Columbia University.Google Scholar
Saposs, David J. 1960. The Wisconsin Heritage and the Study of Labor – Works and Deeds of John R. Commons. School for Workers 35th Anniversary Papers. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin, University Extension Division, School for Workers.Google Scholar
Sass, Steven A. 1982. The Pragmatic Imagination: A History of the Wharton School, 1881–1981. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sawyer, Steven. 2004. The Influence of Thorstein Veblen's Theory of Business Enterprise on the Economic Theories of Edward Chamberlin. Journal of Economic Issues 38 (June): 553–561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scherer, F. M. 2000. The Emigration of German-Speaking Economists after 1933. Journal of Economic Literature 38 (September): 614–626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlabach, Theron F. 1969. Edwin E. Witte: Cautious Reformer. Madison, WI: State Historical Society of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Schlabach, Theron F. 2001. Rationality and Welfare: Public Discussion of Poverty and Social Insurance in the United States 1875–1935. http://www.ssa.gov/history/reports/schlabach.htmlGoogle Scholar
Schlegel, John H. 1995. American Legal Realism and Empirical Social Science. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Schmid, A. Allan. 2004. The Spartan School of Political Economy at Michigan State University. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 22-C, pp. 207–243.Google Scholar
Schultz, Henry. 1928. Statistical Laws of Demand and Supply. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Schultz, Henry 1935. Correct and Incorrect Methods of Determining the Effectiveness of the Tariff. Journal of Farm Economics 17 (November): 625–641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Henry (1937) 2000. The Quantitative Method with Special Reference to Economic Inquiry. Lecture given to the Division of Social Sciences, 1937. Edited by Luca Fiorito and Warren Samuels, Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology: Twentieth Century Economics 18-C: 343–355.Google Scholar
Schwartz, A. 2000. Karl Llewellyn and the Origins of Contract Theory. In Kraus, J. and Walt, S., eds., The Jurisprudential Foundations of Corporate and Commercial Law. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Seager, Henry R. 1910. Social Insurance. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Seager, Henry R. and Gulick, Charles A.. 1929. Trusts and Corporation Problems. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Shute, Laurence. 1997. John Maurice Clark: A Social Economics for the Twenty-First Century. New York: St. Martin's.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert. 1955. A Behaviorial Model of Rational Choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69 (February): 99–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simons, Henry C. 1934. A Positive Program for Laissez Faire: Some Proposals for a Liberal Economic Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, Robert.John Maynard Keynes: The Economist as Saviour, 1920–1937. London: Macmillan, 1992.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. (1924) 1971. The Organization and Control of Economic Activity. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 303–355.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1928. The Price of Industrial Progress. New Republic 53 (February 8): 316–318.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1931. Modern Economic Society. New York: H. Holt.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1934. The Economics of Public Works. American Economic Review 24 (March): 174–185.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. (1937) 1961. Safeguards Against Depression: An Analysis of Depression Cures. In Potentials of the American Economy: Selected Essays of Sumner H. Slichter. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1961. Potentials of the American Economy: Selected Essays of Sumner H. Slichter. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soule, George. (1924) 1971. Economics – Science and Art. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 359–367.Google Scholar
Sowell, Thomas. 1993. A Student's Eye View of George Stigler. Journal of Political Economy 101 (October): 784–792.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stapleford, Thomas A. 2006. Market Visions: Liberal Reform and the Study of Consumption in the New Deal. Mimeo.
Sternsher, Bernard. 1964. Rexford Tugwell and the New Deal. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
Stewart, Walter W. 1917. Social Value and the Theory of Money. Journal of Political Economy 25 (December): 984–1002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stewart, Walter W. 1919. Economic Theory – Discussion. American Economic Review 9 (March): 319–320.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1947a. The Kinky Oligopoly Demand Curve and Rigid Prices. Journal of Political Economy 55 (June): 432–449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1947b. Professor Lester and the Marginalists. American Economic Review 37 (March): 154–157.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1954. The Economist Plays with Blocs. American Economic Review 44 (May): 7–14.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. and Becker, Gary S.. 1977. De Gustibus non est Disputandum. American Economic Review 67 (March): 76–90.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. and Friedland, C.. 1983. The Literature of Economics: The Case of Berle and Means. Journal of Law and Economics 26 (January): 237–268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J. and Kindahl, James K.. 1970. The Behavior of Industrial Prices. New York: Columbia University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Stigler, Stephen M. 1994. Some Correspondence between Milton Friedman and Edwin B. Wilson; November-December 1946. Journal of Economic Literature 32 (September): 1197–1203.Google Scholar
Stocking, George Ward. 1925. The Oil Industry and the Competitive System: A Study in Waste. Boston and New York: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Stocking, George Ward and Watkins, Myron W.. 1946. Cartels in Action. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.Google Scholar
Stocking, George Ward and Watkins, Myron W. 1948. Cartels or Competition. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.Google Scholar
Stone, Richard. 1947. Definition and Measurement of the National Income and Related Topics. Appendix to Measurement of National Income and the Construction of Social Accounts, Report of the Sub-Committee on National Income Statistics of the League of Nations Committee of Statistical Experts. Geneva: United Nations.Google Scholar
Street, James H. 1988. The Contribution of Simon S. Kuznets to Institutional Development Theory. Journal of Economic Issues 22 (June): 499–509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swisher, Carl Brent. 1930. Stephen J. Field: Craftsman of the Law. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Swisher, Carl Brent 1943. American Constitutional Development. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Tannenbaum, Frank. 1929. The Mexican Agrarian Revolution. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Tannenbaum, Frank 1933. Peace by Revolution: An Interpretation of Mexico. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Tannenbaum, Frank 1946. Slave and Citizen: The Negro in the Americas. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Tawney, Richard. H. 1921. The Acquisitive Society. London: G. Bell.Google Scholar
Taylor, Horace. 1928. Making Goods and Making Money. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, Horace 1938. Contemporary Economic Problems and Trends. New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Taylor, Timothy. 2010. Recommendations for Further Reading. Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (Summer): 251–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Terborgh, George W. 1945. The Bogey of Economic Maturity. Chicago: Machinery and Allied Products Institute.Google Scholar
Thorp, Willard L. 1928. Economic Institutions. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Thorp, Willard L. 1947. Entry in Current Biography 1947. New York: H. W. Wilson.Google Scholar
Thorp, Willard L. and Mitchell, Wesley C.. 1926. Business Annals. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1921. The Economic Basis for Business Regulation. American Economic Review 11 (March): 643–658.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1922a. The Economic Basis of Public Interest. New York: Agustus M. Kelley, 1968.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1922b. Human Nature in Economic Theory. Journal of Political Economy 30 (June): 317–345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. (1924a) 1971. Experimental Economics. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 370–422.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. ed. (1924b) 1971. The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1927. Industry's Coming of Age. New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1930. Human Nature and Social Economy, I and II. Journal of Philosophy 17 and 18 (August 14 and 28): 449–457, 477–492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1931. The Theory of Occupational Obsolescence. Political Science Quarterly 46 (June): 171–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1932a. Flaws in the Hoover Economic Plan. Current History 35 (January): 525–531.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1932b. The Principle of Planning and the Institution of Laissez Faire. American Economic Review 22 (March): 75–92.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1933. The Industrial Discipline and the Governmental Arts. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1935a. Consumers and the New Deal. In The Battle for Democracy. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 268–286.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1935b. When Corporations Save. In The Battle for Democracy. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 187–192.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1937. Wesley Mitchell: An Evaluation. New Republic 92 (October 6): 238–240.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. 1982. To the Lesser Heights of Morningside. Philadelphia: University of Philadelphia Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G. and Hill, Howard C.. 1934. Our Economic Society and its Problems. New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Tugwell, Rexford G., Munroe, Thomas, and Stryker, Roy E.. 1925. American Economic Life and the Means of Its Improvement. New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Turner, Stephen P. 1999. Does Funding Produce its Effects? The Rockefeller Case. In Richardson, Theresa and Fisher, Donald, eds., The Development of the Social Sciences in the United States and Canada: The Role of Philanthropy. Stamford, CT: Ablex.Google Scholar
Horn, Rob. 2009. Reinventing Monopoly and the Role of Corporations: Chicago School of Law and Economics. In Mirowski, Philip and Plehwe, Dieter, eds., The Road from Mont Pelerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 204–237.Google Scholar
Horn, Rob and Mirowski, Philip. 2009. The Rise of the Chicago School of Economics and the Birth of Neoliberalism. In Mirowski, Philip and Plehwe, Dieter, eds., The Road from Mont Pelerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 139–178.Google Scholar
Vaughn, Gerald F. 1999. Veblen's Possible Influence on the New Deal Land-Utilization Program as Evidenced by His Student Claud Franklin Clayton. Journal of Economic Issues 33 (September): 713–727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vaughn, Gerald F. 2001a. Veblen, Camp, and the Industrial Organization of Agriculture. Journal of Economic Issues 35 (March): 139–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vaughn, Gerald F. 2001b. The Influence of Veblen's Theory of the Leisure Class on Rural Sociologist Fred Roy Yoder. Journal of Economic Issues 25 (December): 979–993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. 1898. Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?Quarterly Journal of Economics 12 (July): 373–397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1899. The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 18991900. The Preconceptions of Economic Science, I, II and III. Quarterly Journal of Economics 13 (January): 121–150; (July): 396–426; 14 (February): 240–269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1901. Gustav Schmoller's Economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 16 (November): 69–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1904. The Theory of Business Enterprise. New York: Scribners.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1906. The Place of Science in Modern Civilization. American Journal of Sociology 11 (March): 585–609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1907. The Socialist Economics of Karl Marx and His Followers, II. Quarterly Journal of Economics 21 (February): 299–322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1908a. Professor Clark's Economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 22 (February): 147–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1908b. On the Nature of Capital, I and II. Quarterly Journal of Economics 22 (August): 517–542; 23 (November): 104–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1909. The Limitations of Marginal Utility. Journal of Political Economy 17 (November): 620–636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1914. The Instinct of Workmanship. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1915. Imperial Germany and the Industrial Revolution. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1917. An Inquiry into the Nature of Peace. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1918. The Higher Learning in America. New York: B. W. Huebsch.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1919a. The Vested Interests and the State of the Industrial Arts. New York: B. W. Huebsch.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1919b. The Place of Science in Modern Civilization. New York: B. W. Huebsch.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1921. The Engineers and the Price System. New York: B. W. Huebsch.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1925. Economic Theory in the Calculable Future. American Economic Review 15 (March): 48–55.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1934. Essays in our Changing Order. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1928. The Present Status and Future Prospects of Quantitative Economics. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 18 (March): 30–36.Google Scholar
Vining, Routledge. 1939. Suggestions of Keynes in the Writings of Veblen. Journal of Political Economy 47 (October): 692–704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vining, Routledge 1949. Methodological Issues in Quantitative Economics: Koopmans on the Choice of Variables to Be Studied and on Methods of Measurement. Review of Economics and Statistics 31 (May): 77–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vining, Routledge 1950. Methodological Issues in Quantitative Economics: Variations upon a Theme by F. H. Knight. American Economic Review 40 (June): 267–284.Google Scholar
Vining, Routledge 1963. On the Problem of Recognizing and Diagnosing Faultiness in the Observed Performance of an Economic System. Journal of Law and Economics 6 (July): 165–184.Google Scholar
Wallas, Graham. 1908. Human Nature in Politics. London: Archibald Constable and Co.Google Scholar
Wallas, Graham 1914. The Great Society. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Waller, Spencer W. 2000. The Language of Law and the Language of Business. Working Paper, Institute for Consumer Anti-Trust Studies, Loyola University Chicago School of Law.
Wallis, W. Allen. 1980. The Statistical Research Group, 1942–1945. Journal of the American Statistical Association 75 (June): 320–335.Google Scholar
Wallis, W. Allen and Friedman, Milton. 1942. The Empirical Derivation of Indifference Functions. In Lange, Oscar, ed., Studies in Mathematical Economics and Econometrics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 175–189.Google Scholar
Wells, Wyatt C. 1994. Economist in an Uncertain World: Arthur F. Burns and the Federal Reserve, 1970–78. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Whalen, Charles J. 2008. John R. Commons and John Maynard Keynes on Economic History and Policy. Journal of Economic Issues 42 (March): 225–242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilber, Charles K. and Harrison, Robert S.. 1978. The Methodological Basis of Institutional Economics: Pattern Model, Storytelling, and Holism. Journal of Economic Issues 12 (March): 61–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1998a. The Institutions of Governance. American Economic Review 88 (May): 75–79.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1998b. Transaction Cost Economics: How It Works: Where It Is Headed. De Economist 146 (April): 23–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witte, Edwin E. 1932. The Government in Labor Disputes. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Witte, Edwin E. 1937. Old Age Security in the Social Security Act. Journal of Political Economy 45 (February): 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witte, Edwin E. 1952. The Teacher and Guide. John R. Commons: Teacher, Economist, and Administrator. Madison, WI: Sate Historical Society of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Witte, Edwin E. 1954. Institutional Economics as Seen by an Institutional Economist. Southern Economic Journal 21 (October): 131–140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witte, Edwin E. 1960. Selig Perlman. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 13 (April): 335–337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woirol, Gregory R. 1984. Observing the IWW in California, May–July 1914. Labor History 25 (Summer): 437–447.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woirol, Gregory R. 1992. In the Floating Army: F. C. Mills on Itinerant Life in California, 1914. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Woirol, Gregory R. 1999. The Contributions of Frederick C. Mills. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 21 (June): 163–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woirol, Gregory R. 2006. New Data, New Issues: The Origins of the Technological Unemployment Debates. History of Political Economy 38 (Fall): 473–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfe, A. B. (1924) 1971. Functional Economics. In Tugwell, Rexford G., ed., The Trend of Economics. Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press, pp. 443–482.Google Scholar
Wolfe, A. B. 1936. Institutional Reasonableness and Value. Philosophical Review 45 (March): 192–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolman, Leo. 1919. The Statistical Work of the War Industries Board. Publications of the American Statistical Association 16 (March): 248–260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolman, Leo 1924. The Growth of American Trade Unions, 1880–1923. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Wolman, Leo 1927. The Frontiers of Social Control. American Labor Legislation Review 17: 233–241.Google Scholar
Wolman, Leo 1930. Planning and Control of Public Works. New York: NBER.Google Scholar
Wolman, Leo and Peck, Gustav. 1933. Labor Groups in the Social Structure. Recent Social Trends in the United States. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Worcester, Kenton W. 2001. Social Science Research Council, 1923–1998. New York: Social Science Research Council.Google Scholar
Wright, David McCord. 1943. Moulton's The New Philosophy of Public Debt. American Economic Review 33 (September): 573–590.Google Scholar
Wright, David McCord 1945. The Future of Keynesian Economics. American Economic Review 35 (June): 284–307.Google Scholar
Yohe, William P. 1982. The Mysterious Career of Walter W. Stewart, especially 1922–1930. History of Political Economy 14 (Winter): 583–607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yohe, William P. 1990. The Intellectual Milieu at the Federal Reserve Board in the 1920s. History of Political Economy 22 (Fall): 465–488.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yonay, Yuval P. 1998. The Struggle over the Soul of Economics: Institutionalist and Neoclassical Economists in America Between the Wars. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Allyn A. 1918. National Statistics in War and Peace. Publications of the American Statistical Association 16 (March): 873–885.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Allyn A. (1925) 1927. The Trend of Economics as Seen by Some American Economists. Reprinted in Young, Allyn A., Economic Problems Old and New. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, pp. 232–260.Google Scholar
Young, Allyn A. 1929. Economics. In Gee, Wilson, ed., Research in the Social Sciences: Its Fundamental Methods and Objectives. New York: Macmillan, pp. 53–80.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Malcolm Rutherford, University of Victoria, British Columbia
  • Book: The Institutionalist Movement in American Economics, 1918–1947
  • Online publication: 03 May 2011
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511977046.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Malcolm Rutherford, University of Victoria, British Columbia
  • Book: The Institutionalist Movement in American Economics, 1918–1947
  • Online publication: 03 May 2011
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511977046.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Malcolm Rutherford, University of Victoria, British Columbia
  • Book: The Institutionalist Movement in American Economics, 1918–1947
  • Online publication: 03 May 2011
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511977046.014
Available formats
×