Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-fscjk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T22:12:44.023Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Politics of Order in Informal Markets: Evidence from Lagos

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 November 2019

Get access

Abstract

Property rights are important for economic exchange, but in many parts of the world, they are not publicly guaranteed. Private market associations can fill this gap by providing an institutional structure to enforce agreements, but with this power comes the ability to extort from group members. Under what circumstances do private associations provide a stable environment for economic activity? The author uses survey data collected from 1,179 randomly sampled traders across 199 markets in Lagos, Nigeria, and finds that markets maintain institutions to support trade not in the absence of government, but rather in response to active government interference. The author argues that associations develop protrade policies when threatened by politicians they perceive to be predatory and when the organizations can respond with threats of their own. The latter is easier when traders are not competing with one another. To maintain this balance of power, an association will not extort; it needs trader support to maintain the credibility of its threats to mobilize against predatory politicians.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Johnson, Simon. 2005. “Unbundling Institutions.” Journal of Political Economy 113, no. 5: 949–95. doi: 10.1086/432166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Reed, Tristan, and Robinson, James A.. 2014. “Chiefs: Economic Development and Elite Control of Civil Society in Sierra Leone.” Journal of Political Economy 122, no. 2: 319–68. doi: 10.1086/674988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., and Lien, Da-Hsiang Donald. 1985. “A Note on Taxation, Development, and Representative Government.” Politics and Society 14, no. 1: 5370. doi: 10.1177/003232928501400102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beegle, Kathleen G., Benjamin, Nancy Claire, Recanatini, Francesca, and Santini, Massimiliano. 2014. “Informal Economy and the World Bank.” Policy Research Working Paper no. 6888. Washington, D.C.: World Bank Group. At http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/416741468332060156/pdf/WPS6888.pdf, accessed June 21, 2019.Google Scholar
Berman, Sheri. 1997. “Civil Society and the Collapse of the Weimar Republic.” World Politics 49, no. 3 (April): 401–29. doi: 10.1353/wp.1997.0008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratton, Michael, and Gyimah-Boadi, E.. 2016. “Do Trustworthy Institutions Matter for Development? Corruption, Trust, and Government Performance in Africa.” Afrobarometer Dispatch no. 112. At http://afrobarometer.org/sites/default/files/publications/Dispatches/ab_r6_dispatchno112_trustworthy_institutions_and_development_in_africa.pdf, accessed June 21, 2019.Google Scholar
Cross, John C. 1998. Informal Politics: Street Vendors and the State in Mexico City. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
de Gramont, Diane. 2014. “Constructing the Megacity: The Dynamics of State Building in Lagos, Nigeria, 1999–2013.” M.A. thesis. University of Oxford.Google Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. 1994. Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D.. 1996. “Explaining Interethnic Cooperation.” American Political Science Review 90, no. 4: 715–35. doi: 10.2307/2945838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frye, Timothy. 2000. Brokers and Bureaucrats: Building Market Institutions in Russia. Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gambetta, Diego. 1996. The Sicilian Mafia: The Business of Private Protection. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 3: 481510. doi: 10.1086/228311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition.” American Economic Review 83, no. 3: 525–48. At https://www.jstor.org/stable/2117532, accessed September 1, 2019.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Shelby. 2019a. “Replication files for: The Politics of Order in Informal Markets: Evidence from Lagos.” Harvard Dataverse, V1. doi: 10.7910/DVN/FRPRDP CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Shelby. 2019b. “Supplementary material for: The Politics of Order in Informal Markets: Evidence from Lagos.” At https://doi.org/10.1017/S0043887119000121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habyarimana, James, Humphreys, Macartan, Posner, Daniel N., and Weinstein, Jeremy M.. 2009. Coethnicity: Diversity and the Dilemmas of Collective Action. New York, N.Y.: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Hummel, Calla. 2017. “Disobedient Markets: Street Vendors, Enforcement, and State Intervention in Collective Action.” Comparative Political Studies 50, no. 11: 1524–55. doi: 10.1177/0010414016679177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ikioda, Faith. 2014. “Communities of Practice in Competitive Settings: Exploring the Role of Associations of Market Traders in Nigeria’s Marketplaces.” Knowledge Management for Development Journal 10, no. 2: 105–16.Google Scholar
Jutting, Johannes P., and de Laiglesia, Juan R., eds. 2009. Is Informal Normal? Towards More and Better Jobs in Developing Countries. Paris, France: Development Center of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. doi: 10.1787/9789264059245-en.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larson, Jennifer M. 2017. “Networks and Interethnic Cooperation.” Journal of Politics 79, no. 2: 546–59. doi: 10.1086/690066.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, Peter T. 2007. “An-arrgh-chy: The Law and Economics of Pirate Organization.” Journal of Political Economy 115, no. 6: 1049–94. doi: 10.1086/526403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markus, Stanislav. 2012. “Secure Property as a Bottom-Up Process: Firms, Stakeholders, and Predators in Weak States.” World Politics 64, no. 2 (April): 24277. doi: 10.1017/S0043887112000044.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, Benjamin, Stoker, Thomas M., and Suri, Tavneet. 2013. “The Political Economy of Ethnicity and Property Rights in Slums: Evidence from Kenya.” Working Paper. At http://cega.berkeley.edu/assets/cega_events/53/WGAPE_Sp2013_Suri.pdf, accessed June 21, 2019.Google Scholar
Mattingly, Daniel C. 2016. “Elite Capture: How Decentralization and Informal Institutions Weaken Property Rights in China.” World Politics 68, no. 3 (July): 383412. doi: 10.1017/S0043887116000083.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul R., North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1990. “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs.” Economics & Politics 2, no. 1: 123. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0343.1990.tb00020.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York, N.Y.: W. W. Norton & Co. Google Scholar
Office of State Auditor General, Lagos State, Nigeria. 2012. “2012 Audit Report of Local Government and Local Council Development Areas in Lagos State.” Lagos, Nigeria: Lagos State Government.Google Scholar
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. 2014. “The Economics of Guilds.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28, no. 4: 169–92. doi: 10.1257/jep.28.4.169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 2000. Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships. New York, N.Y.: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richman, Barak D. 2017. Stateless Commerce: The Diamond Network and the Persistence of Relational Exchange. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, Friedrich. 2005. “Shadow Economies Around the World: What Do We Really Know?European Journal of Political Economy 21, no. 3: 598642. doi: 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2004.10.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skarbek, David. 2014. The Social Order of the Underworld: How Prison Gangs Govern the American Penal System. New York, N.Y.: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thachil, Tariq. Forthcoming. “Does Police Repression Unite or Divide Poor Migrants? Evidence from Urban Indian Marketplaces.” Journal of Politics.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1992. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990—1992. Oxford, UK: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1995. “The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and Economic Development.” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 11, no. 1: 131. doi: 10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a036861.Google Scholar
World Bank. 2002. “State and Local Governance in Nigeria.” Report no. 24477-UNL. Washington D.C.: World Bank. At http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/442501468780898611/Nigeria-State-and-local-governance-in-Nigeria, accessed September 1, 2019.Google Scholar
World Bank Group. 2010. “Guatemala Enterprise Informal Survey Implementation Note.” At enterprisesurveys.org, accessed September 1, 2019.Google Scholar
World Bank Group. 2014. “Doing Business 2015: Going Beyond Efficiency.” Washington D.C.: World Bank. doi: 10.1596/978-1-4648-0351-2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: Link

Grossman supplementary material

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Grossman supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Grossman supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 432.5 KB