Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T06:37:33.077Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Roundtable on Rick Doner, Gregory Noble, and John Ravenhill, The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia

Review products

Roundtable on Rick Doner, Gregory Noble, and John Ravenhill, The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 November 2022

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Book Review Roundtable
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the East Asia Institute

Introduction

Research on the political economy of growth in East Asia from its inception was motivated by a focus on institutions. The early developmental state literature highlighted the role that government intervention played in rapid economic growth, but that literature centered largely on the question of which policies governments chose to implement. From Chalmers Johnson (Reference Johnson1982) forward, political scientists have paid greater attention to political institutions—and particularly state institutions—as the enabling conditions for the growth process. Factors such as political autonomy, bureaucratic competence, and coordination with the private sector through business councils were seen as crucial to rapid capital accumulation, a relatively efficient allocation of resources, and corresponding increases in social welfare.

In contrast to this macrolevel focus on national-level institutions, a second strand of the early literature on growth was decidedly micro in its approach, honing in much more closely on economic or what might be called “local” institutions. These institutions served to coordinate or regulate a diverse set of state and private actors, including both foreign and local firms. This literature—which included its share of classics as well—typically took an industry or sectoral focus with particular attention being paid to the relationship between multinational corporations and networks of local suppliers.

This approach to the political economy of the region has continued in various guises, for example in a wide-ranging literature on international production networks. But as editors of the Journal of East Asian Studies, we have seen a decline in this qualitative, institutionally focused case study research on economic growth. Two related considerations thus motivate this roundtable on Rick Doner, Gregory Noble, and John Ravenhill's (Reference Doner, Noble and Ravenhill2021) book The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia (hereafter DNR). The first is its return to these core micro-institutional questions. But second, the book invites scholars of East Asian political economy to consider how such studies fit with other research approaches to the region's development, including not only the earlier generation of sectoral studies, but also more recent quantitative research and the burgeoning revival of interest in a “new” or “open economy” industrial policy.

The argument in brief

DNR make four core arguments. First, they advocate for a more disaggregated approach to industrialization than is usually found in the development literature, and certainly in the macroeconomic literature on growth per se. They draw a core distinction between “extensive” and “intensive” growth. In the automotive sector, the former consists largely of the development of vehicle and components assembly and, in some cases, exports, controlled by multinational firms operating in global value chains. “Intensive” growth, by contrast, involves an increase in local value added as a result of an expansion in the supply of inputs from efficient indigenous producers with their own distinctive technical capabilities. Whereas economic diversification involving the expansion of auto assembly and exports is the hallmark of successful extensive growth, dense input–output linkages with competitive local producers characterize successful intensive growth. Innovation—typically associated with larger firms—is key to the development of these competitive local producers.

Second, DNR go beyond the developmental state literature in proposing that these different forms of industrial growth require different competencies at the national, sectoral, and even firm levels. These range from the well-known demands of financing capital formation and providing increasingly sophisticated physical infrastructure, but also to the supply of new forms of public goods—or what is often called “quality infrastructure”—such as testing and standards or technical training that expands firm-level capacities. Unlike most of the literature on the developmental state, DNR argue that an understanding of the reasons for the successful pursuit of either extensive or, more particularly, intensive strategies requires an investigation of sector-specific institutions.

Third, developing these various competencies poses institutional challenges, and not only for the state: public, private, and public–private partnerships are all in play. They argue—in a functional way—that capacities either “fit” (or “don't fit”) the demands of different types of growth. More specifically, the book proposes that extensive growth will be associated with institutions focusing largely on mobilizing capital and labor, whereas intensive growth requires institutions that promote the absorption of technologies new to a country's firms, or that can spur technological innovation within these firms.

Fourth, DNR go beyond a purely functional approach to these developmental challenges by addressing the question of institutional origins and the conditions under which such institutions are likely to arise in the first place. In the most explicitly political component of the book, DNR hypothesize that institutions with the capacity to promote intensive growth will emerge to the degree that political leaders are compelled to address external threats and domestic unrest but lack easy access to resources to do so. In such difficult circumstances—in effect, when constrained—leaders will be more likely to make the investment of scarce resources required to improve local industrial capacity through institutional innovation. They show this in particular with their contrast between the political economies of the resource-abundant Southeast Asian countries and their cases in Northeast Asia—China, Korea, and Taiwan—that were characterized by significant external threats and/or resource scarcity.

These arguments are played out over the course of the book. Chapter 2 reviews the lure and challenges of the global auto industry, and then establishes the book's core empirical puzzle: how to explain cross-national variation in response to these conditions within East Asia. DNR address this puzzle through a two-pronged comparative research design. The first, covered in Chapter 3, consists of theoretically informed, cross-case analysis. This “most-similar-different-outcome” design examines variation in the strategies and performance of seven countries pursuing automotive industrialization within the same region and the same producer-driven value chain. It is, of course, difficult to exclude the possibility that other factors, besides or beyond the presence of certain kinds of institutions and pressures on political leaders, account for the superior performance of, say, South Korea, relative to Malaysia. DNR thus turn to within-case analysis in Chapters 4–9. These case studies provide a finer-grained assessment of performance and, most crucially, trace the temporal evolution of policies and institutions relative to performance.

Theoretical touch points

We see several ways in which a renewed focus on sectoral analysis might prove useful for the study of the international and comparative political economy of the region.

Reinvigorating research on industries

DNR build on an earlier, robust body of sectoral research on East Asian growth. Much of this work was on large firms, especially in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan (Amsden Reference Amsden1989; Zysman Reference Zysman1983; Vogel Reference Vogel1996; Woo Reference Woo1991; Chang Reference Chang1994; Wade Reference Wade1990; Mathews and Cho Reference Mathews and Cho2000), and others exploring the role of small firm networks especially in Taiwan (Amsden Reference Amsden, Evans, Rueschemeyer and Skocpol1985; Kuo Reference Kuo1995). Some of this work was explicitly comparative (Haggard Reference Haggard1990; Weiss and Hobson Reference Weiss and Hobson1995; Noble Reference Noble1998; McKendrick, Doner, and Haggard Reference McKendrick, Doner and Haggard2000; Wong Reference Wong2011; Yeung Reference Yeung2016).

Yet, at least in terms of explicitly political economy scholarship, this earlier tradition of industry studies, with the exception of work on China, for example (Thun Reference Thun2006; Chin Reference Chin2010; Hsueh Reference Hsueh2011), has seen a relative decline in the English-language political economy literature. Several factors contributed to this shift, including the simple fact that the original subjects of the developmental state literature—Japan, Korea, and Taiwan—entered a new phase in their growth in which other political economy topics—from financial crises to inequality and social policy to social media—have received more attention. At the regional level, a focus on international institutions and trade agreements has, with some exceptions (for example, Manger Reference Manger2014; Ravenhill Reference Ravenhill2017) been almost entirely divorced from a focus on the interplay between state and business.

But DNR goes beyond this earlier sectoral analysis by virtue of its distinction among stages of industrialization, its emphasis on “goodness of fit” between institutions and development challenges at the sectoral level, and its emphasis on the socio-political underpinnings of institutional capacities. These foci resemble in important ways the varieties of capitalism literature and go well beyond the state autonomy assumptions and what Robert Wade labeled the “thin politics” of much of that earlier literature (Wade Reference Wade1992, 307).

Quantitative research on East Asian growth

Another possible reason for the decline of such work may be the availability of new statistical data, including on the nature and impact of “governance” (see McGuire Reference McGuire2020; Bernhard et ak, Reference Bernhard2015). The value of this work, especially those studies exploring the impact of political institutions on various aspects of development) is indisputable. However, by its very nature, this work typically neglects several issues highlighted in DNR. To date, it has not been able to capture the impact, evolution, and political origins of domestic institutions dedicated to productivity enhancement of local firms. It assumes that evidence as to the utility of certain measures, such as targeted FDI incentives, will be adopted and implemented by agencies such as investment boards rather than exploring the underlying politics. And the logic of inquiry in most quantitative research on governance follows what Abbott (Reference Abbott1988) calls “general linear reality,” in which variables are additively related to one another (rendering it impossible to see the interactive relationships across institutional domains) and the focus is on average treatment effects (thus obscuring pathbreaking cases and follow-the-leader dynamics).

Relatedly, it assumes the relevance of “good governance” indicators (Kaufman et al Reference Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi2010), despite evidence from case studies that such indicators miss key elements of governance on the ground at the sectoral level (Kurtz and Schrank Reference Kurtz and Schrank2007). DNR demonstrate how aggregated indicators such as “good governance” are unable to explain variance in performance across industrial sectors—Malaysia is an obvious case, a country that for decades has scored well on good governance and indicators of macroeconomic management but whose policies in the automotive sector were a colossal failure. Further, DNR's cross- and within-case analysis is exemplary of mid-range and a mixed-methods approach that stands in contrast with an obsession on external validity to the neglect of context (Haggard Reference Haggard2018, 93–94).

Links to the literature on global value chains

In the last two decades, much of the analysis of industrial development has been conducted through the lens of global value chains. Much of the literature is concerned with how value chains are organized and, in particular, on the forms of governance of inter-firm relationships within the chains (Gereffi, Humphrey, and Sturgeon Reference Gereffi, Humphrey and Sturgeon2005).

In moving beyond an exclusive focus on the state and domestic institutions, the literature on global value chains, including work on the automotive industry (e.g. Sturgeon et al., Reference Sturgeon, Daly, Frederick, Bamber and Gereffi2016), provides a useful supplement, pointing to how inter-firm networks can assist local firms to upgrade their capabilities and gain access to international markets. Much of the literature, however, is characterized by atheoretical case studies and/or typologies that have failed to generate any significant cumulation of knowledge. By focusing on within-value chain opportunities, that is, primarily on relations among firms, many studies within the GVC framework provide only a partial sense of the factors influencing firm upgrading. Sophisticated analysts have always noted that the institutional context in which value chains operate has a profound impact on their effects (e.g., Ponte Reference Ponte2002). This nuance was frequently lost when the multilateral economic institutions became enthusiastic advocates of developing economies making themselves as attractive candidates as possible to the lead firms in value chains primarily through the application of policies associated with the Washington Consensus.

More recent work on GVCs is more consistent with DNR by virtue of its emphasis on “bringing the state back in” (Eckhardt and Poletti Reference Eckhardt and Poletti2018) and on various kinds of non-market, often local institutions (Corredoira and McDermott (Reference Corredoira and McDermott2014). Reinforcing this move toward institutions, one of the few “meta-analyses” of the burgeoning literature on GVCs found that a crucial element in firms’ ability to upgrade within GVCs is the local institutional environment and, more specifically, “the capacity of the state” and “public–private collaborative engagement” (Pipkin and Fuentes Reference Pipkin and Fuentes2017, 547, 549). These factors were critical in the (relatively rare) success of some firms in upgrading while the majority, in their terms, underwent a process of “treadmilling” in which attempts to upgrade were followed by “backsliding, decay and obsolescence.” The implication of this more recent extension of the GVC and related literature is consistent with a core DNR contention—namely, that the absence of effective local institutions designed to promote spillovers from foreign producers will result in weak technological capabilities on the part of local firms and, as a result, fragile linkages between them and foreign lead firms (see also Ravenhill Reference Ravenhill2014).Footnote 1

Yet, with some exceptions (e.g. Corredoira and McDermott Reference Corredoira and McDermott2014), the GVC and related literature pay little if any attention to the institutions that contribute more directly to improvements in sector and firm upgrading. Nor do they address one of the core elements of DNR—namely, the origins of these institutions, i.e. the factors leading political leaders to expend scarce resources on their creation.Footnote 2

Upgrading, technological catch-up and the new industrial policy

Finally, DNR's concern with the productivity and technological capacities of local firms so central to intensive growth makes it highly relevant to a growing literature on technological catch-up, inspired by earlier work of Sanjaya Lall and Linsu Kim (e.g. Lee et al Reference Lee, Lee, Meissner, Radosevic and Vonortas2021, Yeung Reference Yeung2016). Drawing on both large-N and in-depth case study analysis, the scholarship on technological catch-up recognizes the challenges of technology absorption by local firms, sheds light on specific challenges and stages of such absorption, and recognizes the importance of institutional ecologies and innovation systems for countries facing middle-income traps and the challenge of taking advantage of participation in global value chains.

This literature's appreciation of institutions is informed by the “new industrial policy,” which places less emphasis on top-down, technocratic directives than on a recursive process of discovery, learning and diagnostic monitoring to ensure ongoing error correction. Such functions require effective institutions.

Because of its own sociology of knowledge, this literature has tended to shy away from the political economy question of where these industrial policies and corresponding institutions came from in the first place, or the question of what DNR call “origins.” There are scattered mentions of factors such as the power of vested interests, the tendency of political leaders to have short time horizons, and the potentially utility of crises (e.g. Lee et al Reference Lee, Lee, Meissner, Radosevic and Vonortas2021). But these are not part of the core arguments and tend to occupy the same explanatory space as “political will” in the work of the early neo-classical economists who turned their attention to the region over the course of the 1970s. Rather than addressing the question of why political elites would expend scarce resources to develop institutions with effective monitoring capabilities, this literature emphasizes rather their functionality for growth.

Two cases, one positive and one negative, are illustrative. Fundación Chile, the “business incubator” key to Chile's successful salmon industry, is frequently and rightly cited as the kind of public–private institution to which other middle-income countries should aspire. Not mentioned is the critical question of why Pinochet, a leader best known for his turn to neoclassical market orthodoxy, would support such an institution-intense approach to sectoral development. A second case involves Malaysia's PEMANDU (Performance Management and Delivery Unit), established by the Malaysian government in 2009 with the expressed purpose of coordinating diverse public agencies and private sector interests in a recursive, “new industrial policy”-type process of learning and monitoring (Sabel and Jordan Reference Sabel and Jordan2015). In the event, PEMANDU has not lived up to expectations owing to intra-bureaucratic infighting and broader political resistance.

Our purpose in this roundtable is not to generate an altogether new research paradigm, but simply to reflect on the ways in which the early industry focus of research on the region's rapid growth might be revived, updated and appropriately amended. The structure of the roundtable is as follows. The journal invited four respondents to reflect on the strengths and weaknesses of DRT: Natasha Hamilton-Hart (University of Auckland), Eun Mee Kim (Ehwa University), Roselyn Hsueh (Temple University), and Robert Wade (London School of Economics). The authors, as always, have the last word.

Footnotes

1. The multilateral economic institutions are now tempering their enthusiasm for GVCs by acknowledging that the benefits from participation in GVCs are unevenly distributed, and that a “win-win” situation is not an inevitable outcome but is dependent on specific government policies that enable firms to strengthen their capacity to gain from GVCs (Kummritz, Taglioni, and Winkler Reference Kummritz, Taglioni and Winkler2017). Rodrik (Reference Rodrik2018) extends the critique by arguing that GVCs’ privileging skilled labor makes it hard for developing countries to use their comparative advantage, weakening both trade balances and, by implication, the opportunities for local firms.

2. This lack of attention to institutional origins also characterizes the literature on “national innovation systems” (e.g. Intarakumnerd Reference Intarakumnerd2018)

References

Abbott, Andrew. 1988. “Transcending General Linear Reality.” Sociological Theory 6 (2): 169186.Google Scholar
Amsden, Alice H. 1985. “The State and Taiwan's Economic Development.” In Bringing the State Back In, edited by Evans, Peter B., Rueschemeyer, Dietrich and Skocpol, Theda, 78106.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amsden, Alice H. 1989. Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bernhard, Michael, et al. 2015. “Party Strength and Economic Growth.” University of Gothenburg, Varieties of Democracy Institute: Working Paper No. 10. September.Google Scholar
Chang, Ha-Joon. 1994. The Political Economy of Industrial Policy. New York: St. Martin's Press.Google Scholar
Chin, Gregory T. 2010. China's Automotive Modernization: The Party-State and Multinational Corporations. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corredoira, Rafael A., and McDermott, Gerald A.. 2014. “Adaptation, Bridging and Firm Upgrading: How Non Market Institutions and MNCs Facilitate Knowledge Recombination in Emerging Markets,” Journal of International Business Studies, 45: 699722.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doner, Richard F., Noble, Gregory W., and Ravenhill, John. 2021. The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia. New York: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckhardt, Jappe, and Poletti, Arlo. 2018. “Introduction: Bringing Institutions Back in the Study of Global Value Chains.” Global Policy 9: 511. doi: 10.1111/1758–5899.12613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gereffi, Gary, Humphrey, John, and Sturgeon, Timothy. 2005. “The Governance of Global Value Chains.” Review of International Political Economy 12 (1):78104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan. 1990. Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan. 2018. Developmental States. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hsueh, Roselyn. 2011. China's Regulatory State: A New Strategy for Globalization. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Intarakumnerd, Patarapong. 2018. Mismanaging Innovation Systems: Thailand and the Middle Income Trap. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925–1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, Daniel, Kraay, Aart, and Mastruzzi, Massimo. 2010. “The Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Issues.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5430, September, Washington, D.C.: World Bank, https://ssrn.com/abstract=1682130.Google Scholar
Kummritz, Victor, Taglioni, Daria, and Winkler, Deborah. 2017. “Economic Upgrading through Global Value Chain Participation Which Policies Increase the Value Added Gains?.” Washington, D.C.: World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 8007, March, accessed 27 June 2019. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/567861489688859864/pdf/WPS8007.pdf.Google Scholar
Kuo, Cheng-Tian. 1995. Global Competitiveness and Industrial Growth in Taiwan and the Philippines. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurtz, Marcus J., and Schrank, Andrew. 2007. “Growth and Governance: Models, Measures,and Mechanisms.” Journal of Politics 69 (2): 538554.Google Scholar
Lee, Jaeng-Dong, Lee, Keun, Meissner, Dirk, Radosevic, Slavor, and Vonortas, Nicholas S.. 2021. The Challenges of Technology and Economic Catch-up in Emerging Economies. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manger, Mark S. 2014. “The Economic Logic of Asian Preferential Trade Agreements: The Role of Intra-Industry Trade.” Journal of East Asian Studies 14 (2): 151184.Google Scholar
Mathews, John A., and Cho, Dong-Sung. 2000. Tiger Technology: The Creation of a Semiconductor Industry in East Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McGuire, James W. 2020. Democracy and Population Health. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKendrick, David, Doner, Richard F., and Haggard, Stephan. 2000. From Silicon Valley to Singapore: Location and Competitive Advantage in the Hard Disk Drive Industry. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Noble, Gregory W. 1998. Collective Action in East Asia: How Ruling Parties Shape Industrial Policy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Pipkin, Seth, and Fuentes, Alberto. 2017. “Spurred to Upgrade: A Review of Triggers and Consequences of Industrial Upgrading in the Global Value Chain Literature.” World Development 98:536554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ponte, Stefano. 2002. “The ‘Latte Revolution’? Regulation, Markets and Consumption in the Global Coffee Chain.” World Development 30 (7): 10991122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ravenhill, John. 2014. “Global Value Chains and Development.” Review of International Political Economy 21 (1): 264274.Google Scholar
Ravenhill, John. 2017. “The Political Economy of the Trans-Pacific Partnership: A ‘21st Century’ Trade Agreement?New Political Economy 22 (5):573–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 2018. New Technologies, Global Value Chains, and the Developing Economies. Pathways for Prosperity Commission Background Paper Series, no. 1. Oxford. https://drodrik.scholar.harvard.edu/files/dani-rodrik/files/new_technologies_global_value_chains_developing_economies.pdf.Google Scholar
Sabel, Charles, and Jordan, Luke. 2015. “Doing, Learning, Being: Some Lessons Learned from Malaysia's National Transformation Program.” Washington DC: World Bank / Competitive Industries and Innovation Program. https://charlessabel.com/papers/CS-LSJ--DLB%20Malaysia%20PEMANDU--Final-190115.pdf.Google Scholar
Sturgeon, Timothy, Daly, Jack, Frederick, Stacey, Bamber, Penny, and Gereffi, Gary. 2016. “The Philippines in the Global Automotive Value Chain.” Duke Center for Globalization, Governance and Competition. https://gvcc.duke.edu/wp content/uploads/2016_Philippines_Automotive_Global_Value_Chain.pdfGoogle Scholar
Thun, Eric. 2006. Changing Lanes in China: Foreign Direct Investment, Local Governments, and Auto Sector Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vogel, Steven Kent. 1996. Freer Markets, More Rules: Regulatory Reform in Advanced Industrial Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Wade, Robert. 1990 (2003). Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wade, Robert. 1992. “East Asia's Economic Success: Conflicting Perspectives, Partial Insights, Shaky Evidence.” World Politics 44 (2): 270320.Google Scholar
Weiss, Linda, and Hobson, John M.. 1995. States and Economic Development: A Comparative Historical Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Wong, Joseph. 2011. Betting on Biotech : Innovation and the Limits of Asia's Developmental State. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Woo, Jung-en. 1991. Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialization. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Yeung, Henry Wai-chung 2016. Strategic Coupling: East Asian Industrial Transformation in the New Global Economy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Zysman, John. 1983. Governments, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Industrial Change. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar