Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T01:56:45.188Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Institutional Change and Economic Growth in China: The View from the Villages

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 March 2011

Get access

Extract

The maoist era of egalitarian collectivism has decidedly come to an end. Although some villages persist in developing cooperative enterprises, the collective is being transformed from a dominant organizational form to one that plays a subsidiary role to the private household sector. In effect, the collective has been relegated to the position formerly held by the private sector. Everywhere the emphasis is on economic growth based on household production and marketlike forces. What is the relationship between these institutional changes and economic growth?

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Association for Asian Studies, Inc. 1990

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

List of References

Barker, Randolph, and Herdt, Robert W.. 1985. The Rice Economy of Asia. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Burawoy, Michael. 1979. Manufacturing Consent: Changes in the Labor Process Under Monopoly Capitalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Chan, Anita, Madsen, Richard, and Unger, Jonathan. 1984. Chen Village: The Recent History of a Peasant Community in Mao's China. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Dimaggio, Paul, and Powell, Walter. 1983. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” American Sociological Review 48:147–60.Google Scholar
Freedman, Maurice. 1958. Lineage Organization in Southeastern China. London: Athlone Press.Google Scholar
Friedland, Roger, and Robertson, A. F., eds. Forthcoming. Beyond the Marketplace: Rethinking Economy and Society. Hawthorne, N.Y.: Aldine and de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91:481510.Google Scholar
Hartford, Kathleen. 1984. “Socialist Agriculture is Dead; Long Live Socialist Agriculture! Organizational Transformations in Rural China.” In The Political Economy of Reform in Post-Mao China, ed. Perry, Elizabeth and Wong, Christine. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; Council on East Asian Studies.Google Scholar
Homans, George C. 1974. Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Langlois, Richard N. 1986. “The New Institutional Economics: An Introductory Essay.” In Economics as a Process, ed. Langlois, Richard. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lardy, Nicholas R. 1983. Agriculture in China's Modern Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lardy, Nicholas R. 1985. “State Intervention and Peasant Opportunities.” In Chinese Rural Development: The Great Transformation, ed. Parish, William L.. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe Press.Google Scholar
Latham, J. Richard. 1985. “The Implications of Rural Reforms for Grass-Roots Cadres.” In The Political Economy of Reform in Post-Mao China, ed. Perry, Elizabeth and Wong, Christine. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; Council on East Asian Studies.Google Scholar
Lin, Cyril Zhiren. 1989. “Open-Ended Economic Reform in China.” In Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism: China and Eastern Europe, ed. Nee, Victor and Stark, David. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Liu, Alan P. 19831984. “The Politics of Corruption in the People's Republic of China.” American Political Science Review 77:602–23.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1989. Discovering Institutions: The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W.., and Rowan, Brian. 1977. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structures as Myth and Ceremony.” American Journal of Sociology 88:340–63.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry. 1984. “The New Economics of Organization.” American Journal of Political Science 28:739–77.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor. 1985. “Peasant Household Individualism.” In Chinese Rural Development: The Great Transformation, ed. Parish, William L.. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe Press.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor. 1986. “The Peasant Household Economy and Decollectivization in China.”Journal of Asian and African Studies 21:185203.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor. 1989a. “Peasant Entrepreneurship and the Politics of Regulation in China.” In Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism: China and Eastern Europe, ed. Nee, Victor and Stark, David. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor. 1989b. “A Theory of Market Transition: From Redistribution to Markets in State Socialism.” American Sociological Review 54:663–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nee, Victor, and Young, Frank W.. Forthcoming. “Peasant Entrepreneurs in China's ‘Second Economy’: An Institutional Analysis.” Economic Development and Cultural Change.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. Forthcoming. Institutions and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Thomas, Robert P.. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Oi, Jean. 1986. “Commercializing China's Rural Cadres.” Problems of Communism 35:115.Google Scholar
Oi, Jean. 1989. “The Fate of the Collective After the Commune.” In The Social and Political Impact of Chinese Reform, ed. Davis, Debra and Vogel, Ezra. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; Council on East Asian Studies.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Parish, William L., and Whyte, Martin King. 1978. Village and Family in Contemporary China. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
People's Daily (international edition).Google Scholar
Perkins, Dwight, and Yusuf, Shahid. 1984. Rural Development in China. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Piore, Michael, and Sabel, Charles. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Riskin, Carl. 1987. China's Political Economy: The Quest for Development Since 1949. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
SchultzTheodore, W. Theodore, W. 1953. The Economic Organization of Agriculture. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Schurmann, Franz. 1968. Ideology and Organization in Communist China. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Shirk, Susan. 1989. “The Political Economy of Chinese Industrial Reform.” In Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism: China and Eastern Europe, ed. Nee, Victor and Stark, David. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Shue, Vivienne. 1980. Peasant China in Transition: The Dynamics of Development Toward Socialism, 1949–1956. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Shue, Vivienne. 1984. “The Fate of the Commune.” Modern China 10:259–83.Google Scholar
Sicular, Terry. 1984. “Rural Marketing and Exchange in the Wake of Recent Reforms.” In The Political Economy of Reform in Post-Mao China, ed. Perry, Elizabeth and Wong, Christine. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; Council on East Asian Studies.Google Scholar
Skinner, G. William. 1978. “Vegetable Supply and Marketing in Chinese Cities.”China Quarterly, no. 76:733–94.Google Scholar
Stark, David, and Nee, Victor. 1989. “Towards an Institutional Analysis of State Socialism.” In Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism: China and Eastern Europe, ed. Nee, Victor and Stark, David. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
State Statistical Bureau. 1986. Statistical Yearbook of China (1986). Hong Kong: Economic Informational Agency.Google Scholar
Travers, Lee S.. 1984. “Getting Rich Through Diligence: Peasant Income After the Reforms.” In The Political Economy of Reform in Post-Mao China, ed. Perry, Elizabeth and Wong, Christine. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; Council on East Asian Studies.Google Scholar
Tsou, Tang, Blecher, Mark, and Meisner, Mitch. 1982. “The Responsibility System in Agriculture.” Modern China 8:41103.Google Scholar
Unger, Jonathan. 1985. “The Decollectivization of the Chinese Countryside: A Survey of Twenty-eight Villages.” Pacific Affairs 58:585606.Google Scholar
Watson, Andrew. 1988. “The Reform of Agricultural Marketing in China Since 1978.” China Quarterly, no. 113:128.Google Scholar
White, Gordon. 1987. “The Impact of Economic Reforms in the Chinese Countryside: Towards the Politics of Social Capitalism?Modern China 13:379410.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Wong, Christine. 1986. “The Economics of Shortage and Problems of Reform in Chinese Industry.” Journal of Comparative Economics 10:363–87.Google Scholar
Zweig, David. 1986. “Prosperity and Conflict in Post-Mao Rural China.” China Quarterly, no. 105:118.Google Scholar