Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T05:31:49.044Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

MANDATORY BINDING DISPUTE RESOLUTION IN THE BASE EROSION AND PROFIT SHIFTING (BEPS) TWO PILLAR SOLUTION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2023

Chris Noonan
Affiliation:
Associate Professor, Faculty of Law, University of Auckland, Auckland, New Zealand, [email protected]
Victoria Plekhanova
Affiliation:
Senior Lecturer, Business School, Massey University, Auckland, New Zealand, [email protected].
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Binding taxpayer-initiated international dispute resolution has traditionally played a minor role in the international tax system. Despite being long pursued by corporate interests and increasingly accepted by developed countries, international tax arbitration has remained less developed and less respectful of private interests than investor–State arbitration. The binding multilateral dispute settlement endorsed by over 130 countries as part of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development's Two Pillar Solution to issues raised under Action 1 of the Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) project marks a change and is noteworthy at a time when some States are reconsidering their consent to the international adjudication of trade and investment disputes. The design of international dispute settlement in the Two Pillar Solution, and the focus on the protection of multinationals from juridical double taxation, displays little appreciation of the experience with dispute settlement in international trade and investment over the past two decades.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the British Institute of International and Comparative Law

I. INTRODUCTION

Global tax governance is characterised by intergovernmentalism with specks of multilateralism and is supported by a network of shared norms and expectations.Footnote 1 Putting aside the European Union (EU), multilateral treaties have had only a marginal impact on the setting of the rules for cross-border income taxation.Footnote 2 The cross-border income tax regime derives its structure from bilateral double tax treaties, and from non-binding standards for cross-border taxation of income and capital agreed in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and, to a lesser extent, the United Nations (UN).Footnote 3 Double tax treaties allocate the rights to tax between countries and collectively constrain the approach that an individual jurisdiction can take to cross-border income tax issues. The purpose of these treaties is to minimise the risk of juridical double taxation and tax discrimination of non-residents. Over 3,000 bilateral double tax treaties are in force around the world.Footnote 4 They follow either the OECD or the UN Model Tax Convention,Footnote 5 which are themselves very similar and reflect the conceptual structure of the first model treaty drafted by a League of Nations Committee of Technical Experts in 1927.Footnote 6 The approach to dispute settlement in double tax treaties has traditionally been distinct from trade or investment treaties, shunning both binding State–State and binding State–taxpayer dispute settlement. Many double tax treaties have a Mutual Agreement Procedure (MAP). The procedure is based on Article 25 of either the OECD Model Tax Convention or the UN Model Tax Convention and allows taxpayers to challenge actions of States participating in a double tax agreement when these actions result in taxation that is not in accordance with the agreement.Footnote 7

Over the last 15 years, developed countries have moved to accept mandatory arbitration in double tax treaties. An option of binding arbitration was included in the MAP article of the OECD Model Tax Convention in 2008 following long-term corporate advocacy.Footnote 8 In 2013, the OECD and Group of Twenty (G20) launched the Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) project.Footnote 9 BEPS refers to tax planning strategies that exploit gaps and mismatches in tax rules to avoid paying income tax—usually by shifting profits to low- or no-tax jurisdictions where there is often little or no real economic activity.Footnote 10 In 2015, over 60 countries agreed to 15 Actions under the BEPS project. BEPS Action 14 sought to enhance the scope and effectiveness of dispute settlement mechanisms in bilateral double tax treaties, including through taxpayer access to mandatory binding arbitration.Footnote 11

In 2016, the OECD and G20 members established an Inclusive Framework, a structure which allows interested countries and jurisdictions to work on an equal footing with the OECD and G20 members in the next phase of the BEPS project. This structure currently includes 141 countries.Footnote 12 In 2017 many of these countries signed a Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS which, among other things, gave effect to rules developed under BEPS Action 14.Footnote 13 Signatories were free to opt out of some of the Instrument's provisions. As a result, only about 30 countries, mostly developed countries and low- or no-tax jurisdictions, committed to mandatory binding arbitration for certain tax disputes.

In October 2021, corporate interests obtained the inclusion of mandatory binding arbitration as part of a core component of the so-called Two Pillar Solution to the income tax challenges of digitalisation.Footnote 14 Despite traditionally strong resistance to taxpayer-initiated international tax arbitration outside of the OECD, especially from developing countries, and concerns raised by tax and political science scholars,Footnote 15 138 members of the Inclusive Framework agreed to an unprecedented role for binding dispute settlement within the international income tax regime without much fanfare.Footnote 16 This sudden turn of events warrants attention.

International dispute settlement will be available unevenly across different components of the Two Pillar Solution. Most significantly, Pillar One of the Two Pillar Solution will create a new taxing right, labelled ‘Amount A’, for the jurisdictions in which certain very large multinationals sell their products and derive non-routine profits.Footnote 17 The proposed multilateral convention that will establish the right to collect Amount A will permit multinationals to elect to have matters related to Amount A resolved in a mandatory and binding manner if State actions create a risk of juridical double taxation.Footnote 18 An arbitration decision relating to Amount A would bind all jurisdictions that are party to the multilateral convention establishing the right to collect Amount A.

The embrace of taxpayer-initiated, mandatory and multilaterally binding arbitration by the members of the Inclusive Framework is out of step with developments in international economic law.Footnote 19 The triumphalist rhetoric of international economic lawyers of two decades ago has disappeared, because of the sovereignty and legitimacy concerns of developed and developing countries created by international dispute settlement. The United States, for example, caused the World Trade Organization (WTO) dispute settlement system to collapse in 2019. Many States are rejecting or seeking to limit binding investor–State dispute settlement. The EU and other States are seeking to develop an appellate mechanism for investor–State dispute settlement because of the perceived shortcomings of ad hoc international arbitration. Tax arbitration procedures have attracted increased attention in the tax literature, but with only limited engagement with the challenges that dispute settlement is facing in other areas of international economic law.Footnote 20 So, it is both surprising and unsurprising that the recent embrace of binding mandatory dispute settlement in international taxation has occurred without any apparent reference to the challenges that dispute settlement has faced in trade and investment treaties. This article seeks to understand the likely future of international tax arbitration under the Two Pillar Solution in light of the existing role of arbitration in double tax treaties and the experience of other international economic law dispute settlement processes. For different reasons, the experiences under the international trade and investment regimes suggest that Two Pillar Solution dispute settlement processes and the ongoing Two Pillar Solution policy development and implementation will generate growing concerns with legitimacy and sovereignty. A rosy future is not assured. Greater investment in ensuring the legitimacy of dispute settlement processes is required.

The article proceeds as follows. Sections II and III examine how MAP arbitration and mandatory binding dispute resolution under the Two Pillar Solution is likely to operate. Section IV asks what lessons the international income tax regime may learn from the recent collapse of the WTO Appellate Body. Section V argues, despite the unique features of international tax arbitration, that many of the key concerns expressed about WTO dispute settlement and investor–State dispute settlement (ISDS) are applicable to binding arbitration under the Two Pillar Solution. Section VI concludes.

II. MAP ARBITRATION

A. Arbitration in International Taxation

Recognising that income from cross-border activities might be taxed in more than one jurisdiction, the model tax treaties provide that the country where income is generated (the source State) should have priority over the country of the taxpayer's residence (the residence State), and that active (business) income should be taxed at source, while passive (investment) income should be taxed on a residence basis. Much tax planning and cross-border income tax avoidance by multinationals takes advantage of the structure of the international income tax system, often by shifting profits to low- or no-tax jurisdictions where there is often little or no real economic activity. The efforts of one State to collect corporate income tax, close loopholes and respond to new forms of business organisation and tax planning may be challenged by a taxpayer or another State as inconsistent with a double tax treaty. Contentious cross-border tax rules and application of tax treaties are mostly litigated by taxpayers in national courts.Footnote 21 While cross-border tax matters are not infrequently the subject of inter-State consultations, the model tax conventions do not contain a standalone State–State dispute settlement mechanism. Double tax treaties of developed States, however, often have MAP provisions for resolving difficulties that arise out of the treaty.Footnote 22

Like investor–State dispute settlement, the MAP is an outgrowth of the process of diplomatic protection in general international law whereby a State asserts a claim against another State because one of its nationals has been treated in a manner that is in violation of international law.Footnote 23 Under the MAP, on the request of the taxpayer, the competent authorities of the Contracting States engage with each other and endeavour to resolve disputes that arise from the way that one or both contracting States have interpreted or applied the tax treaty.Footnote 24 The issues which may be subject to the MAP include transfer pricing adjustments, attribution of profits to permanent establishments, determination of residence of individuals and companies, deduction of withholding taxes, application of tax treaty anti-abuse provisions and the application of domestic anti-avoidance provisions. The competent authorities are required to endeavour to resolve the case by mutual agreement. If agreement is reached, it must be implemented by the contracting States.Footnote 25 The competent authorities may also resolve by mutual agreement any difficulties or doubts arising as to the interpretation or application of the tax treaty and eliminate double taxation in cases not provided under the treaty.Footnote 26

The number of MAP cases commenced each year has been growing since 2016.Footnote 27 In 2020, 2,508 cases were started, and 1,725 cases were closed.Footnote 28 Of the cases started and closed, 1,178 and 667 were transfer pricing cases. In 2018, just over 75 per cent of MAP cases were resolved, that is, the relevant competent authorities were able to reach agreement on the matter. The process is less effective in resolving the ‘big’ cases.Footnote 29 MAP cases are very concentrated, with 25 jurisdictions accounting for 95 per cent of the cases started in 2020.Footnote 30

Consistent with its origins in diplomatic protection, the MAP requires the competent authorities to act in good faith but does not require them to reach an agreement or to disclose their exchanges to the taxpayer.Footnote 31 As noted in the Introduction, over the past decade and a half, tax law, following the broader trend in international law, started giving more attention to individual remedies under international rules.Footnote 32 While most do not, the MAP provisions in some treaties now permit the taxpayer to submit issues that the competent authorities cannot resolve by mutual agreement to binding arbitration.Footnote 33 This was occurring at a time when some States were becoming increasingly wary of and withdrawing their consent to international dispute settlement in other areas of economic law, which reflects the general detachment of international tax law from other areas of international law.

Before the 2017 Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS was signed,Footnote 34 a little more than 200 double tax treaties included an arbitration procedure, and even then often arbitration was neither mandatory nor binding and the treaties did not specify the procedure for the arbitration.Footnote 35 Under Article 25(5) of the OECD Model Tax Convention, only claims of taxation not consistent with the tax treaty which were not resolved within two years of the submission of all relevant information to the competent authorities may be submitted to arbitration.Footnote 36 Precedence is, however, given to domestic court processes. The taxpayer is unable to initiate arbitration if a decision on the issues to be submitted to arbitration has already been rendered by a court of administrative tribunal of either State.Footnote 37

The MAP provisions in Article 25 have been criticised on many grounds, including the limited access to them, uncertainty, lack of transparency, long timeframe and no guarantee of resolution of the dispute.Footnote 38 Some steps to address these concerns were taken under BEPS Action 14 and the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS. Countries that join the Inclusive Framework must commit to implementing the 15 Action Items identified by the OECD to combat BEPS and meet the four Minimum Standards. The fourth Minimum Standard relates to treaty disputes and arbitration. Changes to the MAP processes brought about under the Inclusive Framework, and the signing of the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS, have improved both the effectiveness of MAPs and access to arbitration.Footnote 39 The Instrument, however, contains only optional provisions for the settlement of taxation disputes by arbitration, because of objections to mandatory arbitration from many jurisdictions.

The mandatory arbitration clause in the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS is a modified and more detailed version of the clause in Article 25(5) of the OECD Model Tax Convention. The Instrument did not formally amend double tax treaties but modified some of the rights and obligations of the parties to those treaties because it was a more recent treaty under Article 30(3) of the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties.Footnote 40 Article 30 of the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS expressly preserves the rights of the parties to a double tax treaty to amend that treaty. The bilateral obligations created by tax treaties and the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS differentiate MAP arbitration from a multilateral dispute settlement mechanism. Under double tax treaty provisions like Article 25, disputes are resolved through application of the relevant double tax treaty rather than domestic law. This will probably increase the importance of the Explanatory Statement adopted at the time of the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS and any OECD Commentary on arbitration proceedings.Footnote 41

As of December 2022, 100 jurisdictions have signed the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS.Footnote 42 If all 100 ratified the Instrument and made no reservations, up to 1,700 tax treaties could be modified. However, the Instrument only modifies double tax treaties in force between parties to the Instrument which have been listed by both parties as covered by the Instrument.Footnote 43 Modification is also subject to parties’ reservations. So far, around 650 bilateral double tax treaties have been modified.Footnote 44 The United States has, however, not signed the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS.Footnote 45 Nonetheless, the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS entered into force on 1 July 2018.

So far, the Instrument has had a limited observable impact on tax arbitration. As noted above, the mandatory binding arbitration provisions of the Instrument (Articles 18 to 26) only apply if both jurisdictions to a dispute have expressly decided that their bilateral double tax treaty is a covered tax agreement. Only 30 jurisdictions have opted in. Furthermore, few (if any) of these jurisdictions are likely to be connected by double tax treaties to all of the other 29 jurisdictions that are opting in.Footnote 46 The Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS also permits the jurisdictions that opt in to make reservations and therefore limit the scope of the mandatory arbitration clause,Footnote 47 and over half of jurisdictions opting in have chosen to do so.Footnote 48

As with Article 25 of the OECD Model Tax Convention, once an arbitration decision has been delivered, the contracting States are expected to implement it through the MAP.Footnote 49 However, an arbitration decision does not need to be implemented if the contracting States agree on a different solution.Footnote 50 The taxpayer also has the option to reject the arbitration decision or litigate in a national court.Footnote 51 Arbitration decisions can also be declared invalid by national courts.Footnote 52

In 2016, an International Fiscal Association report stated that apart from a couple of cases, most States had no experience in tax arbitration, observing that ‘it is evident that taxpayers cannot rely on this mechanism in the way [it] is implemented today’.Footnote 53 A couple of years later the number of arbitrations appears to have grown. Mann cites data from Europe, where in 2018 out of a total of 942 pending MAP cases there were 47 arbitrations, and in 2019 out of 778 pending MAP cases there were 42 arbitrations.Footnote 54 If slightly over 5 per cent of MAP cases are going to arbitration that is not insignificant. The prospect of mandatory arbitration will encourage the competent authorities to reach an agreement that is in line with the double tax treaty. On the other hand, greater familiarity with the arbitration process is probably leading to a greater number of cases.Footnote 55 The use of arbitration in international tax matters appears to be growing, albeit from a low base.

B. Limitations of MAP Arbitration

Developing countries remained wary of the risks associated with the arbitration of tax disputes when the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS was developed.Footnote 56 They had multiple concerns, including loss of sovereignty, their experience with investor–State dispute settlement, substantial litigation and revenue loss costs, and limited experience in or capacity to arbitrate. As a consequence, binding mandatory arbitration became optional in the BEPS project. Article 25(5) modified under the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS has a number of limitations as a dispute settlement mechanism and did not meet all of the expectations of corporate taxpayers.

Only cases where taxes have actually been charged can be submitted to arbitration under the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS.Footnote 57 This condition would appear to preclude advisory decisions and may reduce the opportunities of corporate taxpayers to use MAP arbitration strategically. Nonetheless, MAP arbitration is still seen as primarily a benefit for taxpayers and its inclusion in the BEPS Action 14 Minimum Standard was supported by the business community. Taxpayers have little to lose from arbitration and cannot be really said to be bound by the process or the outcome. The Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS does not contain a fork-in-the-road clause typical of investment treaties. Taxpayers are generally free to exit the MAP process and pursue remedies under domestic law at any time,Footnote 58 but cannot pursue MAP and domestic remedies simultaneously.Footnote 59 Even after the competent authorities have negotiated a resolution or the matter has been arbitrated, the taxpayer is not bound to accept the outcome.Footnote 60

On the other hand, the competent authorities can also agree on a longer or shorter period than the usual two-year period before MAP arbitration can be commenced.Footnote 61 If any of the competent authorities fail to appoint a member of the arbitration panel in the manner and in the timeframe specified in Article 19(2) of the Instrument, a member is appointed by the highest-ranking official of the OECD Centre for Tax Policy. However, without a default set of rules for arbitration, delays or the withholding of agreement on the rules will prevent arbitration proceeding. The Instrument rules therefore cannot be seen as providing the same consent to international arbitration normally present in investment treaties.Footnote 62

Two types of arbitration are foreseen under the Instrument rules: baseball type arbitration and legal opinion arbitration. Legal opinion arbitration anticipates a reasoned decision as might be expected in an international trade dispute settlement or investor–State arbitration. Under baseball arbitration, each party puts forward its preferred solution, and the arbitration panel must choose between the two solutions.Footnote 63 Baseball-type arbitration aims to narrow the differences between the parties and discourage extreme positions because they are likely to be rejected by the arbitrators. A jurisdiction may make reservations as to the type of arbitration in which it is prepared to engage. Jurisdictions party to a dispute may therefore have incompatible preferences, in which case arbitration cannot go forward until the parties agree on the format of the arbitration.Footnote 64 The process for baseball-type arbitration may be speedier than legal opinion arbitration. However, decisions will have no precedential value and lack transparency. While the legal opinion approach formerly does not create a precedent, the existence of legal opinions helps to clarify legal rules and advance legal certainty. Their existence is likely to affect the future actions of tax administrations and arbitrators even if they are subject to broad confidentiality obligations.Footnote 65

MAP decisions are generally not made public, which may be explained by the process being rooted in diplomatic protection, the nature of baseball arbitration, taxpayer privacy and commercial secrecy concerns, and a wish to avoid the creation of precedents.Footnote 66 The lack of transparency and legal certainty under the MAP is often criticised.Footnote 67 The OECD admitted that publishing reasoned arbitral decisions ‘would lend additional transparency to the process’ and ‘having the material in the public domain could influence the course of other cases so as to avoid subsequent disputes and lead to a more uniform approach to the same issue’.Footnote 68 Unless MAP arbitration decisions are reasoned and published, they will not influence the interpretation or application of the tax treaty by national courts.

In summary, prior to the Two Pillar Solution being agreed, arbitration was available under only a small fraction of the over 3,000 bilateral tax treaties, and, even when it was available, consent to be bound by the arbitration by either the contracting States or the taxpayer was highly qualified.

III. BINDING DISPUTE SETTLEMENT IN THE TWO PILLAR SOLUTION

The Two Pillar Solution, reached after lengthy and at time difficult negotiations, was the global response to the income tax challenges arising from the digitalisation of the economy.Footnote 69 A full account of the negotiations or the outcome is beyond the scope of this article, but some background is necessary. Despite the modest role played so far in international taxation, international tax dispute resolution was a key element of the negotiations leading to the Two Pillar Solution. This section examines the scope for the use of international dispute settlement procedures to resolve issues arising from the Two Pillar Solution. Different aspects of the Two Pillar Solution were matched with different international dispute settlement responses, ranging from none to the creation of a radical multilateral process for the new taxing right ‘Amount A’.

The income tax challenges arising from the digitalisation of the economy are central to BEPS Action 1.Footnote 70 Cross-border online commerce was thriving and the companies operating the international digital platforms had grown rapidly and were making enormous profits but were paying little or no income tax in most of the jurisdictions where their customers were located. The ability to structure a business so that little or no corporate income tax is paid in many jurisdictions where customers are located, and from which significant profits are derived, may have been taken to a new level by the digital platforms, but is not unique to them. The digital platforms nonetheless provided the political imperative for governments to take some action.

The United States as the home State to most of the largest digital platforms was not keen on changes to the century-old framework for the international allocation of rights to tax income that would increase the tax bases of States importing the digital services and goods sold online. The combination of the political imperative for action in market States and the unwillingness of the United States and others to contemplate a change that was outside the conceptual structure of the existing international income tax regime led to policy innovation. A key innovation was the introduction or threat of the introduction of digital services taxes on some suppliers of digital services. Such taxes were not necessarily inconsistent with the WTO and essentially fall outside double taxation treaties, but the United States was firmly opposed and reacted strongly.Footnote 71

The Two Pillar Solution is a compromise suggested by the OECD's Secretariat in response to the demands of the United States. In the version accepted by Inclusive Framework members in October 2021, Pillar One aims to ease tensions between the home jurisdictions and market jurisdictions of large multinationals, essentially, by agreeing to a new taxing right for market jurisdictions known as Amount A in exchange for a prohibition on the use of digital services taxes and similar taxes. The introduction of Amount A will require a level of multilateral coordination and cooperation not seen previously in taxation.

Pillar Two aims to address a different set of concerns arising from corporate income tax competition. It seeks to incentivise all countries to apply a minimum level of corporate income taxation for multinational enterprises, but without tax rates being set under a binding treaty. The key rules that were agreed are modified versions of tax measures unilaterally introduced by the United States.

A. Pillar One

The Pillar One rules seek to reallocate, for the purposes of corporate income tax, some of the profits of very large and very profitable multinationals and multinationals engaged in specific intra-group transactions.Footnote 72 The two main legal elements of Pillar One are an agreement on a new taxing right for market jurisdictions (Amount A) with a binding dispute resolution procedure, which would be implemented through a multilateral convention and domestic legislation;Footnote 73 and a domestic transfer pricing rule for market jurisdictions known as Amount B.Footnote 74 Only some host countries will be able to collect both Amount A and Amount B from qualified multinationals. A draft of the proposed multilateral convention for Amount A is yet to be released. Of the publicly available information, the 225-page October 2020 Pillar One Blueprint sets out the overall design of the Amount A rules and institutions. Subsequently, the OECD has released for public consultation draft model rules for some aspects of Amount A, but not yet for international dispute settlement.Footnote 75

The proposed multilateral convention for Amount A will contain a broad array of institutional and procedural rules to make the substantive rules workable, as well as a prohibition on the use of digital services taxes and similar measures. On 20 December 2022, the OECD released for public consultation draft provisions for the removal of all existing digital services taxes and other relevant similar measures.Footnote 76 The multilateral convention will create mutual obligations on taxation for all jurisdictions that are party to the convention, whether or not they are presently connected through a bilateral double tax treaty. While only a relatively small fraction of pairs of jurisdictions have committed to binding arbitration in their double tax treaties, under the multilateral convention for Amount A multinationals will be able to elect to have issues related to Amount A resolved in a mandatory and binding manner if they are at risk of juridical double taxation.Footnote 77 The focus in the OECD documentation is on providing certainty to multinationals—on request—rather than assisting tax administrations challenging multinationals’ self-assessment or the validation of the self-assessment by the lead tax administration.Footnote 78 The proposed Amount A dispute settlement system gives prominence to the norm against juridical double taxation, which protects corporate interests in relation to the Amount A and creates a precedent for the future.

Aside from Pillar One, virtually all tax disputes are handled in bilateral processes, and sometimes a series of bilateral processes, rather than through a multilateral process.Footnote 79 Corporate taxpayers, however, can seek multilateral dispute prevention and/or resolution for Amount A. The design of the Amount A allocation rules, which involves an assessment of income of the entire multinational group, probably necessitates some sort of multilateral process, because any dispute between two jurisdictions over Amount A will probably affect the taxation of Amount A in multiple jurisdictions.Footnote 80 Baseball arbitration will not work for a dispute over Amount A or similar tax bases.Footnote 81 The Pillar One Blueprint proposes that a panel of a representative sample of tax administrations from jurisdictions where the multinational operates will conduct a substantive review of the multinational's self-assessment. Tax administrations from all jurisdictions affected by the allocation of Amount A will have an opportunity to object to the panel's decision. The dispute resolution process is then envisaged to operate as follows:Footnote 82

  • If the review panel cannot reach agreement or cannot accommodate objections from other tax administrations, questions will be referred to a determination panel that is required to reach a decision, which is binding on all tax administrations.

  • Rules for dispute prevention and resolution could be embedded in the same instrument that introduces rules for the taxation of Amount A, ensuring that the new taxing right is linked to the availability of the new and enhanced tax certainty regime.

These commitments will go far beyond what is offered under the 2017 Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS. Indeed, the process is intended to address some of the limitations of MAP arbitration, including its voluntary and bilateral nature. The process envisages a very significant delegation of authority in relation to Amount A to a determination panel. The arbitration will take the final determination of the rules governing Amount A out of the hands of individual States. The Pillar One Blueprint, however, proposes that the determination panel result will not bind the multinational that triggered the process.Footnote 83 Moreover, the tax administrations would be bound even if the multinational withdraws from the process.Footnote 84 This is an unusual arrangement. There are no risks to a multinational commencing the dispute settlement process because they can walk away at any point. The multinational will be able to pursue other remedies against a State for not complying with the treaty or domestic law, possibly including when the State is complying with the decision of the determination panel. The existence of multiple remedies will strengthen the negotiating position of the multinational with tax administrations and contribute to multi-jurisdictional litigation strategies.

The ability of taxpayers to reject the outcomes of MAP arbitration has been justified on the basis that the taxpayers have a constitutional or human right to access the courts, and the taxpayer is not party to the arbitration.Footnote 85 The first reason flows from the second. The consent to arbitration of participating jurisdictions and the rights of the multinational under the Pillar One Blueprint proposal are now closer to investor–State arbitration than the traditional MAP arbitration.

An elective binding dispute resolution mechanism is also being considered for eligible developing economies.Footnote 86 Again, something beyond the enhancements of tax arbitration offered in the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS must be contemplated. The eligibility of developing countries will be reviewed regularly. Once found ineligible by a review, jurisdictions will remain ineligible in all subsequent years.Footnote 87 The prospect for this mechanism is unclear. Unless the rules for developing country-initiated arbitration are part of the multilateral convention establishing the Amount A taxing rights, the jurisdictions that are home to most of the multinationals will have little incentive to implement the agreed dispute settlement mechanism.

The other main component of Pillar One, Amount B, is a new transfer pricing rule for the allocation of business profits related to transactions between members of a multinational group. The rule will apply to ‘in-country baseline marketing and distribution activities’ of subsidiaries or permanent establishments of a multinational group in the market jurisdiction and will standardise the remuneration for these activities.Footnote 88 The objective is to increase the profits that will be subject to corporate income taxation in market jurisdictions. The introduction of the Amount B rule by a market jurisdiction will require that jurisdiction to secure agreements to amend its double tax treaties. Any disputes related to the application of Amount B in a way which creates the risk of double taxation under transfer pricing rules may also be subject to mandatory binding dispute resolution if a relevant double tax treaty allows.Footnote 89 Amount B will therefore be subject to different dispute settlement rules than Amount A. In fairness, Amount B is likely to be subject to fewer disputes than Amount A because Amount B is founded on a fixed rate of return on baseline marketing and distribution activities.Footnote 90

The publication of well-reasoned arbitration decisions would seem to be important to reducing uncertainty over how the provisions will be implemented.Footnote 91 In this regard, the past practice in relation to MAP arbitration is not reassuring. In any event, the multilateral process envisaged for Amount A dispute resolution may require creative thinking to address issues associated with the sharing of commercially sensitive information while protecting the rights of all jurisdictions to object.

B. Global Anti-Base Erosion Rules

Implementation of Pillar Two of the Two Pillar Solution would create three new domestic tax rules (together known as the Global anti-Base Erosion (GloBE) rules) and a model treaty rule (the Subject to Tax Rule) for double tax treaties.Footnote 92 The three GloBE rules are the Qualified Domestic Minimum Top Up Tax on the excess profits of a constituent entity of a multinational located in the jurisdiction; the Income Inclusion Rule, which imposes a top-up tax on a parent entity in respect of the low taxed income of a constituent entity, which may be in or outside the jurisdiction; and the Undertaxed Payment Rule, which denies deductions or requires an equivalent adjustment to the extent that the low tax income of a constituent entity is not subject to tax under the Income Inclusion Rule.Footnote 93 The rules are complex, but the core idea is that where a source jurisdiction imposes a corporate income tax of less than 15 per cent on an entity of a multinational enterprise, another jurisdiction that hosts a parent or related entity of the same multinational will be able to impose a top-up tax that equals the difference between the actual level of taxation in the source jurisdiction and 15 per cent. There are, of course, exceptions and further rules setting out the top-up taxing rights and priorities of those rights for multinational enterprises with entities in multiple jurisdictions. The GloBE rules address more than the headline corporate income tax rate and will limit the ability of countries to provide tax holidays to attract investment, which are common in developing countries. Some workarounds will be possible, but difficult where the source jurisdiction is a low- or no-tax jurisdiction where no real economic activity occurs, ie, a tax haven. The GloBE rules are designed, it is claimed, to dampen corporate income tax competition heavily even if only the major capital exporting jurisdictions implement the full suite of GloBE rules.

The GloBE rules are intended to be domestic and voluntary but, according to the OECD, ‘will have the status of a common approach’, which means that members of the Inclusive Framework on BEPS ‘are not required to adopt the GloBE rules, but, if they choose to do so, they will implement and administer the rules in a way that is consistent with the outcomes provided for under Pillar Two, including in light of model rules and guidance agreed to by the IF [Inclusive Framework]’; and ‘accept the application of the GloBE rules applied by other IF members including agreement as to rule order and the application of any agreed safe harbours’.Footnote 94 These are significant commitments. For a voluntary arrangement, it is highly prescriptive, except for the relationship between GloBE and the United States’ Global Intangible Low-Taxed Income (known as GILTI) regime,Footnote 95 which is left open in the OECD documents. The two taxes have similar aims, and the United States tax provided the inspiration for the GloBE rules, but they are different in important ways.Footnote 96

A range of tax disputes may arise under the GloBE rules, notwithstanding the claim that the rules ‘have been designed in a way to minimise the scope for disputes concerning their application across multiple jurisdictions’.Footnote 97 First, some commentators have argued that GloBE may itself breach many double tax treaties.Footnote 98 Similar but contested claims have been made in relation to GILTI and Base Erosion Anti-Abuse Tax (BEAT) taxes in the United States.Footnote 99 In October 2021, the OECD stated that at the latest by the end of 2022 an implementation framework will be developed that facilitates the coordinated implementation of the GloBE rules.Footnote 100 At a minimum, a switchover rule, which is a mechanism that would enable home jurisdictions to amend or override double tax treaty obligations under which they have committed to exempt profits attributable to foreign permanent establishments, is needed. Without the switchover rule, the GloBE rules could not treat exempt branches the same as foreign subsidiaries to prevent low-taxed income of a foreign branch being combined with high-taxed income in the home jurisdiction. If this view is correct, the fact the GloBE rules are domestic and not treaty based means that they might be challenged under a double tax treaty, if they are inconsistent with the treaty. Secondly, the Qualified Domestic Minimum Top Up Tax or the top-up tax under the Undertaxed Payment Rule may be applied to a multinational in a manner inconsistent with the Two Pillar Solution. Thirdly, both top-up taxes may be applied by more than one State to the same multinational. The second and third possibilities appear to be the motivation for an agreement providing for binding mandatory arbitration, because multinationals are at risk of juridical double taxation.

The proposed mechanism for implementation of the GloBE rules does not contemplate a multilateral convention. MAP arbitration is only possible where the relevant States are already connected by a double tax treaty and, even then, arbitration is usually not available to resolve disputes. This suggests that mandatory binding dispute resolution will not generally be available for Pillar Two issues. In any event, the availability of MAP arbitration along the lines of Article 25 of the OECD Model Tax Convention may not be able to resolve some types of dispute. The possibility that top-up taxes are imposed by more than one jurisdiction leading to juridical double taxation may require multiple jurisdictions to be party to a dispute to allocate taxing rights consistently, unless all these jurisdictions amend domestic legislation with provisions that create a MAP obligation for them.Footnote 101 It would be possible for States to commit to arbitrate certain tax disputes in national legislation as part of the ‘common approach’.

If binding dispute settlement was available, the issue of the relationship between the United States’ GILTI regime and the GloBE rules might be impossible to avoid. Assuming that the GILTI regime is not in conformance of the common approach agreed in the GloBE rules, the United States practice might be challenged. This possibility is unlikely to be acceptable to the United States. Assuming, however, that a dispute settlement challenge by a multinational to the imposition of an additional tax under the GILTI regime was possible, a jurisdiction might wish to seek a negotiated resolution with the United States to avoid an arbitration decision. A finding that the GILTI regime is inconsistent with a tax treaty or other international instrument may simply force the United States to demand the amendment to the international agreement or other action. Many States would not wish to see their relationship with the United States be put at risk.

C. Subject to Tax Rule

The Subject to Tax Rule will allow source jurisdictions to tax certain related-party payments (eg, interest; royalties; franchise fees; insurance premiums; guarantee, brokerage or financing fees; rent payments for movable property; and consideration for the supply of marketing, procurement, agency or other intermediary services between two companies which are part of the same multinational group) that are taxed in the jurisdiction where the taxpayer received the payment (which will usually be the taxpayer's residence jurisdiction) at a nominal corporate income tax rate below 9 per cent.Footnote 102 The Subject to Tax Rule would only apply between developed and developing countries.

The implementation of the Subject to Tax Rule will require the amendment of a jurisdiction's double tax treaties because the rule would affect treaty commitments made in relation to taxation of passive income. The Inclusive Framework members are yet to agree on whether the Subject to Tax Rule will be implemented by means of a model treaty provision which would need to be incorporated in each double tax treaty by its amendment or through incorporation of the Subject to Tax Rule in a multilateral instrument that will modify rights under double tax treaties.Footnote 103 Either option may well lead to partial or delayed implementation of the Two Pillar Solution. Once incorporated into the relevant tax treaties, the Subject to Tax Rule would be subject to the MAP, including arbitration if available.Footnote 104 Otherwise disputes relating to the income tax in the recipient or source jurisdiction are subject to domestic processes. The OECD commentary on the Subject to Tax Rule will probably be influential for interpretation in both domestic processes and the resolution of disputes through a MAP.

Without a comprehensive multilateral instrument, the legal rights under Pillar Two will be asymmetrical. A foreign multinational operating in a developed country objecting to the imposition of a Subject to Tax Rule tax would be able to invoke the MAP in a double tax treaty. A developing country objecting to the failure of a developed country to agree to the amendment of a double tax treaty would not have similar rights and would not have a right to countermeasures under general international law unless the commitment of Inclusive Framework members to the Subject to Tax Rule is ultimately contained in a binding legal instrument. Where there is no double tax treaty, no dispute settlement provisions will be applicable unless they are contained in a multilateral instrument. The United States has been prepared to agree to bilateral tax arbitration similar to Article 25 of the OECD Model Tax Convention but would be likely to baulk at a multilateral instrument with mandatory arbitration provisions. Unlike Amount A, dispute settlement is not or less essential here to protect US multinationals from juridical double taxation.

D. Uncertain Future

The future of the Two Pillar Solution is not settled. The Pillar Two report observes that ‘It may be possible to include the GloBE provision in the new multilateral instrument considered under Pillar One, which could also have the benefit of setting out the interaction between Pillar One and Pillar Two.’Footnote 105 This now seems unlikely. Even so, it will only concern jurisdictions that see a benefit in Amount A relative to the costs and benefits of digital services taxes and similar taxes. A less positive view of the benefits of Pillar One for many States is possible after they have considered the legislation and administrative steps required to collect their share of Amount A.

The Two Pillar Solution will be implemented through an array of binding and non-binding instruments. The multilateral convention that is intended to give effect to Amount A and the prohibition on digital services taxes will presumably not enter into force until it has achieved a specified critical mass of ratifications. The number will be set to reassure the parties that enough jurisdictions are committed so that convention provides net benefits to its members. When a jurisdiction ratifies the convention, that not only creates international obligations and rights but also affects the interests of both parties and non-parties, including in relation to their own ratification decisions. Jurisdictions that contemplate ratifying later in time will consider the identity and reservations of other jurisdictions that have ratified. Moreover, if a decision to ratify is made, reservations may be crafted in response to the ratifications and reservations of other parties. Putting aside issues that may arise from the possibility of reservations, some jurisdictions are likely to hold off ratifying the Pillar One multilateral convention quickly. Dispute settlement may be one of the key issues.

Most jurisdictions will have little incentive to ratify the proposed multilateral convention for Pillar One's Amount A until it is clear that the United States will also ratify. They will not wish to be caught with an obligation to implement the convention when the home jurisdictions of the in-scope multinationals are not parties to the convention. Implementation of Amount A rules without a multilateral convention may result in a jurisdiction breaching, inter alia, the equivalent of Articles 5, 7 and 9 of the OECD Model Tax Convention that are in many double tax treaties. If the United States wishes to act in a manner that is consistent with its existing double tax treaties, it will need to amend its laws. It is not clear how easy it would be to take amendments to multiple double tax treaties and introduce the multilateral convention for Amount A through the United States Senate. The politics of corporate income tax and the aversion to a loss of sovereignty and binding dispute settlement will be significant obstacles.

The situation with Pillar Two is different. On 22 December 2022, the Council of the EU issued the Minimum Tax Directive which requires Member States to incorporate the Pillar Two rules into domestic law by 31 December 2023. EU members with no more than 12 ultimate parent entities of in-scope multinational enterprises, however, can delay introduction of the Directive until 31 December 2029.Footnote 106 As noted above, the United States already has rules that are similar to but not compliant with the GloBE rules. There is no consensus on which non-EU jurisdictions will have a strong interest in the implementation of Pillar Two.Footnote 107 Much depends on how jurisdictions make decisions under conditions of uncertainty. Arguably, some jurisdictions will have little incentive to ratify a multilateral instrument implementing Pillar Two quickly unless the United States links that to its ratification of Pillar One. If that view is correct, the failure of the United States to ratify the multilateral convention for Pillar's One Amount A may cause the previously widespread support for Pillar Two to unravel. The major capital-exporting countries will still have the legitimation of a unilaterally implemented rule that protects their tax base and countries as destination for investment.

The value of Pillar Two to jurisdictions other than the United States may, in part, depend on the relationship between the GloBE and the similar tax provisions already in place in the United States (GILTI and BEAT). If the ‘common approach’ has no treaty basis, inconsistent approaches to the GloBE rules and double taxation are the likely consequences. A treaty basis for GloBE would, however, put certain tax exemptions at risk in many jurisdictions. The risk of politically significant tax exemptions being examined in a MAP arbitration is likely to be politically problematic for some countries, including the United States. If this analysis is correct, unilateralism and treaty overrides seem the likely outcome.

The final binding and non-binding instruments intended to give effect to the Two Pillar Solution have not been finalised, accepted and implemented by the members of the Inclusive Framework. The future of the package and its elements is not certain. Inclusive Framework members have decisions to make, including on the role of dispute settlement in any new international tax rules. In making those decisions, members should understand the political limits of adjudication of disputes in international economic law and explicitly address the need for legitimacy and public accountability. These issues are taken up in Sections IV and V below.

IV. POLITICAL VIABILITY OF INTERNATIONAL DISPUTE SETTLEMET

Establishing and maintaining binding international dispute settlement are not easy. The experience in the WTO suggests that even if mandatory binding arbitration of international tax disputes is agreed, sustaining that system over the decades will face challenges. The challenges are likely to grow as the number of cases and the ‘size’ of the cases increase. The Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU) was part of the grand bargain that produced the WTO.Footnote 108 The more power-oriented approach to dispute settlement under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) is often contrasted with the conscious move to the more rule-oriented WTO processes.Footnote 109 Under the DSU, members no longer had the ability to delay or block the formation of a panel, agreement on terms of reference, appointment of panellists, adoption of panel recommendations, or authorisation of retaliation. The DSU created a right of appeal to the Appellate Body, which was often described as the ‘crown jewel’ of the WTO. Within a decade of the establishment of the WTO, the Appellate Body emerged as one among the most widely used and strongest international courts and enjoyed broad support from the WTO members.Footnote 110 Despite popular perceptions of the Appellate Body as a world trade court, the intention was never to create a strict rule of WTO law. Political oversight and, in theory, control were essential elements.

In 2018, taking advantage of the consensus rule for decision-making, the Trump administration decided to block all appointments to the Appellate Body.Footnote 111 By December 2019, the Appellate Body was left with just one member. The last three members of the Appellate Body agreed to continue working on the three appeals for which a hearing had been held after their terms expired.Footnote 112 Work on all other appeals was indefinitely suspended. Without an Appellate Body decision, the disputes remain unresolved, and the challenged measures remained in place. The Biden administration has continued to block the appointment process.

Since the demise of the Appellate Body, almost all of the disputes have been appealed ‘into the void’, preventing the adoption of the panel report by the Dispute Settlement Body. A further consequence has been the dramatic drop in the number of WTO disputes that have been commenced. In 2018 there were 38 requests for consultation and in 2019 there were 20. By contrast, in 2020 there were five and in 2021 there were nine.Footnote 113 In 2021, ten panels and one compliance panel were established, and seven reports relating to nine disputes were circulated, but eight disputes were appealed. As of 31 December 2022, 24 disputes were pending before the Appellate Body.Footnote 114

The reasons for the collapse of the WTO dispute settlement are salient to the growing role of binding dispute settlement in the international tax regime. The United States has voiced a number of complaints about the Appellate Body and WTO dispute settlement system but has not (yet) identified what it thinks needs to be done to fix the system. The Appellate Body was said not to have followed its own rules, including ignoring mandatory deadlines for completion of reports; allowed Appellate Body members to continue to sit after the expiry of their terms; reviewed questions of fact and not just law; treated Appellate Body reports as binding precedents for panels; opined on matters not necessary to resolve a dispute; and sought to determine matters that are within the authority of WTO members.Footnote 115 The substantive concerns of the United States focused on trade remedy cases that went against the United States, in particular those prohibiting ‘zeroing’ and the defining ‘public bodies’. While some of these concerns were shared by other members,Footnote 116 the scholarly consensus is that the United States’ complaints were overstated if not outright wrong.Footnote 117 The United States has declined, and continues to decline as of mid-2022, to engage with proposals from other members that would be the restoration of the Appellate Body.Footnote 118 The recent statements of the United States in the WTO indicate that it is not ready to agree to a restoration of binding dispute settlement, notwithstanding United States participation in informal consultations about WTO reform.Footnote 119 In the meantime, the United States has commenced and defended panel proceedings and appealed some but not all panel reports into the void.

The conduct of the United States in the WTO is consistent with the long-standing aversion to binding third-party dispute settlement in the United States. The United States has not ratified treaties because, at least in part, of opposition to dispute settlement provisions and refused to submit to the general jurisdiction of the International Court of Justice, Inter-American Court of Human Rights, International Tribunal for the Law of the Sea, or International Criminal Court.Footnote 120 Such conduct is consistent with the preference, identified by international relations scholars, of hegemonic powers for diplomatic rather than legal dispute settlement, where they can deploy their power to greatest advantage. Only a rather unique set of circumstances encouraged members of the United States Senate to accept that the downside of the WTO dispute settlements system was outweighed by the rest of the WTO in 1994.Footnote 121 The strong support of corporate business in the United States and the wishful expectation that arbitration will largely only constrain other jurisdictions might suggest that tax arbitration could receive a pass. A more realistic outcome is that arbitration might constrain United States tax legislation, and therefore will be rejected by the United States Senate, which, it has been argued above, might put pressure on the Two Pillar Solution.

A focal point of the United States government's discontent with the DSU was the outcome of several disputes with China.Footnote 122 The outcomes were the result of fairly literal interpretations of the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures. Discontent with the decisions therefore is not entirely consistently with the United States’ concern about judicial activism. The source of the discontent with the decision lay ultimately in the economic and geopolitical challenge today perceived to be posed by China, but not anticipated when China acceded to the WTO in 1995.Footnote 123 The same concerns may over time afflict dispute settlement under the Two Pillar Solution if Pillar One is implemented. As economic and geostrategic environments change, the major powers may find the Two Pillar Solution rules, or certain interpretations of the rules produced by arbitrators, less convenient, in which case continued adherence to the regime or individual decisions is unlikely.

Other countries have maintained a greater commitment to dispute settlement in international economic law. The EU's response to the collapse of the Appellate Body was to establish a Multi-Party Interim Appellate Arbitration Arrangement,Footnote 124 which could provide effective appellate review to the signatories on the basis of Article 25 of the DSU and guarantee the adoption of a panel report by the Dispute Settlement Body. Australia, Brazil, Canada, China and Japan are among the 48 signatories. India and most African and Asian WTO members are not a party. The parties in several disputes have already agreed to use the Multi-Party Interim Appellate Arbitration Arrangement. The EU also takes compliance with WTO panel decisions seriously.Footnote 125 The EU's commitment to multilateral processes is not, however, unconditional. The EU has indicated its willingness to resort to unilateral countermeasures under general principles of international law,Footnote 126 and use dispute settlement provisions in its preferential trade agreements.Footnote 127 Nonetheless, the collapse of the Appellate Body is widely seen as likely to bring about a longer-term shift away from a rule-based trading system.Footnote 128

The selective attachment of major powers to international law does not go unnoticed. Some developing countries have also been prepared to sabotage regional courts that have ruled against them.Footnote 129 Only a third of WTO members chose to join the Multi-Party Interim Appellate Arbitration Arrangement. Small countries will be circumspect about likely outcomes of agreements to arbitrate a cross-border tax issue, if large States refuse to submit to binding WTO dispute settlement or do not implement panel recommendations, especially in the light of the underdeveloped mechanisms for the enforcement of MAP tax arbitration decisions.Footnote 130 Non-compliance by large States might facilitate small States doing likewise. Under the Two Pillar Solution smaller countries may then have the ability not to comply with arbitration decisions that go against them.

The Appellate Body crisis was fuelled by the inability of the WTO members to clarify and develop the WTO agreements through negotiation. Being left to interpret ambiguous provisions, the Appellate Body was criticised for being overly textual. Textualism provided a device for the Appellate Body to insulate itself from the political controversies within and surrounding the WTO.Footnote 131 The features of MAP and Pillar One's Amount A arbitration discussed above might temporarily shield decisions from scrutiny and decision-makers from accountability. On the other hand, experience with dispute settlement in other contexts shows that these same features will generate legitimacy challenges (see Section V below). It is unclear whether the Two Pillar Solution dispute settlement processes will be able to walk what appears to be the narrow pathFootnote 132 required to maintain political and professional community support and doing what it does in a manner that comports with the basic requirements of the rule of law.

Further challenges may come from different quarters. The Two Pillar Solution affects not only individual taxpayers but mandates tax policies that affect multiple public interests. The anti-globalisation movement has attacked the WTO for not being adequately concerned with the environment, health or human rights.Footnote 133 One basis for the criticism is that these values are required to be considered because members have binding obligations under other areas of international law. The principle of the harmonious interpretation of different rules of international law could play a greater role in the international tax regime than the WTO.Footnote 134 Sustainable development and the right to developmentFootnote 135 are directly affected by international tax rules, and the response to BEPS issues, and arguably have a role to play in the interpretation of international tax instruments, even though these issues have been traditionally side-lined in OECD tax policy-making processes.Footnote 136 If non-tax considerations are invoked, commercial interests may be concerned. With greater prominence will come greater politicisation of tax arbitration.

One lesson from the WTO is that the establishment of dispute settlement regimes is a political act, and the resilience of any regime cannot be guaranteed. Tensions created by institutional design weaknesses, changing geo-economic circumstances, and litigation losses may grow over time. The WTO DSU was never expected to enforce a strict rule of trade law, but even the inbuilt flexibility proved insufficient, and the future of the binding dispute settlement in the WTO has been put into question by the United States. These considerations suggest that the signs for binding dispute settlement under the Two Pillar Solution are not auspicious. The rights conferred on multinational taxpayers differentiates the situation from the WTO. However, the Inclusive Framework members have failed to heed the lessons learnt from investor–State dispute settlement in the design of their mechanisms.

V. SOME COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN LESSONS

Global governance has seen the rise in novel forms of public authority and the demise of a sharp national–international divide.Footnote 137 Dispute settlement under the Two Pillar Solution fits that broader trend. In this regard, the international rax regime bears some resemblance to the international investment protection regime. Both are primarily structured by several thousand bilateral agreements that share many common provisions, and protect the private economic interests in capital-exporting countries.Footnote 138 The Two Pillar Solution and the international tax regime in general, however, embody a different balance between bilateral and multilateral rights compared to the investment and trade regimes. International tax has been on the move from a bilateral towards a multilateral order.Footnote 139 A long-standing controversy is whether the WTO agreements create a bundle of bilateral obligations or whether the agreements pursue a common purpose.Footnote 140 The situation in the tax regime is clearer. Some of the international obligations to be created under the Two Pillar Solution appear to be multilateral (eg, rules relating to Amount A), while others are bilateral (eg, Subject to Tax Rule) even where the rules have their origin in a multilateral instrument. Notwithstanding the limitations on MAP arbitration discussed in Section IIB and structural differences, the experience under the international investment regime speaks most directly to the design choices being made for dispute settlement under the Two Pillar Solution.Footnote 141

The number of investor–State arbitration cases rose significantly after the mid-1990s (see Section IIA). Now, international tax arbitration case numbers look set to increase, if not follow a similar trajectory, which has cost and political implications for many countries. The total investor–State dispute settlement (ISDS) case count had reached over 1,100 by the end of 2020. Claims of over US$100 million are common.Footnote 142 To date, 124 countries and one economic grouping are known to have been respondents to one or more ISDS claims.Footnote 143 The amount at stake in tax arbitration could in due course surpass that claimed in ISDS. The costs of bringing and defending a WTO dispute are in the millions and the costs of a typical ISDS case could be five times higher.Footnote 144 The costs of tax arbitration are also substantial. All members of the Inclusive Framework do not have the same financial or technical capacity to bring and defend Two Pillar Solution-related tax disputes against well-resourced multinationals.

The legal capacity of a member has been shown to matter more than its power in WTO disputes.Footnote 145 Empirical work also shows that poorer countries do worse in ISDS cases than richer countries.Footnote 146 The same concerns have been raised by developing countries in the past as one of the reasons not to embrace tax arbitration.Footnote 147 Unsurprisingly, the BRICS (Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa) have actively sought to increase their legal capacity in the WTO over the past two decades, neutralising to some extent an advantage long held by large developed members.Footnote 148 The loss of advantage in dispute settlement is broadly correlated with the decline in the acceptance of the WTO dispute settlement outcomes by the United States. An increase in the number of international tax arbitrations will mean a significant increase in the amount of tax revenue affected, which in turn means that international tax arbitrations will no longer be able to fly below the public and political radar. Any perceived unevenness of the playing field in tax arbitration will attract attention and may have longer-term systemic effects on international tax cooperation.

The Pillar One Blueprint proposes that experts could provide technical assistance to developing countries or those countries with resource constraints.Footnote 149 The design and funding of any technical assistance programme will determine its effect. A general comment without specifics does not provide much reassurance. Something akin to the Advisory Centre on WTO LawFootnote 150 would be a necessary piece of a programme of assistance if developing countries are to engage in tax arbitration effectively.Footnote 151 If developing countries were likely to be as well-resourced as the multinationals arbitrating tax disputes, support for international arbitration among multinationals might not even be so firm.

Unlike WTO disputes, MAP and Amount A arbitration can be initiated by private actors,Footnote 152 and they share certain similarities with investment disputes. International tax arbitration will have an impact on the past and future tax liabilities of companies and the revenue collected by tax jurisdictions. As already observed, at a time when opportunities for taxpayer-initiated international tax arbitration appear to be expanding, governments in many developed and developing countries are re-examining and reducing their commitments under investment treaties, because of concerns about ISDS.Footnote 153 The concern is not just with restrictions on host State policies under investment agreements, but also with ISDS as a process and therefore directly relevant to tax arbitration. The ISDS provisions in investment agreements have been vigorously criticised by civil society groups, politicians and scholars throughout the world.Footnote 154 ISDS is attacked for the absence of the level of accountability expected in democratic societies, the unequal access to legal representation, and a failure to meet rule-of-law principles. Many of the features which render arbitration more attractive than litigation in domestic courts—the possibility for discrete settlement or a formal ruling without publicity, the avoidance of appellate review, and the prospect of selecting adjudicators—are the same features that are seen as raising rule-of-law concerns. Accordingly, a number of recent investment agreements have sought to limit ISDS or excluded it entirely.Footnote 155 The UN Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) has been working to assist States to modernise older-generation investment treaties. In parallel, the United States and other developed countries have also elaborated their model investment agreements. The United States and its business community, however, remain supportive of ISDS in principle. The same is true of China and Japan. Perhaps indicating that if MAP and Amount A arbitration are unlikely to constrain, in practice, the tax policies of major capital-exporting countries and at the same time assist their multinationals, an imperfect system of tax arbitration may still receive political support.

Many of the features of the ISDS process that have been challenged as illegitimate are being replicated in the international tax regime. The legitimacy of a regime exerts a ‘compliance pull’ on those normatively addressed by the regime.Footnote 156 Decisions of international tribunals and courts that are perceived to be illegitimate are less likely to be complied with. In the investment regime, the Convention on the Settlement of Investment DisputesFootnote 157 and New York ConventionFootnote 158 have mitigated risks of non-compliance with awards. Similar arrangements are not in place for international tax arbitrations, and the ease and reliability with which tax arbitration decisions can be enforced in many jurisdictions are uncertain and have not so far been addressed in the Two Pillar Solution. Consequentially, if tax arbitration is not perceived to be illegitimate, the impact on compliance may be greater than in the case of ISDS.

The obligation to implement the outcome of the arbitration is clearer for MAP arbitration than it is for the WTO. In the WTO, a panel or the Appellate Body normally will only make a recommendation to bring the offending measure into compliance.Footnote 159 That recommendation needs to be adopted by the Dispute Settlement Body, which is a committee composed of all WTO members, before any requirement to implement arises.Footnote 160 The MAP article in double tax treaties results in an arbitrated agreement between the home and host State. Parties to an arbitration have a duty to implement the decision, unless the decision is rejected by the taxpayer, but no wider process of enforcement cooperation exists.Footnote 161 The publication of trade and investment arbitration decisions adds to the pressure on governments to comply with the decision. As discussed below, tax arbitration suffers from a very low level of transparency. The design of Two Pillar Solution dispute settlement will not aid the self-enforcement of its arbitration decisions and may incentivise States to explore the weaknesses of the arrangements for enforcement of arbitration awards. Multinational taxpayers may need to call on their home States to assist, which will politicise individual cases.

States have been concerned about inconsistent and expansive holdings by ISDS arbitration panels, which in turn deters and/or raises the costs of implementing public policies.Footnote 162 Specific process-related concerns have included the selection of arbitrators, lack of transparency, no third-party participation, lack of an appeal process, and prioritising market rationality over fundamental values of the international community. Many of the process-related concerns with ISDS would seem to be applicable to MAP and Amount A arbitration or any similar process agreed. The social class, education, career and expertise of arbitrators, for example, have been shown to shape ISDS.Footnote 163 Similar concerns have been raised about tax arbitration, in particular the perception that arbitrators will be dismissive of or hostile to the concerns of developing countries.Footnote 164

The International Centre for the Settlement of Investment Disputes (ICSID), the most important forum for ISDS arbitration, has negotiated new arbitration rules to address some of the process-related criticisms.Footnote 165 Discussion of broader and more significant procedural changes are underway under the auspices of the UN Commission on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL), but are unlikely to bear fruit for several years.Footnote 166 The European Commission has proposed replacing the ad hoc arbitration panels with a more centralised investment court system, inspired in a large part by the WTO Appellate Body.Footnote 167 The discussion of permanent international courts or tribunals and appellate mechanisms has been a prominent part of the UNCITRAL's work. Critics fear an investment court will be dominated by a governmental ethos, with little guarantee of more impartial or competent arbitrators.Footnote 168 The OECD documentation on the Two Pillar Solution did not discuss these ongoing negotiations.

While some issues, such as an absence of an appeal process for ISDS, remain contentious, it is unclear why the Inclusive Framework members, or even the more active OECD countries in the development of the Two Pillar Solution, felt limited pressure to address some of the features of ISDS that are broadly accepted as problematic. One possible explanation may be the domination of representatives from tax administrations in the negotiations. If this is correct, broadening country representation in the Inclusive Framework beyond national tax administrations may help raise awareness of any process-related deficiencies.

As discussed above, taxpayers are generally free to exit the MAP process and pursue remedies under domestic law at any time. There is no fork-in-the-road provision in MAP arbitration treaty articles, despite being common in investment agreements. Even after the competent authorities have negotiated a resolution of the matter, the taxpayer is not bound to accept the outcome.Footnote 169 On the other hand, jurisdictions can prevent a matter being resolved by arbitration by agreeing to a solution before or after the arbitration has commenced.Footnote 170 Tax arbitration is in some respects worse, from the point of view of the public interest, than ISDS because the taxpayer can renounce the outcome of the arbitration. On the other hand, the involvement of the competent authorities and their ability to exit the process through mutual agreement may provide some constraint on the taxpayer.

Jurisdictions will have less freedom in relation to Amount A, but the multinational will still be free to reject the arbitration decision. The one-sided commitment is open to abuse by taxpayers, and it will affect the perceived legitimacy of the process. If Amount A needs a multilateral dispute settlement process, a multinational enterprise should be bound by the outcome of a process that it initiates.

Tax arbitration will be less transparent than investment or trade disputes. The MAP arbitration procedure, it will surely be objected, was intended to resolve individual tax cases simply, rather than developing general interpretations of a treaty.Footnote 171 A baseball-type arbitration by its nature cannot be expected to provide transparency or precedent. The legal opinion process, however, also arguably lacks the transparency and guarantees of rationality expected of a decision that has significant consequences for the public. While strong protection for confidential information is necessary,Footnote 172 the failure to discuss transparency and accountability in Amount A arbitration is particularly surprising given the practice and trend in investment arbitration. The inability to share analyses and outcomes of cases works against the consistent application of rules and learning by domestic authorities. It may also have an impact on arbitrator selection, favouring those with experience and creating a privileged club of arbitrators.

Even with rules clarifying that arbitration decisions do not create binding precedents, a tension will inevitably arise between the pursuit of transparency and legitimacy, on the one hand, and non-precedential decisions, on the other hand. Published decisions will affect future decisions. Notwithstanding that Article 3(2) of the WTO DSU provides that the DSU intended to ‘clarify provisions’ of the WTO agreements in accordance with customary rules of interpretation of public international law, and ‘Recommendations and rulings of the [Dispute Settlement Body] cannot add to or diminish the rights and obligations provided in the covered agreements’, the United States’ attack on the Appellate Body was based on a concern that the Appellate Body was in fact affecting rights and obligations. The issues to which it is proposed that binding dispute settlement will be available under the Two Pillar Solution reflects the economic interests of the large, developed countries and their multinationals. Without arbitration decisions being made public, large States will have a greater ability to reject decisions unilaterally or pressure smaller States to agree to another outcome. The asymmetrical availability of binding dispute settlement does not appear to be a good recipe for long-term stability. Together with adequate legal capacity, transparency may help make interaction between smaller developing countries, and multinationals and their home States more rule oriented.

Rights to unilaterally terminate an investment agreement are usually limited, and, when terminated, existing investments will still benefit from protection for many years.Footnote 173 Nonetheless, recent years have seen an upsurge in terminations and, more frequently renegotiation of treaties, which can produce more immediate effects.Footnote 174 It is not clear how a jurisdiction may withdraw from part or all of the Two Pillar Solution, in particular the Amount A multilateral convention. Buyer's remorse in relation to the Two Pillar Solution might arise if States were unable to assess accurately the consequences of the package at the time of signature or ratification, but over time the costs and benefits became clearer as treaty provisions were applied and better understood.Footnote 175 States that have been involved in ISDS, in particular those that are challenged, have been the States most likely to seek renegotiation or termination.Footnote 176 In other words, many States are not good at assessing the costs and benefits of treaties ex ante. The same might be expected in the Two Pillar Solution. The renegotiations of investment treaties, interestingly, focused more on substantive policy space, with more modest changes to ISDS processes.Footnote 177 It may, of course, be that States most unhappy with ISDS seek to terminate rather than renegotiate.

Once a jurisdiction has ratified the proposed Amount A multilateral convention modifying its rights and obligations under double tax treaties, the practical freedom to reject some of the Two Pillar Solution rules may be limited. Changing the rules would require the renegotiation of several, possibly dozens of double tax treaties. If the counterparties are unwilling to negotiate, a jurisdiction may be forced to choose between renunciation of the tax treaty or living with the relevant Two Pillar Solution rules. The opportunity for treaty override will depend on constitutional structure of each jurisdiction.Footnote 178 Dualist (or effectively dualist) countries like Australia, Canada, Germany, the United Kingdom and the United States appear to have more freedom to move. More consideration would need to be given to the amendment and exit from treaty arrangements.

The consensus-based decision-making in the WTO has resulted in almost total gridlock, which in turn resulted in too much being asked of the WTO's dispute settlement system. The gridlock is in part due to the shift in power away from developed countries toward emerging economies in the world economy and the WTO. The large emerging economies have learned how to utilise WTO process to their advantage as they have grown in economic importance.Footnote 179 The more decentralised investment treaty regime, by contrast, has allowed a degree of learning and evolution of treaty rules.Footnote 180 The Two Pillar Solution, combined with the structural features of the existing international income tax regime, seeks to create a regime that is more centralised than the investment regime. It is also a regime that the developed countries expect to be able to dominate and supplement with further implementing arrangements without fear of being held up because of a lack of global consensus. It is not clear that the OECD countries will be able to dominate the tax regime in the longer term. The major emerging countries are building their capacity in international tax law and policy. Many developing countries also have a preference for tax to be negotiated under the auspices of the UN rather than the OECD.

The Two Pillar Solution contemplates many new international instruments. As noted at the outset, non-binding standards have played an important role in the international tax regime. The processes by which Two Pillar Solution guidelines and commentary are being developed have been and are likely in the immediate future to be dominated by a fairly small group of States.Footnote 181 As is common throughout global governance, many States will not send representatives, and others will send generalists often from the local embassy and sometimes with authority simply to take notes rather than to speak.Footnote 182 Lacking expertise, some governments have sent private arbitration lawyers to represent them in the ongoing investment agreement reform negotiations in the UNCITRAL.Footnote 183 Experts that spend their career working in tax are likely to have both the requisite expertise to participate meaningfully, but also to have built relationships with other experts and a reputation. The influence of the major OECD countries over the Inclusive Framework and the development of the Two Pillar Solution and its implementation may in time contribute to the weakening of the regimes. A full discussion of decision-making within the Inclusive Framework is beyond the scope of this article. It is simply observed here that arrangements perceived to be one-sided will create discontent, and once the groups of disaffected countries enhance their legal capacity, gridlock is a realistic outcome in a consensus-based process.

The expertise of the WTO and Appellate Body secretariats has been a technical strength of the WTO dispute settlement process, but ultimately became a political weakness.Footnote 184 The WTO dispute settlement panellists are formally independent but are commonly accused of being insiders with a pro-trade liberalisation outlook.Footnote 185 The OECD's role in drafting and building consensus around explanatory statements and official commentaries is likely to be more important, which are likely to carry considerable weight in international arbitration of Two Pillar Solution rules. What, if any, role the OECD Secretariat may have in the future assisting arbitration panels is unclear. The potential for the OECD Secretariat to influence tax arbitration may discourage some jurisdictions from accepting binding dispute settlement. The subject deserves further consideration by Inclusive Framework members.

This section has highlighted a number of issues with international tax dispute settlement under the Two Pillar Solution. Preliminary responses to only a couple of the issues have been suggested. All of the issues require further analysis. The aim has been to bring attention to the issues and hopefully stimulate further discussion. The difficulty of reaching agreement on reforms for ISDS suggests that the designers of dispute settlement systems for international taxation should endeavour to ‘get it right’ from the beginning.

VI. CONCLUSION

The prominent role that binding dispute settlement plays in the Two Pillar Solution is arresting when viewed alongside the limited role that MAP arbitration has played in the international tax system. The nature of Amount A necessitates some sort of multilateral process for its efficacy and administrative efficiency. However, questions need to be asked about a negotiation process that generated a dispute settlement system that has privileged corporate interests over public interests and ignored the political and policy lessons from other fields of international economic law. The interests of multinationals are advanced at the expense of State sovereignty by dispute settlement in relation to Amount A. Some commentators, however, celebrate these developments which they see leading to the fusion of horizontal disputes between tax authorities and vertical disputes between taxpayers and tax authorities within a State, which will in turn help to deal with multi-jurisdictional and multifaceted tax disputes more effectively.Footnote 186 The utility of the process for taxpayers does not ensure the legitimacy of the process. Tax arbitration impacts the broader public interest. Issues of transparency, arbitrator selection and capacity of smaller developing countries should not be neglected. In Pillar Two, where many States will have an interest in the GloBE rules being correctly applied, dispute settlement is likely to have a more limited scope, which will protect the large capital-exporting countries from legal challenges.

The role of mandatory binding arbitration in disputes of cross-border income taxation merits closer and more systemic attention. The enhancement of dispute settlement in the international income tax field is taking place at a time when States are reconsidering their consent to international adjudication of trade and investment disputes. The experience with dispute settlement in international trade and investment over the past two decades suggests that there are limits to what can and should be asked from the arbitration of international tax disputes. If tax arbitration decisions are decided against several jurisdictions, concerns about loss of sovereignty are likely to assume greater political salience. The influence exercised over the OECD/G20 BEPS Project and the Inclusive Framework by major developed countries suggests that the trade-offs inherent in the Two Pillar Solution rules and processes may be satisfactory for them today. Looking forward two decades, a changed economic environment may make today's rules less appealing, but the institutional structures may inhibit change in the direction(s) favoured by tomorrow's tax powers.Footnote 187 Many OECD documents embrace ‘common’ understandings about the tax treaties.Footnote 188 A similar clubbish-ness existed in the GATT, but that did not survive the appearance of a greater number of active and confident members within the WTO and extensive litigation.

References

1 Mason, R, ‘The Transformation of International Tax’ (2020) 114(3) AJIL 353CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Avi-Yonah, RS, Advanced Introduction to International Tax Law (Edward Elgar 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Noonan, C and Plekhanova, V, ‘Compliance Challenges of the BEPS Two-Pillar Solution’ (2022) 5 BTR 512, 515–16Google Scholar. Multilateral agreements on cooperation in tax matters have, however, made a substantial contribution to tackling tax evasion and avoidance, such as the Convention on Mutual Administrative Assistance in Tax Matters, which opened for signature on 25 January 1988, and has 146 participating jurisdictions. See Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Convention on Mutual Administrative Assistance in Tax Matters <https://www.oecd.org/tax/exchange-of-tax-information/convention-on-mutual-administrative-assistance-in-tax-matters.htm>.

3 The desire of the developed countries for the OECD to retain its central position in global tax governance can be seen in defeat of the amendment proposed by the United States to the UN General Resolution. See UNGA Draft Res, ‘Promotion of Inclusive and Effective International Tax Cooperation at the United Nations’ (16 November 2022) UN Doc A/C.2/77/L.11/Rev.1; the US proposal, ‘United States: Amendment to Draft Resolution A/C.2/77/L.11/Rev.1: Promotion of Inclusive and Effective International Tax Cooperation at the United Nations’ (22 November 2022) UN Doc A/C.2/77/CRP.2; and the vote result (23 November 2022) <https://www.un.org/en/ga/second/77/docs/voting/CRP.2.pdf>. See the summary of the discussion in the press release: UN, ‘Concluding Its Session, Second Committee Approves 11 Draft Resolutions, Including Texts on Women's Development, Global Tax Cooperation, Entrepreneurship’ (23 November 2022) UN Doc GA/EF/3579 <https://press.un.org/en/2022/gaef3579.doc.htm>.

4 The leading work on tax treaties is Baker, P, Double Taxation Conventions (3rd edn, Sweet & Maxwell 2022)Google Scholar.

5 The latest versions of the model tax treaties are: OECD, Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (21 November 2017) <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/model-tax-convention-on-income-and-on-capital-2017-full-version_g2g972ee-en>; and UN, Model Double Taxation Convention between Developed and Developing Countries 2021 (September 2021) <https://www.un.org/development/desa/financing/sites/www.un.org.development.desa.financing/files/2022-03/UN%20Model_2021.pdf>.

6 For a history of the international income tax regime, see Jogarajan, S, Double Taxation and the League of Nations (CUP 2018)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 The MAP can be traced back to Article XVI of the 1943 League of Nation's Model Bilateral Convention for the Prevention of the Double Taxation of Income. League of Nations Fiscal Committee, Model Bilateral Conventions for the Prevention of International Double Taxation and Fiscal Evasion: Second Regional Tax Conference, Mexico, D.F., July 1943 (League of Nations 1945).

8 M Hearson and TN Tucker, ‘“An Unacceptable Surrender of Fiscal Sovereignty”: The Neoliberal Turn to International Tax Arbitration’ (2021) PerspectivesPol https://doi.org/10.1017/S1537592721000967, 1. See also D Ring, ‘Who is Making International Tax Policy? International Organizations as Power Players in a High Stakes World’ (2009) 33(3) FordhamIntlLJ 697. The MAP of the UN Model Double Taxation Convention contains two alternatives. Only Alternative B provides for binding arbitration, and then only on the request of a competent authority rather than the taxpayer. UN Model Double Taxation Convention (n 5) art 25, Alternative B, para 5.

9 OECD, Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (12 February 2013) <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/addressing-base-erosion-and-profit-shifting_9789264192744-en#page4>; OECD, Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (19 July 2013) <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/action-plan-on-base-erosion-and-profit-shifting_9789264202719-en#page1>.

10 OECD, ‘What Is BEPS?’ <www.oecd.org/tax/beps/about>. See also OECD, Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, ibid.

11 OECD, Making Dispute Resolution Mechanisms More Effective, Action 14: 2015 Final Report (5 October 2015) <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/making-dispute-resolution-mechanisms-more-effective-action-14-2015-final-report_9789264241633-en#page1>. See also OECD, Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 9) 23–4.

12 OECD, ‘Members of the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS’ (as of November 2021) <http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/inclusive-framework-on-beps-composition.pdf>.

13 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, often referred to as ‘MLI’.

14 OECD, ‘Statement on a Two-Pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalisation of the Economy’ (8 October 2021) <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/statement-on-a-two-pillar-solution-to-address-the-tax-challenges-arising-from-the-digitalisation-of-the-economy-october-2021.pdf> (Statement of 8 October 2021). See also the responses of AstraZeneca (p 5) and BIAC (pp 43–4) to the OECD, ‘Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation: Public Comments Received on the Pillar One and Pillar Two Blueprints’ (12 October–14 December 2020) <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/public-comments-received-on-the-reports-on-pillar-one-and-pillar-two-blueprints.htm>.

15 See, eg, Rocha, SA, ‘The Other Side of BEPS: “Imperial Taxation” and “International Tax Imperialism”’ in Rocha, SA and Christians, A (ed), Tax Sovereignty in the BEPS Era (Wolters Kluwer 2017)Google Scholar; Hearson and Tucker (n 8) 4–5.

16 OECD, ‘Members of the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS joining the October 2021 Statement on a Two-Pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalisation of the Economy as of 16 December 2022’ (16 December 2022) <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/oecd-g20-inclusive-framework-members-joining-statement-on-two-pillar-solution-to-address-tax-challenges-arising-from-digitalisation-october-2021.pdf>.

17 See Section III of this article.

18 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 2; OECD, ‘Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation – Report on Pillar One Blueprint’ (14 October 2020) para 705 <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/tax-challenges-arising-from-digitalisation-report-on-pillar-one-blueprint-beba0634-en.htm> (‘Report on Pillar One Blueprint’).

19 The backlash against international courts extends beyond international economic law. MR Masden, P Cebulak and M Weisbusch, ‘Backlash Against International Courts: Explaining the Forms, and Patterns of Resistance to International Courts’ (2018) 14 IntJLC 197.

20 The literature generally supports a greater role for arbitration in international tax. See, eg, HJ Ault, ‘Tax Treaty Arbitration: A Reassessment’ in G Kofler, R Mason and A Rust (eds), Thinker, Teacher, Traveler: Reimagining International Tax (IBFD 2021); WC Haslehner and M Kobetsky, ‘Arbitration after BEPS’ in Kofler, Mason and Rust (eds), ibid 221–32; however, see Mann, H, ‘The Expanding Universe of International Tax Disputes: A Principled Analysis of the OECD International Tax Dispute Settlement Proposals’ (2023) 31(1) AsiaPacLRev 268Google Scholar.

21 Exceptionally, some tax disputes are able to be litigated under international trade or investment treaties. See, eg, Davie, M, ‘Taxation-Based Investment Treaty Claims’ (2015) 6(1) JIDS 202Google Scholar; Chaisse, J, ‘Investor–State Arbitration in International Tax Dispute Resolution: A Cut Above Dedicated Tax Dispute Resolution’ (2015) 25 VaTaxRev 149Google Scholar; Lang, M et al. , The Impact of Bilateral Investment Treaties on Taxation (IBFD 2017)Google Scholar; Neufeldt, CL, ‘The WTO and Direct Taxation: Direct Tax Measures and Free Trade’ (2018) 59 HarvIntlLJ 3Google Scholar; Rubini, L, ‘Between Sovereignty and Complexity: The Settlement of Tax Disputes by the World Trade Organization’ (2023) 31(1) AsiaPacLRev 204Google Scholar.

22 New Zealand, for example, has 40 double tax agreements, 11 tax information exchange agreements, and six supplementary agreements to those information exchange agreements, each of which contains a MAP article. See Inland Revenue, New Zealand Government, ‘Mutual Agreement Procedure (MAP)’ <https://www.ird.govt.nz/international-tax/double-tax-agreements/mutual-agreement-procedure>.

23 For a concise summary of the law of diplomatic protection, see Dugard, J, ‘Diplomatic Protection’ in Crawford, J, Pellet, A and Olleson, S (eds), The Law of International Responsibility (OUP 2010)Google Scholar.

24 OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5) art 25(1). See also OECD, ‘Commentary on Article 25 of the OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Full Version’ (as it read on 21 November 2017) (OECD Publishing 2019) para 73; OECD, Manual on Effective Mutual Agreement Procedures (MEMAP) (OECD Publishing 2007) <https://www.oecd.org/ctp/38061910.pdf>.

25 OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5) art 25(2).

26 ibid, art 25(3).

27 OECD, ‘New Mutual Agreement Procedure Statistics on the Resolution of International Tax Disputes Released on OECD Tax Certainty Day’ (OECD News, 22 November 2022) <https://search.oecd.org/tax/forum-on-tax-administration/news/new-mutual-agreement-procedure-statistics-on-the-resolution-of-international-tax-disputes-released-on-oecd-tax-certainty-day.htm>.

28 OECD, ‘2020 Mutual Agreement Procedure Statistics’ <https://www.oecd.org/tax/dispute/mutual-agreement-procedure-statistics.htm>.

29 MA Markham, ‘Arbitration and Tax Treaty Disputes’ (2019) 35 ArbIntl 473, 484. See also PK Sidhu, ‘Is the Mutual Agreement Procedure Past Its “Best-Before Date” and Does the Future of Tax Dispute Resolution Lie in Mediation and Arbitration?’ (2014) 68(11) BullIntlTaxn 590, section 2.4.

30 OECD, ‘2020 Mutual Agreement Procedure Statistics’ (n 28).

31 RJ Danon and S Wuschka, ‘International Investment Agreements and the International Tax System: The Potential of Complementarity and Harmonious Interpretation’ (2021) 75(11/12) BullIntlTaxn 687, section 2.2.

32 M Bothe, ‘Compliance in International Law’ in Oxford Bibliographies (OUP online, last modified 28 October 2020).

33 OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5) art 25(5). See C del Campo Azpiazu, ‘Dispute Resolution Procedures in International Tax Matters: General Report’ in Cahiers de droit fiscal international, vol 101A (International Fiscal Association 2016) paras 4.1–4.2. Within the EU, Council Directive (EU) 2017/1852 of 10 October 2017 on tax dispute resolution mechanisms in the European Union [2007] OJ L265/1 provides a stronger basis for the arbitration of tax disputes. See HM Pit, ‘The Changed Landscape of Tax Dispute Resolution within the EU: Consideration of the Directive on Tax Dispute Resolution Mechanisms’ (2019) 47(8–9) Intertax 745.

34 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13).

35 HM Pit, ‘Arbitration under the OECD Multilateral Instrument: Reservations, Options and Choices’ (2017) 71(10) BullIntlTaxn 568, section 7.3.

36 OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5) art 25(5) as amended on 21 November 2017 provides: ‘Where,

(a) under paragraph 1, a person has presented a case to the competent authority of a Contracting State on the basis that the actions of one or both Contracting States have resulted for that person in taxation not in accordance with the provisions of this Convention, and

(b) the competent authorities are unable to reach an agreement to resolve that case pursuant to paragraph 2 within two years from the date when all information required by the competent authorities in order to address the case has been provided to both competent authorities,

any unresolved issues arising from the case shall be submitted to arbitration if the person so requests in writing. These unresolved issues shall not, however, be submitted to arbitration if a decision on these issues has already been rendered by a court or administrative tribunal of either State. Unless a person directly affected by the case does not accept the mutual agreement that implements the arbitration decision, that decision shall be binding on both Contacting States and shall be implemented notwithstanding any time limits in the domestic laws of these States. The competent authorities of the Contracting States shall by mutual agreement settle the mode of application of this paragraph.’

See further, G Groen, ‘The Nature and Scope of the Mandatory Arbitration Provision in the OECD Multilateral Convention (2016)’ (2017) 71(11) BullIntlTaxn 607, sections 1, 3.2.3.

37 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 19(2).

38 See, eg, SE Malamis and Q Cai, ‘International Tax Dispute Resolution in Light of Pillar One: New Challenges and Opportunities’ (2021) 75(2) BullIntlTaxn 94, sections 5.1.2–5.1.4; Danon and Wuschka (n 31) section 2.2; J Salom and P Duss, ‘The Mutual Agreement Procedure: A Swiss Perspective on Aspects of Action 14 of the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Initiative’ (2018) 72(9) BullIntlTaxn 535, section 1; T Falcão, ‘Granting Juridical Autonomy to Article 25(5) of the Tax Treaty Model’ (2017) 4 BTR 453, 479–83; Groen (n 36) section 4.

39 J Owens, ‘Mandatory Tax Arbitration: The Next Frontier Issue’ (2018) 46 Intertax 610; WW Park and DR Tillinghast, Income Tax Treaty Arbitration (Sdu Fiscale & Financiële Uitgevers 2004) 22; E Morris, ‘From Best Endeavours to Binding Arbitration: Eliminating Double Taxation’ (International Tax Review, 14 February 2019) <https://www.internationaltaxreview.com/article/2a68tf1dbv4l58hq4yscg/from-best-endeavours-to-binding-arbitration-eliminating-double-taxation>.

40 Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (adopted 23 May 1969, entered into force 27 January 1980) 1155 UNTS 331 (Vienna Convention).

41 The Explanatory Statement was adopted at the same time as the text of the Convention, ie, on 24 November 2016. See OECD, ‘Explanatory Statement to the Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting’ <https://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/explanatory-statement-multilateral-convention-to-implement-tax-treaty-related-measures-to-prevent-BEPS.pdf>. It will be seen as part of the ‘context’ for the purposes of interpretation under the Vienna Convention, ibid, art 31(2).

42 OECD, Signatories and Parties to the Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, status as of 16 December 2022 <https://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/beps-mli-signatories-and-parties.pdf>. Initially 68 countries and jurisdictions signed this convention.

43 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) arts 1, 2.

44 Interestingly, the Note by the OECD Directorate for Legal Affairs, ‘Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting: Functioning under Public International Law’, repeatedly refers to the modification of the 3,000 double tax treaties <https://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/legal-note-on-the-functioning-of-the-MLI-under-public-international-law.pdf>.

45 PJ Hattingh, ‘The Impact of the BEPS Multilateral Instrument on International Tax Policies’ (2018) 72(4/5) BullIntlTaxn 234, section 3.5.

46 Andorra, Australia, Austria, Barbados, Belgium, Canada, Curacao, Fiji, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Liechtenstein, Malta, Mauritius, Netherlands, New Zealand, Papua New Guinea, Portugal, Singapore, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom. See OECD, Signatories and Parties to the Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting. Status as of 1 June 2022 <https://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/beps-mli-signatories-and-parties.pdf>. For a discussion of the operation of MAP arbitration under the Multilateral Instrument to Prevent BEPS, see Pit (n 35); Groen (n 36).

47 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 28(1) sets out an exhaustive list of possible reservations, apart from reservations as to the scope of cases eligible for arbitration, which can be formulated by a party under art 28(2).

48 See OECD, ‘MLI Database – Matrix of Options and Reservations’ <https://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/mli-database-matrix-options-and-reservations.htm>. See also Groen (n 36) section 3.2.4.

49 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 19(4)(a).

50 ibid, art 24.

51 ibid, arts 19(4)(b)(i), (iii).

52 ibid, art 19(4)(b)(ii).

53 Campo Azpiazu (n 33) para 4.3.

54 Mann (n 20).

55 Within the EU, Council Directive (EU) 2017/1852 (n 33) will further accelerate the use of arbitration in international tax matters.

56 Rocha (n 15); M Lennard, ‘International Tax Arbitration and Developing Countries’ in M Lang and J Owens (eds), International Arbitration in Tax Matters (IBFD 2016). See also AW Oguttu, ‘Resolving Treaty Disputes: The Challenges of Mutual Agreement Procedures with a Special Focus on Issues for Developing Countries in Africa’ (2016) 70(12) BullIntlTaxn.

57 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 19(1)(a).

58 ibid, art 22(b).

59 Falcão (n 38) 468.

60 OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5) art 25(5).

61 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 19(1)(b).

62 See U Kriebaum, C Scheuer and R Dolzer, Principles of International Investment Law (3rd edn, OUP 2022) 360–78.

63 AP Kotha, ‘Baseball Arbitration Option under the EU Dispute Resolution Directive: How Well Does It Fare against the Objectives?’ (2021) 13(2) WTJ 253.

64 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 23.

65 Strict confidentiality obligations apply to all MAP arbitration. See Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 21.

66 Danon and Wuschka (n 31) section 2.2; Malamis and Cai (n 38) section 5.5.2 and footnotes therein.

67 See, eg, A Mills and J Spencer, ‘Improving Treaty Dispute Resolution: An Australian Perspective’ (2015) 69(6/7) BullIntlTaxn 387, sections 1.5 and 3.2 and footnotes therein.

68 OECD, ‘Improving the Resolution of Tax Treaty Disputes (Report adopted by the Committee on Fiscal Affairs on 30 January 2007)’ (February 2007) 24, para 39 <www.oecd.org/ctp/dispute/38055311.pdf>.

69 For the definition of challenges, see OECD, ‘Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy, Action 1 – 2015 Final Report’ (5 October 2015) para 376 <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/addressing-the-tax-challenges-of-the-digital-economy-action-1-2015-final-report_9789264241046-en#page1>.

70 OECD, Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 9) 14–15.

71 See C Noonan and V Plekhanova, ‘Taxation of Digital Services under Trade Agreements’ (2020) 23 JIEL 1015; C Noonan and V Plekhanova, ‘Digital Services Tax: Lessons from the Section 301 Investigation’ (2021) 1 BTR 83.

72 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 3.

73 OECD, ‘Report on Pillar One Blueprint’ (n 18) para 705; OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 1–2; OECD, OECD Secretary-General Tax Report to G20 Leaders (October 2021) <https://www.oecd.org/tax/oecd-secretary-general-tax-report-g20-leaders-italy-october-2021.pdf>; OECD, Public Consultation Document, Pillar One – Amount A: Draft Model Rules for Nexus and Revenue Sourcing (4 February 2022–18 February 2022) <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/public-consultation-document-pillar-one-amount-a-nexus-revenue-sourcing.pdf>; OECD, Public Consultation Document, Pillar One – Amount A: Draft Model Rules for Domestic Legislation on Scope (4 April–20 April 2022) 5, 16 <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/public-consultation-document-pillar-one-amount-a-scope.pdf>; OECD, Progress Report on Amount A of Pillar One: Two-Pillar Solution to the Tax Challenges of the Digitalisation of the Economy (11 July–19 August 2022) 13 (art 3, para 2) and 16–17 (art 6) <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/progress-report-on-amount-a-of-pillar-one-july-2022.pdf>.

74 OECD, OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises and Tax Administrations (20 January 2022) <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/oecd-transfer-pricing-guidelines-for-multinational-enterprises-and-tax-administrations-2022_0e655865-en#page1>.

75 For all developments and their progress, see OECD, ‘BEPS Action 1: Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation’ <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/beps-actions/action1/>.

76 OECD, Pillar One – Amount A: Draft Multilateral Convention Provisions on Digital Services Taxes and other Relevant Similar Measures (20 December 2022–20 January 2023) <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/public-consultation-document-draft-mlc-provisions-on-dsts-and-other-relevant-similar-measures.pdf>.

77 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 2; OECD, ‘Report on Pillar One Blueprint’ (n 18) para 705.

78 OECD, ‘Report on Pillar One Blueprint’, ibid, Annex A.

79 LB Terr et al, ‘Resolving International Tax Disputes: APAs, Mutual Agreement Procedures, and Arbitration’ (2012) 41(9) TaxManIntlJ 435, 438–9; OECD, OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises and Tax Administrations (July 2017) 478 <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/oecd-transfer-pricing-guidelines-for-multinational-enterprises-and-tax-administrations-2017_tpg-2017-en#page1>.

80 OECD, Statement by the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS on the Two-Pillar Approach to Address the Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation of the Economy (29–30 January 2020) para 18 <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/statement-by-the-oecd-g20-inclusive-framework-on-beps-january-2020.pdf>.

81 See also Malamis and Cai (n 38) section 5.3.3.

82 OECD, ‘Report on Pillar One Blueprint’ (n 18).

83 ibid, paras 700, 706, 777.

84 ibid, para 779.

85 Lang and Owens (eds) (n 56) (various contributions).

86 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 2, 6–7.

87 ibid 2.

88 ibid 3; OECD, ‘Report on Pillar One Blueprint’ (n 18) paras 12, 649, 659.

89 ibid, para 709.

90 Malamis and Cai (n 38).

91 ibid, section 5.5.3.

92 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 3.

93 OECD, Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalisation of the Economy – Global Anti-Base Erosion Model Rules (Pillar Two) (20 December 2021) <https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/tax-challenges-arising-from-digitalisation-of-the-economy-global-anti-base-erosion-model-rules-pillar-two_782bac33-en#page1>.

94 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 3.

95 26 United States Code, section 951A: ‘Global Intangible Low-taxed Income Included in Gross Income of United States Shareholders’ was introduced by the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act 2017, Public Law 115–97.

96 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 3; OECD, ‘Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation – Report on Pillar Two Blueprint’ (14 October 2020) para 26 <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/tax-challenges-arising-from-digitalisation-report-on-pillar-two-blueprint-abb4c3d1-en.htm> (‘Report on Pillar Two Blueprint’).

97 OECD, ‘Report on Pillar Two Blueprint’, ibid, para 711.

98 V Chand, A Turina and K Romanovska, ‘Tax Treaty Obstacles in Implementing the Pillar Two Global Minimum Tax Rules and a Possible Solution for Eliminating the Various Challenges’ (2022) 14(1) WTJ 3.

99 BEAT in the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act 2017 has been claimed to be a breach of the non-discrimination article in US double taxation agreements, because it denies deductions for payments related to related foreign parties but not to related domestic parties and in some circumstances may be effectively a tax on gross income in excess of the foreign investor's profit. See RS Avi-Yonah and B Wells, ‘The BEAT and Treaty Overrides: A Brief Response to Rosenbloom and Shaheen’ (2018) 92(4) TaxNotesIntl 383; RS Avi-Yonah, ‘The Dubious Constitutional Origins of Treaty Overrides’ (28 July 2022) <https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4099091>. However, see HD Rosenbloom and F Shaheen, ‘The BEAT and the Treaties’ (2018) 92(1) TaxNotesIntl 53; HD Rosenbloom and F Shaheen, ‘Treaty Override: The False Conflict between Whitney and Cook’ (2021) 24 FlaTaxRev 375; HD Rosenbloom and F Shaheen, ‘The TCJA and the Treaties’ (2019) 95 TaxNotesIntl 1057.

100 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 7.

101 See R Danon et al, ‘The OECD/G20 Global Minimum Tax and Dispute Resolution: A Workable Solution Based on Article 25(3) of the OECD Model, the Principle of Reciprocity and the GloBE Model Rules’ (2022) 14(3) WTJ 486.

102 OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14), 3. See also OECD, OECD Secretary–General Tax Report to G20 Leaders (n 73) 5.

103 OECD, ‘Report on Pillar Two Blueprint’ (n 96) paras 21, 677, 707. See also OECD, Statement of 8 October 2021 (n 14) 7.

104 OECD, ‘Report on Pillar Two Blueprint’, ibid, para 714.

105 ibid, para 707.

106 Council Directive (EU) 2022/2523 of 14 December 2022 on ensuring a global minimum level of taxation for multinational enterprise groups and large-scale domestic groups in the Union [2022] OJ L328/1, arts 50(1), 56.

107 Compare J Vella, MP Devereux and H Wardell-Burrus, ‘Pillar 2's Impact on Tax Competition’ (26 August 2022) <https://ssrn.com/abstract=4203395> with Noonan and Plekhanova (n 2).

108 Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex 2, 1869 UNTS 401. See, generally, SP Croley and JH Jackson, ‘WTO Dispute Procedures, Standards of Review, and Deference to National Governments’ (1996) 90 AJIL 193; D Palmeter, PC Mavroidis and N Meagher, Dispute Settlement in the World Trade Organization (3rd edn, CUP 2022).

109 The GATT dispute settlement process became a more recognisable legal process over time. The rate of compliance with panel decisions was high: 88 per cent between 1948 and 1989, with a drop to 81 per cent in the 1980s. Developed countries accounted for 73 per cent of the complaints filed and were the respondents in 83 per cent of cases. RE Hudec, DLM Kennedy and M Sgarbossa, ‘A Statistical Profile of GATT Dispute Settlement Cases, 1948–1989’ (1993) 2 MinnJGlobalTrade 1.

110 CD Creamer and Z Godzimirska, ‘(De)legitimation at the WTO Dispute Settlement Mechanism’ (2016) 49 VandJTransnatlL 275.

111 The US attacks did not begin or end with the Trump administration. There is a wealth of literature on the subject. See, eg, B Hoekman and P Mavoridis, ‘To AB or Not to AB? Dispute Settlement in WTO Reform’ (2020) 23 JIEL 703; R McDougall, ‘The Crisis in WTO Dispute Settlement: Fixing Birth Defects to Restore Balance’ (2018) 52(3) JWT 876.

112 WTO, ‘Appellate Body Annual Report for 2019–2020’ (July 2020) 6–8 <https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/dispu_e/ab_anrep_2019_e.pdf>.

113 WTO, ‘Dispute Settlement Activity – Some Figures’ <https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/dispu_e/dispustats_e.htm>; WTO, Annual Report 2022 (May 2022) 140 <https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/anrep_e/ar22_e.pdf>.

114 WTO, Annual Report 2022, ibid 140–4.

115 US Trade Representative (USTR), Report on the Appellate Body of the World Trade Organization (February 2020) 25–80 <https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/Report_on_the_Appellate_Body_of_the_World_Trade_Organization.pdf>.

116 WTO, ‘Informal Process on Matters Related to the Functioning of the Appellate Body – Report by Facilitator, H.E. Dr. David Walker (New Zealand) (15 October 2019) JOB/GC/222; European Commission, ‘Annex to the Trade Policy Review – An Open, Sustainable and Assertive Trade Policy’ (18 February 2021) COM (2021) 66 final, 7.

117 G Shaffer, ‘A Tragedy in the Making? The Decline of Law and the Return of Power in International Trade Relations?’ (2018) 44 YaleJIntlL 37.

118 See, eg, USTR, ‘Ambassador Katherine Tai's Remarks as Prepared for Delivery at the World Trade Organization’ (October 2021) <https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-offices/press-office/speeches-and-remarks/2021/october/ambassador-katherine-tais-remarks-prepared-delivery-world-trade-organization>; S Lester, ‘Katherine Tai on WTO Dispute Settlement Reform’ (International Economic Law Blog, 12 January 2022) <https://ielp.worldtradelaw.net/2022/01/katherine-tai-on-wto-dispute-settlement-reform.html>. See also the request from 127 WTO members to establish a process to fill the vacancies on the Appellate Body: ‘Appellate Body Appointments’ (13 September 2022) WT/DSB/W/609/Rev.23.

119 Slightly more positively, see WTO Ministerial Conference, Twelfth Session, ‘MC12 Outcome Document’ (17 June 2022) WT/MIN(22)/24, para 4.

120 AL Paulus, ‘From Neglect to Defiance? The United States and International Adjudication’ (2004) 15 EJIL 783.

121 J Hillman, ‘Three Approaches to Fixing the World Trade Organization's Appellate Body: The Good, The Bad, and the Ugly?’ (Washington International Trade Association, 2018) <https://www.wita.org/atp-research/three-approaches-to-fixing-the-world-trade-organizations-appellate-body-the-good-the-bad-and-the-ugly/>.

122 USTR (n 115).

123 See, eg, PC Mavroidis and A Sapir, ‘China and the WTO: Why Multilateralism Still Matters’ (Princeton University Press 2021).

124 ‘Statement on a Mechanism for Developing, Documenting and Sharing Practices and Procedures in the Conduct of WTO Disputes’ (30 April 2020) JOB/DSB/A/Add.12.

125 AR Young, Supplying Compliance with Trade Rules: Explaining the EU's Response to Adverse WTO Rulings (OUP 2021).

126 Regulation (EU) 2021/167 amending Regulation (EU) No 654/2014 concerning the exercise of the Union's rights for the application and enforcement of international trade rules [2021] OJ L49/1.

127 European Commission, ‘Ukraine Wood Export Ban Found Illegal in Independent Panel Ruling’ (12 December 2020) <https://policy.trade.ec.europa.eu/news/ukraine-wood-export-ban-found-illegal-independent-panel-ruling-2020-12-12_en>.

128 R Brewster, ‘WTO Dispute Settlement: Can We Go Back Again?’ (2019) 113 AJIL Unbound 61; MA Pollock, ‘International Court Curbing in Geneva: Lessons from the Paralysis of the WTO Appellate Body’ (2023) 36(1) Governance 23.

129 KJ Alter, JT Gathii and LR Helfer, ‘Backlash Against International Courts in West, East and Southern Africa: Causes and Consequences’ (2016) 27 EJIL 293.

130 See Section V below.

131 IV Damme, ‘Treaty Interpretation by the WTO Appellate Body’ (2010) 21 EJIL 605; R Howse, ‘The World Trade Organization 20 Years On: Global Governance by Judiciary’ (2016) 27 EJIL 9.

132 The metaphor is borrowed from D Acemoglu and JA Robinson, The Narrow Corridor: How Nations Struggle for Liberty (Penguin 2020).

133 See, eg, D Desierto, Public Policy in International Economic Law: The ICESCR in Trade, Finance, and Investment (OUP 2015).

134 The invocation of non-WTO rules of international law in DSU proceedings is common but limited by the DSU reference to ‘covered agreements’. See G Cook, A Digest of WTO Jurisprudence on Public International Law Concepts and Principles (CUP 2015).

135 UNGA Res 41/128 (4 December 1986) UN Doc A/RES/41/128; UN Human Rights Council, ‘Draft Convention on the Right to Development’ (17 January 2020) A/HRC/WG.2/21/2.

136 KB Brown, ‘Tax Incentives and Sub-Saharan Africa’ (2021) 48 PeppLRev 995; M Hearson, Imposing Standards: The North–South Dimension to Global Tax Politics (Cornell University Press 2021).

137 N Krisch, ‘The Decay of Consent: International Law in an Age of Global Public Goods’ (2014) 108 AJIL 1.

138 On the investment regime, see K Miles, The Origins of International Investment Law: Empire, Environment, and the Safeguarding of Capital (CUP 2013); J Salacuse, The Law of Investment Treaties (2nd edn, OUP 2015).

139 HJ Ault, ‘Tax Competition and Tax Cooperation: A Survey and Reassessment’ in J Monsenego and J Bjuvberg (eds), International Taxation in a Changing Landscape: Liber Amicorum in Honour of Bertil Wiman (Wolters Kluwer 2019) 1 <https://works.bepress.com/hugh_ault/109/>; Mason (n 1).

140 Compare J Pauwelyn, ‘A Typology of Multilateral Treaty Obligations: Are WTO Bilateral or Collective in Nature?’ (2003) 14 EJIL 907 with C Carmody, ‘WTO Obligations as Collective’ (2006) 17 EJIL 419. Aspects of the Agreement on Fisheries Subsides concluded at the 2022 WTO Ministerial Conference focus on the protection of collective interests. See WTO, ‘Agreement on Fisheries Subsidies’ (22 June 2022) WT/MIN(22)/33. The issue of inter se modification of multilateral treaties under the Vienna Convention (n 40) art 41 has also arisen in relation to proposals to establish an appellate mechanism for investor–State arbitral awards. See M Potestà, ‘An Appellate Mechanism for ICSID Awards and Modification of the ICSID Convention under Article 41 of the VCLT’ in E Shirlow and K Nasir Gore (eds), The Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties in International Arbitration: History, Evolution, and Future (Kluwer 2022).

141 This article does not explore the relationship between the tax and investment regimes or the possibility of parallel proceedings. See VA Ferreira, The Improper Use of Tax Treaties by Contracting States: Tax Treaty Dodging, IBFD Doctoral Series (IBFD 2021) ch 5; Danon and Wuschka (n 31). Likewise, the relationship between the Two Pillar Solution and the WTO is not addressed. That said, aspects of Pillar Two appear to be inconsistent with the most-favoured-nation rules in Article I of the GATT and Article II of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS).

142 UN Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), ‘Investor–State Dispute Settlement Cases Pass the 1,000 Mark: Cases and Outcomes in 2019’ (IIA Issues Note, July 2020) 4 <https://unctad.org/system/files/official-document/diaepcbinf2020d6.pdf> (disclosed amounts sought by investors covering half of the claims filed in 2019 ranged from $US10 million to US$3.5 billion).

143 UNCTAD, ‘Investor–State Dispute Settlement Cases: Facts and Figures 2020’ (IIA Issues Note, September 2021) <https://unctad.org/system/files/official-document/diaepcbinf2021d7_en.pdf>. The actual number may be greater due to confidentiality. Outcomes are also sometimes confidential. EM Hafner-Burton, ZC Steinert-Threlkeld and DG Victor, ‘Predictability Versus Flexibility: Secrecy in International Investment Arbitration’ (2016) 68(3) WldPol 413.

144 K Pelc, ‘Does the International Investment Regime Induce Frivolous Litigation?’ (19 May 2016) <https://ssrn.com/abstract=2778056>. Some estimates of the differences are even higher. ISDS proceedings may require 40–50 times more hours worked than WTO panel proceedings (not counting consultation, appeal, remedies). L Johnson and B Guven, Securing Adequate Legal Defense in Proceedings under International Investment Agreements: A Scoping Study (11 November 2019) 89 <https://academiccommons.columbia.edu/doi/10.7916/d8-hced-vz23>.

145 A Guzman and B Simmons, ‘To Settle or Empanel? An Empirical Analysis of Litigation and Settlement at the World Trade Organization’ (2002) 31 JLS 205; ML Burch, E Reinhardt and G Shaffer, ‘Does Legal Capacity Matter? A Survey of WTO Members’ (2009) 8 WTR 559.

146 T Schultz and C Dupont, ‘Investment Arbitration: Promoting the Rule of Law or Over-empowering Investors? A Quantitative Empirical Study’ (2014) 25(4) EJIL 1147.

147 See Falcão (n 38) 469–70.

148 G Shaffer, Emerging Powers and the World Trading System: The Past and Future of International Economic Law (OUP 2021).

149 OECD, ‘Report on Pillar One Blueprint’ (n 18) para 797.

150 See Advisory Centre on WTO Law <https://www.acwl.ch>.

151 Malamis and Cai (n 38) section 6.3.

152 OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5) art 25(5); Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art 19(1). Notwithstanding the language of Article 25(1), it appears that access to the MAP can be denied where the request relates to ‘abusive’ transactions. OECD, Commentaries on the Articles of the Model Tax Convention (2017) 361, para 26 <https://www.oecd.org/ctp/model-tax-convention-on-income-and-on-capital-full-version-9a5b369e-en.htm>. See A Navarro, ‘Spanish Supreme Court Denies Access to MAP on Domestic GAAR Tax Case’ (MNE Tax, 2 November 2021) <https://mnetax.com/spanish-supreme-court-denies-access-to-map-in-domestic-gaar-tax-case-46099>.

153 In the investment regime, dissatisfaction with ISDS awards has manifested itself as treaty reform initiatives. The United States has been a respondent in 17 investment claims. Despite not losing a claim, it sought to rethink the content of US investment treaties. The 2020 United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement excludes ISDS between the United States and Canada, and severely restrains the cases between the United States and Mexico. Brazil has moved to include only State–State dispute settlement in its investment agreements. India has constrained ISDS with a strong exhaustion of domestic remedies clause in its model investment agreement. The free trade agreements that the EU signed with Canada (EU–Canada Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (signed 2016, entered into force provisionally 21 September 2017) art 8.29), Singapore (EU–Singapore Investment Protection Agreement (signed 19 October 2018, entered into force 21 November 2019) art 3.12) and Vietnam (EU–Viet Nam Investment Protection Agreement (concluded 30 March 2020, entered into force 1 August 2020) art 3.41) provided for an international investment court. China and Japan continue to support ISDS.

154 See, eg, Schultz and Dupont (n 146); M Waibel et al (eds), The Backlash Against Investment Arbitration: Perceptions and Reality (Wolters Kluwer 2010); J Bonnitcha, LNS Poulsen and M Waibel, The Political Economy of the Investment Regime (OUP 2017); CN Brower and J Ahmad, ‘Why the “Demolition Derby” that Seeks to Destroy Investor–State Arbitration?’ (2017) 91(6) SCalLRev 1139. Defenders of the current regime have pushed back, calling the critics simpletons, Marxists, and even Nazis. JE Alvarez, ‘ISDS Reform: The Long View’ (2021) 36(2) ICSID Rev 253.

155 See, eg, EU–China Comprehensive Agreement on Investment (signed 30 December 2020); Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement (entered into force 1 January 2022).

156 The classic work on legitimacy in international law is TM Franck, The Power of Legitimacy Among Nations (OUP 1990). Despite the widespread discussion of the legitimacy of international regimes, the concept is multifaceted and not well-defined. See J Crawford, ‘The Problems of Legitimacy-Speak’ (2004) 98 ASILPROC 271; CA Thomas, ‘The Uses and Abuses of Legitimacy in International Law’ (2014) 34 OJLS 729; A Galán, ‘The Search for Legitimacy in International Law: The Case of the Investment Regime’ (2019) 82 FordhamIntlLJ 81. The concept of legitimacy reflects cultural and social norms about the rule of law and democracy. The legitimacy deficit of ISDS has often been identified by comparing ISDS with the standards expected of domestic judicial institutions.

157 Convention on the Settlement of Investment Disputes between States and Nationals of Other States (adopted 18 March 1965, entered into force 14 October 1966), also known as the ‘ICSID Convention’.

158 UN Convention on the Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards (adopted 10 June 1958, entered into force 7 June 1959).

159 DSU, art 19. In the case of prohibited subsidies, more specific recommendation to withdraw a subsidy can be made. Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, art 4.

160 DSU, arts 2, 16.

161 See LE Schoueri and MC Barbosa, ‘Practicability, Enforcement and Legitimacy: Tax Treaty Dispute Resolution at a Crossroads’ in Kofler, Mason and Rust (eds) (n 20) 492–8.

162 See, eg, CN Brower, ‘The Coming Crisis in the Global Adjudication System’ (2003) 19 ArbIntl 415; SD Franck, ‘The Legitimacy Crisis in Investment Treaty Arbitration: Privatising Public International Law Through Inconsistent Decisions’ (2005) 73(4) FordhamLR 1521; A Kerner, ‘Why Should I Believe You? The Costs and Consequences of Bilateral Investment Treaties’ (2009) 53(1) IntlStudQ 73; D Schneiderman, ‘Legitimacy and Reflexivity in International Investment Arbitration: A New-Self-Restraint?’ (2011) 2(2) JIDS 471; GV Harten, Sovereign Choices and Sovereign Constraints: Judicial Restraint in Investment Treaty Arbitration (OUP 2013); C Henckels, ‘Protecting Regulatory Autonomy Through Greater Precision in Investment Treaties: The TPP, CETA, and TTIP’ (2016) 19(1) JIEL 27; M Langford and D Behn, ‘Managing Backlash: The Evolving Investment Treaty Arbitrator?’ (2019) 29(2) EJIL 551; H Hahm et al, ‘Who Settles Disputes? Treaty Design and Trade Attitudes Toward the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP)’ (2019) 73(4) IntlOrg 881.

163 S Puig, ‘Social Capital in the Arbitration Market’ (2014) 25 EJIL 387; AK Bjorklund et al, ‘The Diversity Deficit in International Investment Arbitration’ (2020) 21 JWIT 410. See also O Larsson et al, ‘Selection and Appointment in International Adjudication: Insights from Political Science’ (2022) JIDS <https://doi.org/10.1093/jnlids/idac014>.

164 Lennard (n 56) 179.

165 ICSID, ‘ICSID Administrative Council Approves Amendment of ICSID Rules’ (ICSID News & Events, 21 March 2022) <https://icsid.worldbank.org/news-and-events/communiques/icsid-administrative-council-approves-amendment-icsid-rules>.

166 UNCITRAL Working Group III: Investor–State Dispute Settlement Reform <https://uncitral.un.org/en/working_groups/3/investor-state>.

167 See, eg, EU–Canada Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (n 153) art 8.28; EU–Singapore Investment Protection Agreement (n 153) art 3.10; EU–Viet Nam Investment Protection Agreement (n 153) art 3.39.

168 CN Brower and J Ahmad, ‘From the Two-Headed Nightingale to the Fifteen-Headed Hydra: The Many Follies of the Proposed International Investment Court’ (2018) 41 FordhamIntlLJ 791.

169 OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5) art 25(5).

170 Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) arts 19(1)(b), 22, 24.

171 The OECD Model Tax Convention (n 5), however, permits more general issues to be discussed under Article 25(3). Some potential issues under the Two Pillar Solution may be peremptorily addressed by States under this process. Pillar One also envisages other processes being available under a multilateral convention to provide taxpayer ex ante certainty in relation to Amount A. The normal outcome under the MAP would be a memorandum of understanding that does not purport to override the treaty. It may, however, be open to a taxpayer to challenge the memorandum as inconsistent with the treaty under domestic law.

172 See Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (n 13) art. 21.

173 T Voon and A Mitchel, ‘Denunciation, Termination and Survival: The Interplay of Treaty Law and International Investment Law’ (2016) 31(2) ICSID Rev 413.

174 C Peinhardt and RL Wellhausen, ‘Withdrawing from Investment Treaties but Protecting Investment’ (2016) 7(4) GlobalPol 571.

175 B Simmons, ‘Bargaining Over BITS, Arbitrating Awards: The Regime for Protection and Promotion of International Investment’ (2014) 66(1) WldPol 12; LNS Poulsen, Bounded Rationality and Economic Diplomacy: The Politics of Investment Treaties in Developing Countries (CUP 2015).

176 A Thompson, T Broude and YZ Haftel, ‘Once Bitten, Twice Shy? Investment Disputes, State Sovereignty, and Change in Treaty Design’ (2019) 73 IntlOrg 859.

177 See also TS John, ‘Why is Exit So Hard? Positive Feedback and Institutional Persistence’ in TS John, The Rise of Investor–State Arbitration: Politics, Law, and Unintended Consequences (OUP 2018) 234–48; RL Wellhausen, ‘International Investment Law and Foreign Direct Investment’ (2019) 73(4) IntlOrg 839.

178 For a discussion of tax treaty overrides, see references in Noonan and Plekhanova (n 2) 516–18.

179 SE Rolland and DM Trubek, Emerging Powers in the International Economic Order: Cooperation, Competition and Transformation (CUP 2019); Shaffer (n 148).

180 D Blake, ‘Thinking Ahead: Time Horizons and the Legalization of International Investment Agreements’ (2013) 67(4) IntlOrg 797; MS Manger and C Peinhardt, ‘Learning and Precision of International Investment Agreements’ (2017) 16(4) IntlInteract 869.

181 See RC Christensen, M Hearson and T Randriamanalina, ‘At the Table, Off the Menu? Assessing the Participation of Lower-Income Countries in Global Tax Negotiations’ (2020) ICTD Working Paper 115; A Christians and L van Apeldoorn, ‘The OECD Inclusive Framework’ (2018) 72(4) BullIntlTaxn 226; IJM Valderrama, ‘Output Legitimacy Deficits and the Inclusive Framework of the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Initiative’ (2018) 72(3) BullIntlTaxn; TD Magalhāes, ‘What is Really Wrong with Global Tax Governance and How to Properly Fix It’ (2018) 10(4) WTJ 499. See also OECD, Inclusive Framework on BEPS: Background Brief 11–12, para 2.2 <https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/background-brief-inclusive-framework-on-beps.pdf>.

182 S Block-Lieb and S Halliday, Global Lawmakers: International Organization in the Crafting of World Markets (CUP 2017).

183 TS John, ‘Three Conceptions of Sovereignty in Contemporary Investment Law’ in C Smith (ed), Sovereignty: A Global Perspective (Proceedings of the British Academy) (OUP 2023).

184 J Pauwelyn and K Pelc, ‘WTO Ruling and the Veil of Anonymity’ (2022) 33(2) EJIL 527; A Steinbach, ‘Are the Fingerprints of WTO Staff on Panel Rulings a Problem? A Reply to Joost Pauwelyn and Krzysztof Pelc’ (2022) 33(2) EJIL 565.

185 There is a wealth of research on the background of WTO panellists. See, eg, J Pauwelyn, ‘The Rule of Law Without the Rule of Lawyers? Why Investment Arbitrators are from Mars, Trade Adjudicators from Venus’ (2015) 109 AJIL 761.

186 N Tadmore and L Moses, ‘The Future of International Tax Disputes: The Inevitability of Fusion’ in Kofler, Mason and Rust (eds) (n 20) 586–8.

187 Concern about the domination of global tax policy by the major developed countries through the OECD has been discussed many times. See, eg, D Spencer, ‘U.N. Tax Committee, Developing Countries, and Civil Society Organizations’ (2015) 26 JIT 42; M Herzfeld, ‘News Analysis: Who Will Control the Future of International Tax Policy?’ (Tax Notes, 4 May 2015). See also R Avi-Yonah and H Xu, ‘Evaluating BEPS: A Reconsideration of the Benefits Principles and Proposal for UN Oversight’ (2016) 6(2) HarvBusLRev 185, 211.

188 See, eg, OECD, Model Tax Convention (n 5); OECD Council, ‘Tax Treaty Override’ (2 October 1989) R(8)-2 to R(8)-3, para 4.